In the Wake of the Crisis: Pension Reforms in Eight European Countries

Page created by Adrian Nguyen
 
CONTINUE READING
In the Wake of the Crisis: Pension Reforms in Eight European Countries
Karl Hinrichs

In the Wake of the
Crisis: Pension
Reforms in Eight
European Countries

ZeS-Working Paper No. 01/2015
In the Wake of the Crisis: Pension Reforms in Eight European Countries
WORKING PAPERS

Zentrum für Sozialpolitik
Universität Bremen
Postfach 33 04 40
28334 Bremen
Phone: 0421 / 218-58500
Fax: 0421 / 218-58622
E-mail: srose@uni-bremen.de
Editor: Kristin Bothur

http://www.zes.uni-bremen.de
Design: cappovision, Frau Wild
ZeS-Arbeitspapiere
ISSN 1436-7203

2
In the Wake of the Crisis: Pension Reforms in Eight European Countries
Karl Hinrichs

In the Wake of the
Crisis: Pension
Reforms in Eight
European Countries

ZeS-Working Paper No. 01/2015

Prof. Dr. Karl Hinrichs
University of Bremen
Centre for Social Policy Research (ZeS)
karl.hinrichs@uni-bremen.de

                                          3
summary
                      The 2008 financial market crisis, followed by the Great
                      Recession and sovereign debt crises in several EU coun-
                      tries have triggered drastic reforms of old-age security
                      systems. They were supposed to ensure the financial vi-
                      ability of public pension schemes in the short and long
                      run and/or to realize notions of intergenerational fair-
                      ness. Most urgently, however, was regaining room for fis-
                      cal manoeuvre and obtaining financial aid from suprana-
                      tional organizations (such as IMF or EU). These pension
                      reforms differ from previous changes with regard to their
                      scope and the political process. (1) They were large, thus
                      causing a substantial and immediate impact on the liv-
                      ing conditions of present and future retirees and, some-
                      times, changed the hitherto pursued policy direction. (2)
                      The post-2008 reforms swiftly passed the legislative pro-
                      cess and were implemented at short notice. Hence, they
                      can be considered as “rapid policy changes”. This paper
                      analyses pension reforms in eight crisis-shaken EU coun-
                      tries: Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy, Latvia, Portugal,
                      Romania, and Spain. It explores both reform contents and
                      circumstances which led to the respective changes or fa-
                      cilitated them. As is shown, the challenges, which those
                      countries were (or still are) confronted with, allowed or
                      enforced alterations that would not have been feasible
                      otherwise, or which would rather not have been initiated
                      by the respective governments with regard to the politi-
                      cal consequences. Moreover, cross-national comparison
                      reveals similarities and differences and also sheds light
                      on the social consequences that are already visible today.

4         WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
zusammenfassung   Die Finanzmarktkrise von 2008 und in deren Gefolge die
                  Große Rezession sowie Staatsschuldenkrisen in verschie-
                  denen EU-Ländern haben einschneidende Reformen der
                  Alterssicherungssysteme ausgelöst, welche die Finanzie-
                  rung der Renten kurz- und langfristig sicherstellen und/
                  oder Vorstellungen von Generationengerechtigkeit reali-
                  sieren sollen. Dringlicher war es jedoch, den fiskalischen
                  Manövrierspielraum wieder zu erweitern und Kredithilfen
                  von internationalen Geldgebern (IWF, EU) zu erlangen.
                  Diese Rentenreformen unterschieden sich von früheren
                  im Hinblick auf den Umfang und den politischen Prozess.
                  (1) Sie waren groß, zeitigten demzufolge eine signifikan-
                  te und unmittelbare Wirkung auf die Lebensbedingungen
                  der jetzigen und künftigen Rentenbezieher, und manch-
                  mal wurde auch die bis dahin verfolgte Politikausrich-
                  tung verändert. (2) Die nach 2008 erfolgten Reformen
                  passierten rasch den Gesetzgebungsprozess und wurden
                  ohne lange Übergangsfristen umgesetzt. In diesem Pa-
                  pier werden die Rentenreformen in acht krisengeschüt-
                  telten EU-Ländern betrachtet, nämlich Griechenland,
                  Irland, Italien, Lettland, Portugal, Rumänien, Spanien
                  und Ungarn. Dabei geht es um die Inhalte dieser Refor-
                  men und die Umstände, die jeweils zu diesen Verände-
                  rungen geführt bzw. sie ermöglicht haben. Gezeigt wird,
                  dass die Herausforderungen, mit denen diese Länder
                  konfrontiert waren (oder sind), einschneidende Verände-
                  rungen erlaubten bzw. erzwangen, die ansonsten kaum
                  durchsetzbar gewesen oder in Anbetracht der politischen
                  Konsequenzen von den jeweiligen Regierungen so nicht in
                  Angriff genommen worden wären. Weiterhin werden im
                  Ländervergleich die Gemeinsamkeiten und Unterschiede
                  beleuchtet sowie nach den bislang erkennbaren sozialen
                  Konsequenzen gefragt.

                                                                           5
6   WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
content
          1.    Introduction                        8

          2.    Eight Countries – Three Types of
                Pension Systems                    10

          3.    The Post-2008 Pension Reforms      12

          3.1   Ireland                            12

          3.2   The South European Countries       13

          3.3   The CEE Countries                  19

          4.    Commonalities and Differences      22

          5.    The Social Impact of Recent
                Pension Reforms                    24

          6.    Conclusion                         26

          7.    References                         28

                                                        7
1. Introduction*

The 1990s and early 2000s have shown               became a primary target for spending
that in democratic polities, reforms of            cuts because, almost everywhere, they
pension systems – parametric (path-de-             are by far the largest item of welfare state
pendent) as well as systemic (path-de-             budgets (Table 1, rows 7 and 8).
parting) changes – turned out to be not                Second, the political process that
as impracticable as research on the “new           brought about these changes deviated
politics of the welfare state” had suggest-        from previous attempts to retrench, re-
ed (Pierson 1994; 2001). No longer being           finance or recalibrate old-age security
expansionary, they came about when in-             systems. Although governments tried to
cumbent governments were able to shift             avoid a unilateral approach, there was
or share the blame for enacted retrench-           no lengthy process of consensus-seeking
ments, to hide the true impact of changes,         and compromise-building. Rather, the
or when they expected to reap credit for           post-2008 reforms in the crisis-shaken
amendments that put pension systems on             EU countries swiftly passed the legisla-
a more sustainable footing in view of ad-          tive process and were (or will be) im-
vancing population aging (Galasso 2010;            plemented with no or short transitional
Hinrichs 2011). After 2008, however, in            period. Hence, they can be considered
the wake of the Great Recession in a num-          as “rapid policy changes” (Rüb 2012).
ber of European countries being plagued            Mainly, this new reform pattern sprang
with high budget deficits and mounting             from the pressure exerted by financial
sovereign debt, pension policy alterations         markets and supranational actors (IMF,
came to the fore that were different in two        European Commission), limiting policy
aspects. First, their magnitude was large,         space for domestic actors. These exter-
particularly when the sequel of changes            nal constraints urged governments to ne-
is added up. Sometimes even the hith-              glect vote-seeking objectives within the
erto pursued policy direction was moved,           well-known credit-claiming/blame-avoid-
and the reforms cause a substantial and            ance framework for the sake of attaining
immediate negative impact on the living            short-term savings on public expenditure
conditions of present and future retirees.         (Bonoli 2012). Consequently, in a number
In a situation where austerity is no longer        of countries politicians, who tried to cut
simply ‘permanent’ but rather ‘pervasive’,         back on pension expenditure, were pun-
it is hardly surprising that public pensions       ished and lost power during subsequent
                                                   elections because voters rarely appreci-
                                                   ated cuts designated to overcome a ‘major
*		Revised version of a paper prepared for pres-
   entation at the XVIII ISA World Congress of     crisis situation’.
   Sociology, Research Committee 19, Session
   339 (“Social Policy and the Crisis”), Yoko-
   hama (Japan), 13-19 July 2014.

8             WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
In this contribution, eight countries         tention will also be given to the circum-
will be analyzed – four from Southern Eu-          stances which led to respective changes.
rope (Greece, Italy, Portugal, and Spain),         It will be shown that the challenges these
three Central and Eastern European (CEE)           countries were (are) confronted with,
states (Hungary, Latvia, and Romania)              enforced or facilitated profound reforms
and Ireland. All of them have conducted            which would otherwise have not been
pension reforms after 2008 in order to en-         practicable or, in view of the political con-
sure their public schemes’ financial viabil-       sequences, not been initiated by respec-
ity in the short and long term or to realize       tive governments.2 Moreover, it will be
notions of intergenerational equity. Most          briefly touched upon the social and politi-
urgently, however, these countries have            cal consequences of the implemented pol-
sought to regain room for fiscal maneuver          icy changes. An evaluation of the social
and to obtain financial aid from suprana-          outcomes, however, is limited because
tional organizations (IMF, EU). Seven of           not everywhere has the reform process
the eight countries had to seek such aid           already come to an end yet and the ac-
in the wake of the financial market crisis         tions which were taken have not brought
(2007/08), which triggered an economic             to bear their full effects.
slump and, as one immediate outcome
thereof, a sovereign debt crisis. The
causal relevance of these events for the
post-2008 reforms can be read off from
concrete recommendations issued by the
European Commission or detailed reform
demands attached to bailout agreements
(‘memoranda of understanding’). Intensi-
fied reform efforts of deeply indebted Italy
were mainly driven by the rising spread
                                                      publications of the European Commission
over German government bonds’ interest
                                                      (2010 [Annex 6], 2012b, 2012c: 23-40) and the
rate, as well meaning hard external pres-             OECD (2012a, 2013b, 2014: 52-81).
sure that shaped domestic policy-making            2
                                                    		The (‘normal’) politics of pension reform that
(Jessoula 2012: 24-5; de la Porte/Natali              prevailed during the two decades prior to
                                                      2009 has been studied in detail for individual
2014).                                                countries as well as in comparison (see
     In the following, the content of pen-            e.g. Myles/Pierson 2001; Bonoli/Shinkawa
sion reforms will be delineated1, but at-             2005; Schludi 2005; Immergut et al. 2007;
                                                      Natali 2008). Due to limited space, such fine-
		If not indicated otherwise, information on
1
                                                      grained analysis of recent reforms in eight
  the contents of reforms was obtained from           countries that takes into account the involved
  the International Updates of the US Social          actors, their interests, and the political-insti-
  Security Administration (http://www.ssa.gov/        tutional conditions cannot be presented here.
  policy/index.html), the country reports of the      For the same reason, austerity measures in
  project Analytical Support on the Socio-Eco-        other policy domains (e.g. health care, taxa-
  nomic Impact of Social Protection Reforms           tion, public sector employment/wages) will
  (ASISP) (http://www.socialprotection.eu) and        be ignored.

                                                                                                     9
2.		Eight Countries –
    Three Types of Pension Systems

The eight European countries belong to         along occupational lines – most strongly
different welfare-state regimes. Ireland is    in Greece, least in Spain and Portugal –
representing the (Anglo-Saxon) 'liberal'       for which reason benefit generosity var-
cluster, whereas Greece, Italy, Portugal       ied. Despite being ‘rudimentary’ welfare
and Spain belong to the conservative-          states, the social expenditure ratio is
corporatist type. Occasionally, they are       comparatively high but, because old-
said to form a specific 'Southern Model'.      age security constitutes the central pil-
According to Ferrera (1996), these wel-        lar of their social policy arrangements,
fare states show a ‘clientelistic’ structure   the structure of expenditure is strongly
(privileging the labor force in certain oc-    ‘age-biased’ (much more than in Ireland
cupations and economic sectors) and re-        – Table 1, rows 7 and 8). This imbalance
main ‘rudimentary’ because, among oth-         has even grown in recent years. Causes
ers, family and labor market policies are      are the hitherto very generous pension
still underdeveloped. Hungary, Latvia and      payments (at least for insiders), the broad
Romania and further CEE countries be-          access to early retirement (discernible in
long to the 'post-socialist' cluster which,    the low employment rates among those
due to these countries’ diverse welfare        55-64 years of age), and the already high
state designs, is hardly coherent enough       and further increasing longevity (Table 1,
to speak of an (emerging) 'Eastern Model'      rows 2, 3, 5, 9 and 10).
(Hacker 2009).                                     Originally, CEE countries had fol-
     There is a certain arrangement of         lowed the Bismarck model, and certain
old-age security attached to the different     elements remained intact during commu-
welfare state types. Ireland (like the UK)     nist rule. The social insurance approach
has followed the Beveridge model, i.e.         was revitalized after 1990, before Hun-
state responsibility is limited to universal   gary (1998), Latvia (2001) and Romania
basic old-age security, while status main-     (2007) turned to a multi-pillar pension
tenance is left to (state-regulated) private   system as propagated by the World Bank.3
provision by employers and individuals.        They established an additional second pil-
In Southern Europe, social insurance           lar that was private, but mandatory for
schemes of the Bismarck type play a piv-
                                               		It would have been quite possible to include
                                               3
otal role. Access to and the level of public     further CEE countries in the comparison, for
pensions depends on prior earnings-relat-        example Poland or Estonia whose retirement
ed contributions. The accruing benefits          income system came close to the one in
                                                 Latvia. They concluded similar reforms after
are meant to ensure status maintenance.
                                                 2008. – On the pre-2008 pension reforms in
Before the recent reforms, however, the          CEE countries see contributions in Cerami/
schemes were institutionally fragmented          Vanhuysse (2008).

10           WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
Table 1: Pension-relevant indicators

                                                  IE      GR     IT     PT     ES      LV     HU       RO
 1    employment rate 15-64 (2007)               69.2    60.9   58.7   67.6   65.8    68.1    57.3    58.8
      ditto (2012)                               58.8    50.8   56.8   61.4   55.8    63.0    57.2    59.5
 2    ditto 55-64 (2012)                         49.3    36.5   40.4   46.5   43.9    52.8    36.9    41.4
 3    old age ratio (≥ 65 / 20-64) (2010)         19      31     33     29     27      28      27      23
      projection 2050                             44      63     61     61     62      59      55      59
 4    contributors per pensioner (2010)          2.78    1.77   1.47   1.59   2.40    1.52    1.31    0.95
      projection 2050                            1.91    1.29   1.30   0.90   1.28    1.04    1.00    0.76
 5    further life expectancy after reaching
      age 65 (2012): males                       18.0    18.1   18.8   17.6   18.6    13.6    14.3    14.6
                      females                    21.1    21.0   22.6   21.3   22.8    18.5    18.1    17.7
 6    Change of GDP in year 2009 in %            -7.0    -3.3   -5.5   -2.9   -3.7    -17.7   -6.8    -6.6
 7    social expenditure/GDP (2007)              18.3    24.8   26.6   23.9   20.8    11.3    22.7    13.6
                               (2011)            29.6    30.2   29.7   26.5   26.1    15.1    23.0    16.3
 8    public pension expenditure in % of
      GDP (2007)                                  4.0    11.7   14.0   11.4    8.4     5.4    10.9     6.6
      (2010)                                      7.5    13.6   15.3   12.5   10.1     9.7    11.9     9.8
      projection 2050                            11.4    15.4   15.7   13.1   14.0     6.4    13.5    12.8
 9    gross average replacement rate (public
      pensions) (2010)                           37.3    59.3   79.5   56.9   72.4    48.2    38.4    41.6
      projection 2050                            38.0    52.4   66.0   48.2   56.6    15.8    40.3    29.8
 10   net theoretical replacement rate (2010)    85.8   121.3   89.5   85.8   94.5    80.4    100.1   70.7
      projection 2050                            69.0    87.0   69.1   65.9   86.5    55.3    75.0    45.0
 11   targeted benefits in old age in % of
      average earnings                           34.9    13.7   21.6   17.4   19.6             --
      minimum public pension in % of
      average earnings                            --     36.4   19.3   33.8   33.9            12.4
 12   at-risk-of-poverty rate ≥ 65 (2012)        11.0    17.2   16.3   17.4   14.8    13.9     6.0    15.4
      ditto 18-64 years                          15.1    23.8   18.6   16.9   21.9    19.3    13.6    21.0
 13   home ownership rate ≥ 65 (2010)            88.6    84.9   80.4   73.3   88.5    85.4    90.3    100

Sources: rows 1, 2, 5, 6, 7, 12 and 13 = Eurostat Statistical Database (and own calculations); rows 3, 4, 8
(2007 figures: European Commission 2009: 200) and 9 = European Commission 2012a (country fiches); row
10 = European Commission 2012b (country profiles); row 11 = OECD 2013b: 123.

the younger part of the work force. While               mainly motivated by the advancing demo-
the total contribution rate remained un-                graphic shift showing up in an increas-
changed, the share allocated to the pay-                ing old-age dependency ratio or a dete-
as-you-go first-pillar scheme was reduced               riorating system dependency ratio (Table
(and also the accruing pension level).                  1, rows 3 and 4), the latter (contributors
The remaining part was transferred into                 per pensioner) being more relevant for
the second pillar and invested in private               the financing of old-age security systems.
pension funds. This systemic change was                 Both developments are the result of rising
expected to deliver a higher total benefit              longevity and declined birth rates. At least
level and to further domestic capital mar-              since the 1990s, the OECD, the European
ket development.                                        Commission (EC) and the International
    The pre-2008 reforms in the CEE                     Monetary Fund (IMF) have purveyed the
states and other European countries were                conviction that high social security contri-

                                                                                                         11
butions and taxes have a negative effect      which increasing spending (as a result of
on employment levels, thereby support-        demographic change) can be contained.
ing national actors in their policy efforts   The ratio between pensioners and con-
to keep in check the tax and contribution     tributors may be changed by lifting the
burdens. Thus, when the contributions of      pensionable age, and it is possible to low-
employers and employees to state pen-         er the level of newly awarded pensions by
sions are supposed not to rise (much)         modifying the rules of benefit calculation
and if no (higher) tax-financed payments      or to change the way in which pensions in
are to be transferred to pension schemes,     payment are indexed.
only a limited number of levers remain by

3. The Post-2008 Pension Reforms

3.1 Ireland

Ireland’s basic state pension is contribu-        The financial market crisis has se-
tion-financed and flat-rate (but means-       verely hit the assets of the NPRF and oc-
tested for about twenty percent of retirees   cupational pension funds. In 2011, still
without a complete contribution record).      eighty percent of the defined-benefit (DB)
For a single person, the level amounts to     plans were in deficit (OECD 2013a: 53).
about 37 percent of average wages. Dur-       The funding gap has to be removed until
ing the 2000s, benefit increases in real      2016 and private pension funds will have
terms significantly reduced the risk of       to make up for a risk reserve from then
old-age poverty – from 44 percent in 2001     on. From 2011 to 2014, they are obligated
to 10.6 percent in 2010. Over the last        to compound a special levy of 0.6 percent
two decades, occupational pension plans       (p.a.) on accumulated assets and an ad-
constantly covered about one half of the      ditional levy of 0.15 percent in 2014 and
employees. In 2001, a National Pension        2015. The larger part of the (shrunken)
Reserve Fund (NPRF) was established           NPRF assets has been used to bail out and
in order to ease the financing of the ba-     recapitalize the banking sector. Before,
sic state pension and the occupational        the government had already stalled the
scheme for public service workers after       payments into the NPRF, because it had
2025 when population aging will acceler-      to cover growing deficits of the social in-
ate. Every year the government has paid       surance fund with tax money when fewer
one percent of GDP into the NPRF.             people were gainfully employed and paid

12           WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
contributions (Table 1, row 1). Consider-      to modernize, eventually leading to crisis,
able savings for the exchequer stem from       was identified (Katrougalos 1996; Venieris
changes of the DB-type public service          1996). These problems became manifest
pension schemes (Table 2): Pensions in         when the size of the Greek economy con-
payment above a certain threshold have         tracted by 23.5 percent in real terms be-
been cut in a progressive manner; the ac-      tween 2007 and 2012 (Matsaganis 2013:
crual of entitlements is capped at forty       3) and the employment rate declined by
years of service; newly awarded pensions       ten percentage points during the same
turn out to be lower due to pay cuts; pub-     period (Table 1, row 1).
lic service workers have to pay higher              Drastic pension reforms came about
contributions without earning higher enti-     only in 2010 and thereafter due to obli-
tlements; newly recruited public servants      gations related to the bailouts (Nektarios
have to reckon with more unfavorable           2012; OECD 2013d: 115-20). A signifi-
rules for calculating and adjusting their      cant structural reform of the extremely
(future) pensions (OECD 2013a: 41-3).          complex Greek old-age pension system –
These changes were components of the           consisting of a mandatory income-related
austerity package agreed with the 'Troika'     general scheme and a (largely) compulso-
which also included the gradual increase       ry supplementary component (also earn-
of the state pension age from 66 to 68 (leg-   ings-related) – started in 2008, however.
islated in 2011) and tightened contributory    The merger of occupationally differenti-
requirements. Already since 2009, there        ated schemes and standardized rules are
has been no adjustment of the basic state      supposed to bring about greater transpar-
pension, still remaining at 230.30 Euro per    ency, fairness and, additionally, lower ad-
week for a single beneficiary.                 ministrative costs. From 2012 on, all sup-
                                               plementary pension schemes have been
                                               brought together into a single pension
3.2 The South European                         fund. However, these reforms – aiming
    Countries                                  at a more harmonized, rationalized and,
                                               hence, equitable pension system – have
Greece is clearly the straggler among the      not been fully implemented yet. Moreover,
Southern European countries with regard        effectively collecting due contributions is
to social policy reforms in general and the    still hampered by deficient administrative
adaptation of old-age pension systems          capacities and the significant incidence of
to changed economic and demographic            undeclared work (Koutsogeorgopoulou et
circumstances in particular. As early as       al. 2014: 33-5).
in the 1990s, there had been complaints             Strictly following the lenders’ detailed
about the ineffectiveness and inefficiency     demands for change, in 2010 the Greek
of the Greek welfare state and disparate       Parliament decided to lower the accrual
benefit levels – with public employees         rate, most decisive for the replacement ra-
and some groups of professionals benefit-      tio in a defined-benefit scheme, from two
ing disproportionately – and an inability      to three percent to 0.8 to 1.5 percent for

                                                                                         13
14
                           Table 2: Synopsis of pension reform elements, concluded 2008 and later

                                Normal retirement age          Early retirement        Benefit formula            Indexation            Harmonization          Miscellaneous
                           IE   66 → 67 (2021) → 68            ‘transitional state     public service pensions:   state pensions        increasing NRA         cuts of public service
                                (2028)                         pension’ at age 65      career average             frozen at 2009        also applies to        pensions; state pension
                                                               abolished in 2014       earnings for newly         level (230.30 €       public sector          contributions levied without
                                                                                       recruited employees        per week)             workers                income ceiling and minimum
                                                                                                                                                               threshold
                           GR   F: 60 → 65 (2011/13);          after 40 contribution   accrual rate lowered:      suspended until       number of general      further adjustments if pen-
                                M/F: 65 → 67 (2012/13);        years: age 60 (2011)    2 to 3 % → 0.8 to 1.5      end of assistance     and supplementary      sion spending would
                                2021ff. NRA linked to          → 62 (2013);            %; calculation base:       program; 2015ff.:     schemes reduced;       increase by more than 2.5

WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
                                further life expectancy        number of arduous       best 5 out of last 10      not higher than       public sector wor-     percentage points between
                                                               professions reduced     years → entire career      CPI                   kers integrated in     2009 and 2060; progressive
                                                               to < 10 % of                                                             general scheme         solidarity tax on higher
                                                               workforce                                                                                       pensions
                           IT   F: 60 → 65 (2018); F           years of contribu-      NDC rules apply to         suspended for         rules of the           age-specific divisors for
                                public sector: 61 → 65         tions required for      all future pensioners      pensions > 1,400 €    separated schemes      converting notional ‘assets’
                                (2010/11); public sector       seniority pensions      (pro rata); minimum        in 2012 + 2013;       further aligned        into a stream of benefits (due
                                (M/F): 65 → 66                 indexed to changes      contributory period        2014: benefits < 3                           to risen life expectancy)
                                (2011/12); 2013ff. NRA         in life expectancy      for NDC pension:           × minimum                                    adjusted for the first time in
                                linked to life expectancy      2013ff.                 5 → 20 years               pension higher                               2013
                                (forecast: (2019/21: ~ 67;                                                        adjustment
                                2050: ~ 70)
                           ES   2013/27: 65 → 67;              voluntary ER: 63        full pension:              no CPI adjustment     special schemes        sustainability factor: rising
                                still 65: 35 → 38.5 years of   → 65 and 33 → 35        35 → 37 contribution       in 2012/13/14         for civil servants,    life expectancy affects
                                contributions                  insurance years;        years (50 % after 15);     (small arbitrary      farm workers + self-   calculation of newly awarded
                                                               involuntary ER          calculation base: last     increases instead);   employed abolished     pensions as of 2019 (instead
                                                               (unemployed) 61 →       15 → 25 insurance          2015ff.: annual                              of 2027); reserve fund mel-
                                                               63 and 31 → 33          years; 2019ff.: rising     changes deter-                               ting off (used for pension
                                                               (decrements about       longevity influences       mined by sustaina-                           payments)
                                                               7.5 % p.a.)             initial benefit level      bility factor
PT   65 → 66 (2013/14); after     no ret. before 65 for        whole insurance          no adjustment in     special schemes       special solidarity contribution
          it: adjusted according to    employed workers             career, but best 40      2011; 2012: CPI      (public sector,       on higher pensions (2011)
          sustainability factor        until 2014; 62 if            years for full pension   only for lower       banking, telecom)     replaced with ‘sustainability
                                       unemployed after 57                                   pensions             phase out             contribution’ (2015)
     HU   62 → 65 (2014/22) = age      F: any age after 40          benefit calculation      Swiss index →                              elimination of 13th monthly
          65 valid for birth cohorts   insurance years (incl.       changed: ~ -8.5 % for    CPI adjustment                             pension payment (2009);
          1957ff.                      child care periods)          newly awarded            since 2012                                 mandatory 2nd pillar
                                       since 2011; all other        pensions                                                            cancelled + assets shifted to
                                       ER options eliminated                                                                            state budget; no ceiling on
                                       (2012)                                                                                           employees’ share of
                                                                                                                                        contributions (2013)
     RO   M: 63 → 65 (2015)            5 years before NRA           full pension: 33/28 →    no indexation 2010   special schemes for   2nd pillar contribution rate:
          F: 58 → 60 (2015) → 63       with temporary               35 insurance years for   – 2012; 2013: +4     certain occupations   scheduled increase 2 → 6 %
          (2030) → 65 (2035)           decrement of 9 %             M 2015, for F 2030;      %, 2014: +3,75 %;    integrated in         (2009/16) delayed by one
                                       p.a.; eligibility criteria   minimum contribution     2021/2030 shift      general scheme        year; minimum pension
                                       disability pensions          period: 13 → 15 years    to pure inflation    (2010)                introduced 2009 (~ 90
                                       tightened                    (2015)                   adjustment                                 €/month)
     LV   62 → 65 (2014/25)            2 years before NRA           minimum years of         no adjustment                              2nd pillar contribution rate:
                                       with deductions if           contributions: 10 →      2009 – 2012; +4 %                          8 → 2 % (2009); resurgence:
                                       30 insurance years;          15 (2014) → 20 (2025)    for pensions                               2 → 6 (2013/16)
                                       all other ER options                                  < 285 € in 2013;
                                       abolished as of 2012                                  2014ff.: CPI plus
                                                                                             25 % of wage
                                                                                             increase

15
one year of contribution payments. The             percentage points of GDP by 2060 in com-
attainable benefit level is thereby signifi-       parison to 2009.5
cantly reduced, and incentives are created             Subsequently, in 2012, a new (NDC6
to stay in employment for more years be-           look-alike) benefit formula with a built-in
cause the accrual rate is progressive with         sustainability factor for the supplementa-
the total length of insurance (Nektarios           ry pension scheme was enacted; pensions
2012: 267). Furthermore, the pensionable           of the general scheme higher than 1,300
ages of men and women were equalized               Euro were cut by twelve percent on aver-
at age 65 until 2013. In future, entitlement       age7; access to invalidity pensions was
to a full pension will require 40 instead of       made more difficult; and disproportion-
35 insurance years and pensions will be            ately high one-off payments in the area
calculated on the basis of the whole work-         of supplementary pensions were cut. By
ing life. Without reductions (6 % a year)          2015, incurring deficits of both the gener-
only those workers who can prove forty             al and the supplementary pension scheme
insurance years can take early retirement          will no longer be covered by state subsi-
(from 60 years of age).4 From 2021 on,             dies. From then on, the government’s fi-
the standard and the early retirement age
will be adjusted every three years accord-
ing to the development of life expectancy.
Two of the previous 14 monthly payments
                                                   5
                                                    		When comparing the estimates of 2008 and
                                                      2011, Greece did best in containing projected
were abolished and replaced by a (largely)            spending increases until 2050: The increase
uniform ‘vacation allowance’ of 800 Euro              would be lowered by 8.7 percentage points
only for pensioners above age sixty. This             (from 24.1 down to 15.4 % of GDP), if the leg-
allowance was cancelled in 2013. In fu-               islated reforms were actually implemented
                                                      (European Commission 2009: 291, 2012a:
ture, the indexation of pensions in pay-              143, 328). During the period 2005 to 2008,
ment must not be higher than the increase             Portugal was ranking first (see below).
in consumer prices; for the period 2011-
                                                   6
                                                    		NDC is the abbreviation of ‘notional defined
                                                      contribution’ and denotes a pension scheme
2014, the adjustment was suspended en-
                                                      that, although still operating on a pay-as-
tirely. Moreover, further measures have to            you-go basis, mimics the working of a fully
be taken if projections show an increase              funded plan with benefits calculated in
of pension expenditure of more than 2.5               quasi-actuarial manner in relationship to
                                                      contributions paid.
                                                   7
                                                    		Already in 2010, monthly pensions above
                                                      1,400 Euro were cut by 8 % and in 2011 those
                                                      greater than 1,000 Euro by 5 to 15 %. “Official
		Several hundreds of professions had been
4
                                                      estimates suggest that pensioners drawing
  listed as ‘heavy’ or ‘hazardous’, implying the      a total pension (…) of EUR 900 per month
  entitlement to a full pension after 35 years        before the crisis suffered an overall reduc-
  of contributions as early as age 55. The 2010       tion of 26 % in 2009-12. The corresponding
  reform stipulated that a revised list must not      reduction for those on a total pension of EUR
  cover more than 10 % of the labour force and        2,100 per month was 34 %” (Koutsogeor-
  a full pension should not be available before       gopoulou et al. 2014: 34). Furthermore, in
  reaching the age of 60 and less than 40 years       2013, only pensions below 1,000 Euro were
  of service.                                         exempted from further progressive cuts.

16            WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
nancial responsibility is restricted to a         monization of the fragmented public pen-
flat-rate basic pension8, which is sched-         sion system (Natali/Stamati 2014: 317-
uled to go into effect the same year (Euro-       8). Until 2007, these attempts were only
pean Commission 2012a: 98; Petmesidou             partially successful, but massive changes
2013: 604).                                       took place between 2009 and 2011, when
     The ‘haircut’, predating another sup-        the creditworthiness of the Italian state
port package for Greece in November               became increasingly endangered. No
2012, deprived the social insurance funds         other country spent more on public pen-
of a large part of its reserves held in Greek     sions at that time (about 15 % of GDP)
government bonds, and the liquidity prob-         (see Jessoula, 2012: 14-20; Ministero
lems of the pension system were aggra-            2012: 41-3). The most important changes
vated due to lower government subsidies           were launched by the ‘technocratic’ Monti
and fewer workers paying contributions.           government in 2011, which, due to sup-
Obligations related to the support pack-          pressed differences between political
age included an immediate increase of             parties, proved able to rapidly pass the
pensionable age to 67 years in 2013, but          reforms through the parliament.
still allowing workers with forty insurance           The harmonization of still occupation-
years to retire at age 62 (with deductions),      ally differentiated pension arrangements
and to cut pensions of retirees, who ben-         was taken further, including an equali-
efited from the previously more generous          zation of contribution rates (Table 2).
calculation formula and/or prematurely            Furthermore, the alignment of women’s
claimed their pension.                            pensionable age with that of men was
     In Italy, the first attempt to contain       speeded up and will be completed in 2018
the steep rise of public pension spending         (in the public sector already realized in
dates back to 1992. In 1995, the basis of         2011 and then – as for all men – raised
the pension system was changed to the             to age 66 in 2012). Besides, the standard
NDC model which, within the framework             retirement age and the age of eligibility
of a lingering pay-as-you-go scheme,              for seniority pensions have been linked to
emulates the working of a fully funded            the development of further life expectan-
plan with quasi-actuarial benefits. All sub-      cy from 2013 onwards. Thus, in 2019 (but
sequent reforms aimed at an accelerated           in 2021 at latest), a pensionable age of 67
implementation of the NDC rules, tighter          years is expected for men and women in
eligibility criteria for so-called ‘senior-       both the private and public sectors, rising
ity pensions’ (which, originally, could be        to just below seventy by 2050. ‘Seniority
claimed after a 35-years insurance period,        pensions’ – hitherto available either after
regardless of age), and advancing the har-        forty years of contributions or at 62 years
                                                  of age after 35 contribution years – are
		An amount of 360 Euro (2010 prices) will
8
                                                  de facto abolished since the conditions
  be taken into account when the individual
  benefit is calculated, but new retirees with    follow the rising age limits while early re-
  fewer than 15 contribution years have to pass   tirement is possible only with deductions
  a means-test.                                   and if the accruing pension level exceeds

                                                                                           17
the social minimum pension by one and         2013. The age range will move from 63
a half times. In contrast, corresponding      to 65 and the required insurance years
increments are expected to result in pen-     from 33 to 35. For unemployed persons
sions that ensure the standard of living      (involuntary early retirement) the condi-
for those who continue working up to the      tions change from age 61 to 63 and 31 to
age of seventy. Considerable short- and       33 insurance years. Premature claiming
medium-term savings arise from acceler-       of benefits goes along with deductions
ated implementation of the NDC system.        (7.5 % per year) while deferring retire-
From 2012 on, new pensions will be cal-       ment age is rewarded with supplements
culated pro rata, according to the contri-    (between 2 and 4 % a year). In future,
bution periods before 1995 in the old (DB)    a ‘full’ pension will require 37 instead of
system and the contribution years under       35 contribution years (while it will still be
NDC rules after 1995. Beginning in 2013,      the case that 15 years qualifies someone
the age-specific coefficients for convert-    for half of a full pension), and from 2022
ing notional assets into a monthly pension    on, pensions will no longer be calculated
are furthermore periodically adjusted to      on the basis of the last 15 but 25 insur-
lower mortality. Finally, the adjustment      ance years (Table 2). Finally, a sustainabil-
of pensions to price development for pen-     ity factor was scheduled to take effect in
sions over 1,400 Euro was suspended for       2027, but the implementation was accel-
2012 and 2013 (Natali/Stamati 2014: 318).     erated once Spain had to apply for loans
    In Spain, there had been a switch from    from the European Stability Mechanism
expansion to consolidation already in         (ESM) in 2012: Beginning in 2019, the
1985, and since 1995 all pension reforms      level of newly awarded pensions will be
have been based on the (repeatedly re-        affected by changes in further life expec-
newed) Toledo Pact between the respec-        tancy at normal retirement age, and there
tive government and the social partners.      will be no return to price indexation of
As a result, between 1998 and 2010, the       pensions in payment. Instead, as of 2014,
Spanish social security system ran sur-       the annual adjustment will be determined
pluses, so that 66 billion Euro (around 6.3   by the scheme’s financial position (ratio
% of GDP) had accumulated in the re-          of contribution revenues to pension pay-
serve fund in 2011. After 2008, the assets    ments) over the past five and (projected)
have been increasingly invested in Span-      next five years, but must not be less than
ish government bonds (Casey 2014: 36-7).      0.25 percent.9
    The most substantial changes of the
                                              		The cumulative effect of the reforms (includ-
                                              9
2011 reform, which will come into force         ing the 2013 legislation) will be well beyond
mainly between 2013 and 2027, include           the calculations presented in the 2012 Age-
a rise in the statutory retirement age          ing Report (see Table 1, row 9). The replace-
                                                ment ratio is expected to drop sharply from
from 65 to 67 for workers showing less
                                                72.4 % in 2010 to 52.1 % in 2030 and further
than 38.5 years of contribution payments.       to 44.9 % in 2060. Instead of a rise (see Table
Early retirement rules have again been          1, row 8), there should be a (small) decline in
tightened (beyond the 2011 legislation) in      the GDP share of public pension expenditure

18           WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
In the wake of an Excessive Deficit       Furthermore, employees of state-owned
Procedure, Portugal negotiated a pen-         enterprises – banks, telecommunications –
sion reform package with social part-         were integrated in the pay-as-you-go pen-
ners in 2007. It included higher pension      sion insurance system and a total of 9.3
decrements for retirement before age 65       billion Euro of the capital reserves of spe-
and strengthened financial incentives to      cial schemes was transferred to the state
continue working beyond that age; the         budget10 and, hence, reduced the present
already legislated pension calculation on     deficit, but increased the unfunded obliga-
the basis of the whole working career was     tions of the general scheme (the so-called
brought forward to 2017; a sustainability     ‘implicit debt’). Finally, in January 2014,
factor was introduced (2008), linking the     the age limit that entitles to an unreduced
level of newly awarded pensions to in-        pension was raised from 65 to age 66. This
creases of longevity; indexing of pensions    cost-saving measure replaces the sustain-
in payment was debased; and normal            ability factor, linking initial pensions to av-
retirement age of public service workers      erage life expectancy, which was declared
rose from 60 to 65 (completed in 2013).       unconstitutional as well as other pension
The combined effects are quite signifi-       cuts (public sector pensions from the old
cant: A comparison of projected pension       scheme larger than 600 Euro). In future,
spending in 2050 on the basis of calcula-     normal retirement age will change along
tions from 2005 and 2008 shows that Por-      with longevity gains.
tugal had taken the biggest leap of all EU
countries. Instead of 20.8 percent of GDP,
only 13.6 percent pension expenditure         3.3 The CEE Countries
was estimated for 2050 (European Com-
mission 2009: 104).                           The parametric pension reforms during
    Therefore, in order to reduce its pub-    the 1990s in Hungary, Romania and Lat-
lic deficit in the short term, Portugal was   via were less a reaction to demographic
obliged to take only a few pension reform     change than to economic transformation.
measures when it sought financial as-         The successive paradigmatic restructuring
sistance in 2011. Benefits were frozen in     of their pension systems followed a wide-
2011 and not fully indexed to inflation in    spread comprehension of ‘privatization’ as
2012. Pensions above a certain threshold      expression of ‘modernization’ (Orenstein
(2011-2013: 1,350 €; 2014: 1,000 €) are       2008; Cerami 2011; Fultz 2012). These
burdened with a special levy rising with      (and further) countries became amena-
income level, and early retirement of em-     ble to the transnational policy campaign
ployed workers is ruled out until 2014        launched by the World Bank. A multi-pil-
whereas older unemployed cannot take out
a public pension before age 62 (Table 2).        Already in 2005, three billion Euro had been
                                              10

                                                 transferred from the capital reserves of the
  in 2060 (9.6 %) compared to 2010 when the      state-owned banks’ special pension scheme
  figure stood at 10.1 % (European Commis-       to cover the deficits of the general pension
  sion 2014: 14).                                scheme.

                                                                                           19
lar pension system including a mandatory        of the second-pillar pension funds were
and fully funded private pillar promised to     ‘confiscated’ and transferred into the state
ensure adequate as well financially sus-        budget, thereby immediately reducing the
tainable old-age security. However, the         deficit and the amount of public debt. The
problems with this new approach came to         entitlements the participants had earned
the fore during the economic slump. Even        in the second pillar were shifted to the
though it triggered significant changes,        first pillar, which increased its long-term
the recession was not the root cause.           obligations (or rather the ‘implicit debt’).
     Hungary was a forerunner to introduce      In order to extenuate the future spending
the multi-pillar pension model. Already         increase, opportunities to retire early via
highly indebted before 2008, it became          disability pensions or due to long service
dependent on international loans as a re-       have been eliminated almost completely,
sult of the economic crisis. The balance-       except for women (Table 2).
of-payment assistance was granted on                 At the onset of the crisis, Romania’s
condition of structural reforms, including      public pension scheme was facing serious
pensions. The package contained a gradu-        challenges: There had been already less
al increase of the standard retirement age      contributors than beneficiaries (Table 1,
(from 62 to 65); a less favourable calcula-     row 4) while the informal economy was
tion of initial pensions and indexation of      (and still is) sizable, thus causing a wide-
current benefits, and the abolition of the      spread contribution evasion (like in Hun-
13th monthly pension payment (Simono-           gary and Greece). After joining the EU,
vits 2011). The newly elected Orbán gov-        Romania has lost a rising number of po-
ernment (2010) rejected further external        tential contributors due to emigration (like
rescue measures and turned to the struc-        Latvia). Moreover, discretionary pension
ture of the pension system for regaining        increases of more than one third in both
fiscal latitude. The pay-as-you-go first pil-   2007 and 2008 and another 13 percent
lar lacked the necessary resources to hon-      rise in 2009 (Ghinararu 2011: 240) proved
our entitlements of present retirees be-        to be largely responsible for the arising
cause eight percentage points of the total      state budget deficit when the country was
contribution rate (33.5 % in 2010) were         hit hard by the recession. Romania had to
diverted into the second pillar. Those          solicit for a twenty billion Euro loan from
shortfalls had to be balanced out of the        the IMF in 2009 but left its recently estab-
state budget, which ultimately led to an        lished and still small second-pillar scheme
increase of public debt. Shortly after com-     intact. It merely postponed the final divi-
ing into office, the government started a       sion of the total contribution rate by one
turnaround which meant a factual aboli-         year. In 2009, Romania even introduced
tion of the multi-pillar system: Contribu-      a modest minimum pension scheme. Re-
tion payments into the second pillar were       forms which started to take effect in 2011
stopped while the contribution revenues         continued along the legislation of the year
of the first pillar were increased accord-      2000 (Ghinararu 2011): Normal retire-
ingly. The already accumulated assets           ment age will increase further (but re-

20           WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
mains lower for women); the years of con-       insurance contributions was lifted from
tribution required for pension eligibility      2009 to 2013. For the same period, the
and for a full pension will rise once more.     adjustment of pensions in payment ac-
Furthermore, pensions of the first-pillar       cording to consumer price changes was
scheme have not been adjusted from 2010         suspended.11 Further immediate savings
to 2012. Between 2021 and 2030, the in-         accrued from the predefined functioning
dexation will gradually shift from hundred      of the NDC-type first pillar: A lower level
percent of inflation plus fifty percent of      of employment (Table 1, row 1), mean-
average real wage increases to pure price       ing fewer contributors, together with a
level changes. The traditionally far more       significantly reduced average earnings
generous special pension regimes for            automatically devaluated the notional ‘as-
government employees are integrated             sets’ available for conversion into a pen-
into the general scheme and, as a result,       sion. Claiming a first pension in 2009 or
benefit levels of different occupational        2011 made up for a difference of more
groups will converge. Finally, the eligi-       than thirty percent – otherwise identical
bility criteria for early and disability pen-   employment careers assumed (European
sions have been tightened and recipients        Commission 2012b: 296). Changes aim-
of early retirement pensions face higher        ing at the long-term sustainability of the
decrements (0.75 % per month instead of         first pillar have been legislated in 2012:
0.5 %). However, an across-the-board re-        Normal retirement age will increase to 65
duction of pensions in payment by 15 per-       while the minimum period required for an
cent, as demanded by the IMF, was ruled         old-age pension will rise to twenty years.
unconstitutionally in June 2010 and hence       Top growth rates from 2011 onwards al-
removed from the reform package.                leviated Latvia’s fiscal problems and al-
     Of all EU member states, Latvia expe-      lowed for a changed division of the total
rienced the most drastic economic slump         contribution rate between the first and
in 2009 (Table 1, row 6). It had to seek        second pillar. In 2016, the partition will
external aid from different lenders as well.    be 14/6 percent and is expected to remain
Thus, the first priority was to ensure the      stable from then on, i.e. it will differ from
financing of pensions in the short run.         the originally planned equal split.
Instead of finalizing the planned split of
contributions between the first and sec-
ond pillar in 2010 (10 percentage points
for each), the rate diverted into the fully
funded second pillar was lowered from
eight to two percent in 2009 in order to         		Another emergency measure – a temporary
                                                11

close the financing gap of the first pillar.       10 percent reduction of all pensions in pay-
According to the NDC rules, this shift im-         ment (70 % for pensioners also earning a
                                                   salary) from July 2009 to end of 2012 – was
plies correspondingly higher first-pillar
                                                   scrapped by the Latvian Constitutional Court
pension entitlements in future. Addition-          in December 2009, and thus the withheld
ally, the limit on earnings subject to social      amounts had to be reimbursed.

                                                                                             21
4. Commonalities and Differences

The severity and duration of the crises        eliminated in 2012 but partly reinstated
varied and left different imprints on EU       by the constitutional court one year later.
members’ state finances and welfare state      A reduced (but still permanent) special
arrangements. Nevertheless, after 2008,        levy (2.0 to 3.5 % instead of 3.5 to 10 %)
the countries studied in this paper have       on public pensions greater than 1,000
legislated similar changes of their pension    Euro will not go into effect in 2015 due to
systems for attaining savings on public        the court’s recent verdict (Fischer 2014).
pension expenditure in the short and long           Short term savings also result from
run. The set of adjustments does not dif-      closing early retirement pathways, tight-
fer much from those reform elements that       ening entry conditions or computing
had been employed before 2008 or in oth-       decrements when the pension is claimed
er countries since the range of options is     prematurely. Such changes happened in
inherently limited – although varying with     all eight countries as was also true for an
the type of the public pension scheme (ba-     increased normal retirement age which,
sic or earnings-related). However, in most     depending on the length of the phasing-in
of the eight countries the magnitude and       period, delivers medium or long term sav-
hence the impact of the post-2008 chang-       ings. However, the target ages set in the
es differ from what was legislated before      CEE countries remain (much) lower than
or from reforms concluded in less troubled     those in Italy, Spain or Ireland. That ap-
countries at the same time in view of ad-      pears comprehensible in view of further
vancing population aging: The pre-2008         life expectancy at age 65 being shorter by
reforms caused less immediate impair-          about three years (Table 1, row 5). Like-
ments of the living conditions of pension-     wise, mainly long-term savings will accrue
ers and workers close to retirement.           from changes of the benefit formulae af-
     Suspended or less favorable indexa-       fecting future claimants. In particular,
tion rules, which came about in all eight      tightening the contribution/benefit link
countries, ease financial troubles of public   as in NDC schemes (Italy and Latvia) or
schemes most rapidly and, due to the base      taking into account more insurance years
effect, will ripple through subsequent         (up to the whole employment career) lead
years, thus yielding further savings (Table    to lower pensions for the newly retired.
2). Nominal cuts of pensions in payment        Whereas NDC schemes operate with
(as recently happened in Hungary, Greece       a built-in life expectancy factor (when
and Ireland) are even more effective but       converting notional ‘assets’), all South-
can also turn out to be problematic. Cor-      ern European countries have introduced
responding legislation has been ruled          a sustainability factor that automatically
unconstitutional in Romania, Latvia and        changes system parameters (normal re-
in Portugal. In the latter country, the 13th   tirement age, number of insurance years
and 14th monthly pension payment was           required for a ‘full pension’ or the initial

22           WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
benefit level) upon longevity develop-            should be even smaller (see also footnote
ments. Moreover, all eight countries have         9 on Spain).
made steps forward to harmonization of                 The financial market crisis of 2008
pension schemes, either by unifying hith-         posed serious problems for countries
erto fragmented schemes in order to save          whose pension system relied heavily on
on administrative costs and/or by remov-          private, fully funded components. In our
ing existent privileges for certain occu-         sample, this was Ireland. Because those
pational groups (such as a lower normal           events – occupational and sovereign pen-
retirement age or higher accrual rates)           sion funds suddenly losing much of their
(see also Natali/Stamati 2014: 323). Pre-         assets – are unpredictable and cannot be
dominantly, those equalizing reforms fo-          ruled out in future, such vulnerability also
cused on public service workers and on            affects the CEE countries where pre-fund-
women when they were still entitled to            ed private pensions were expected to play
a lower pensionable age (however, Hun-            a larger role in the retirement income mix.
gary and Romania remain exceptions in             In the CEE countries, the development of
that respect). In not a single country was        the mandatory second pillar reveals the
the solvency of public pension schemes            specific challenge of transition costs that
strengthened by raising the contribu-             is also known as ‘double payment prob-
tion rate – at least not for employers.           lem’: The younger cohorts (plus the mid-
On the contrary, intended to stimulate            dle-aged workers who voluntarily joined
job growth, their rate was (temporarily)          the second pillar in larger numbers than
lowered in Greece, Ireland, Portugal and          expected) also build up financial assets
Romania12, whereas employees became               for the private component of their retire-
subject to a higher contribution rate in          ment income out of the diverted share of
Ireland, Latvia, and Portugal (2015).             social insurance contributions. However,
    As a result of the intensified reform         for several decades the pension entitle-
activity, the predicted growth in public          ments of present-day retirees and older
pension spending until 2040 will be con-          workers will have to be honored. The
siderably lower as was calculated in the          lowered contribution revenues of the first
2009 Ageing Report (Table 1, row 8; Eu-           pillar are insufficient to meet these obliga-
ropean Commission 2012a: 142-4). Since            tions (Holzmann/Guven 2009: 170, 230-1)
the most recent reforms were not includ-          while a rising gap could be covered out of
ed in the projections, the future increase        the state budget only as long as it was not
                                                  under pressure itself. However, this was
 		A most significant reduction by 5 percentage
12
                                                  exactly the case after the economic slump
   points of employers’ contribution rate from
   previously 20.8 % and 25.8 % for arduous       in 2009 and forced the governments in
   (30.8 % for very arduous) working conditions   Latvia and Hungary (and elsewhere) to
   became effective in Romania in October         take action. The financial market crisis did
   2014. The arising shortfalls have to be cov-
                                                  not only shake the public’s confidence in
   ered by the government and may endanger a
   balanced state budget, unless an enormous      fully funded pensions. It also triggered a
   job growth will be triggered.                  rethinking among political actors in CEE

                                                                                            23
countries, leading to a revision of the im-       different: Selling off Dutch, French and
plemented multi-pillar model, like in Po-         German government bonds and purchas-
land or Slovakia (Orenstein 2011; Drahok-         ing Spanish ones instead, pushed up the
oupil/Domonkos 2012).                             price of the latter and thus stemmed the
     Utilizing pension (reserve) funds for        rise in the interest rate (Casey 2014: 37).
the sake of a currently lower public deficit      That way the costs of servicing the Span-
was not confined to Hungary and Latvia.           ish sovereign debt were kept in check.
Portugal’s government took over the as-           However, the Spanish government will
sets of special pension schemes. Similar-         have to redeem the issued bonds when
ly, in Ireland the reserve funds of certain       the social security system is confronted
public sector pension plans were trans-           with contribution shortfalls due to popu-
ferred to the national budget (the same           lation aging or economic recession. All
happened de facto with the larger part of         in all, whenever governments held a grip
the NPRF) (Casey 2014: 33, 37-8). These           on (pension) reserve funds or mandatory
attempts to meet strict deficit criteria          second-pillar pension schemes, they used
imply that – since earned entitlements            them as a ‘piggy bank’ to reduce budget
were not declared void – an enlarged part         deficits. This is actually a new element of
of future pension payments is moved to            crisis policies that was facilitated by the
pay-as-you-go funding in all four coun-           pension reforms of the late 1990s and
tries, whereas exactly the opposite was           early 2000s. Without doubt, such crisis
originally intended. The effects of the           management shifts enlarged pension ob-
portfolio shift of the Spanish social secu-       ligations into the future.
rity reserve fund after 2008 are not much

5. The Social Impact of Recent Pension Reforms

A look at the income situation of older           ing that the AROP rate for the 65-plus has
people (65+) in 2012 reveals a diverse and        nowhere increased after 2008. Rather, the
surprising picture. The at-risk-of-poverty        rate actually fell – most considerably in
(AROP) rate, meaning less than sixty per-         Latvia (52.0 % in 2008, 13.9 % in 2012).
cent of the weighted median income, is            Such development is mainly due to the
lowest in Hungary, followed by Latvia and         fact that, for example in Ireland, Greece
Ireland. In all countries, except Portugal,       and Latvia, the median income threshold
the AROP rate of the elderly is below that        decreased as a result of unemployment,
of the adult population below age 65 (Ta-         wage cuts and profit setbacks among the
ble 1, row 12). At first glance, it is surpris-   self-employed whereas, at first, pensions

24            WORKING PAPERS 01 / 2015
remained largely stable and indeed func-            clue because the calculations are based
tioned as ‘automatic stabilizers’. The in-          on standardized assumptions regardless
creased GDP share (2007/2010) of public             of the actual prevalence of complete and
pension spending (Table 1, row 8) shows             non-perforated employment careers in a
this quite clearly. Stable or even declined         given country, wage fluctuations over the
AROP rates do not mean that the elderly             life course, or participation in supplemen-
have become more ‘wealthy’. Rather, by              tary pension schemes. OECD data (2013b:
now they have merely incurred smaller               123) show that in Greece and Portugal
income losses than the population of em-            about sixty percent of the retirees receive
ployable age; and those among the elder-            no more than the (contributory) minimum
ly, who received the lowest benefits regu-          pension while in Italy and Spain the same
larly suffered least because direct pension         is true for around thirty percent. The level
cuts or retrenchments via ‘solidarity lev-          of these minimum pensions or targeted
ies’, benefit freezes or the like, when they        benefits (Table 1, row 11) is considerably
occurred, were targeted at retirees with            lower than the standardized ‘replacement
higher pensions.13                                  ratios’. Thus, only limited informative val-
    The altogether not too bleak present            ue should be attached to them.
situation of pensioners (at least in relative            In order to evaluate the living condi-
terms) might change when the reforms                tions of present and future retirees, a few
will take full effect. The downside of con-         further aspects have to be considered. In
taining the long-term growth of public              all eight countries the homeownership
pension spending is lower replacement               rate among the elderly is very high (Table
rates (Table 1, rows 9 and 10).14 These             1, row 13), and few are still burdened with
figures, however, only provide a rough              mortgages. If homeowners’ imputed rents
13
  		In Greece, however, certain professions suc-    are taken into account, income inequality
    cessfully defended their privileges as Mat-     and the AROP rate are generally reduced
    saganis (2012: 416) concludes from a closer     whereas disposable income increases
    inspection of recent pension policy: “The
                                                    (Sauli/Törmälähto 2010; OECD 2013b:
    familiar pattern of powerful groups securing
    for themselves favourable treatment at the      76-87, 104-5). Thus, homeownership may
    expense of less powerful ones reasserted        partially compensate for low minimum
    itself – even under emergency conditions.”      benefits (Table 1, row 11). Effects in the
14
  		The ‘gross average replacement rate’ is
    calculated as the average first public pen-
                                                    opposite direction may emanate from co-
    sion of those who retire in a given year as a   payments when utilizing the health care
    share of the economy-wide average wage at       system. Those individual out-of-pocket
    retirement (European Commission 2012a:          expenses amount to more than one third
    129). The ‘net theoretical replacement rate’
    indicates the first public pension of a hypo-   (Greece and Latvia) or one quarter (Hun-
    thetical average income earner retiring at      gary and Portugal) of total health care
    65 after a contribution period of 40 years as   funding (OECD 2012b: 129). If pension-
    compared to the last wage before retirement
                                                    ers, usually more in need of health care
    (both pension and wage after income tax
    and social security contributions) (European    than younger people, are not exempted
    Commission 2012b: 218, 240).                    from co-payments their disposable in-

                                                                                             25
You can also read