Are asylum seekers more likely to work with more inclusive labor market access regulations? - edoc
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
February 2018 Are asylum seekers more likely to work with more inclusive labor market access regulations? WWZ Working Paper 2018/08 Michaela Slotwinski, Alois Stutzer, Roman Uhlig A publication of the Center of Business and Economics (WWZ), University of Basel. WWZ 2018 and the authors. Reproduction for other purposes than the personal use needs the permission of the authors. Universität Basel Corresponding Author: Peter Merian-Weg 6 Prof. Dr. Alois Stutzer 4052 Basel, Switzerland Tel: +41 (61) 207 33 61 wwz.unibas.ch Mail: alois.stutzer@unibas.ch
Are asylum seekers more likely to work with more inclusive labor market access regulations?∗ Michaela Slotwinski† Alois Stutzer‡ and Roman Uhlig§ March 1, 2018 Abstract In the face of recent refugee migration, early integration of asylum seekers into the labor market has been proposed as an important mechanism for easing their economic and social lot in the short as well as in the long term. However, little is known about the policies that foster or hamper their participation in the labor market, in particular during the important initial period of their stay in the host country. In order to evaluate whether inclusive labor market policies increase the labor market participation of asylum seekers, we exploit the variation in asylum policies in Swiss cantons to which asylum seekers are randomly allocated. During our study period from 2011 to 2014, the employment rate among asylum seekers varied between 0% and 30.2% across cantons. Our results indicate that labor market access regulations are responsible for a substantial proportion of these differences, in which an inclusive regime increases participation by 11 percentage points. The marginal effects are larger for asylum seekers who speak a language that is linguistically close to the one in their host canton. Summary Inclusive labor market access regulations substantially increase the employment chances of asylum seekers, in particular if the language distance is short. Keywords: Asylum policy, asylum seekers, economic integration, employment ban, labor market access regulation JEL classifications: F22, J61, J15 ∗ We are grateful to Christin Achermann, Didier Ruedin, Stefanie Kurt, and Anita Manatschal for helpful comments. Data on labor market access regulations was kindly provided by Denise Efionayi and Didier Ruedin from the Swiss Forum for Migration and Population Studies (SFM). We acknowledge financial support from the Swiss National Science Foundation and its National Center of Competence in Research - The Migration-Mobility Nexus. † University of Basel, Faculty of Business and Economics, Peter Merian-Weg 6, 4002 Basel, Switzerland. Phone: +41 (0)61 207 33 75, email: michaela.slotwinski@unibas.ch. ‡ University of Basel, Faculty of Business and Economics, Peter Merian-Weg 6, 4002 Basel, Switzerland. Phone: +41 (0)61 207 33 61, email: alois.stutzer@unibas.ch. § University of Basel, Faculty of Business and Economics, Peter Merian-Weg 6, 4002 Basel, Switzerland. Email: roman.uhlig@unibas.ch. 1
1 Introduction Refugee migration is likely to challenge Western democracies for years and to spur discussions about humane as well as efficient asylum processes (see, e.g., Hatton 2017 or Hangartner and Sarvimäki 2017 for recent analyses). How asylum seekers make a living features prominently in this debate (see, e.g., Bansak et al. 2016). It colors the discourse beyond the treatment of refugees and seems to affect attitudes towards migrants in general.1 This is because the economic integration of asylum seekers faces a dilemma. On the one hand, there is the concern that easy access to the labor market attracts migrants,2 on the other, restrictive policies preventing early economic integration might lead to high long-term costs for the receiving countries. In fact, a recent study finds large negative effects of a long initial employment ban on long-term labor force participation (Marbach et al., 2017). In order to assess any trade-off, it is thus key to understand how regulation of the asylum process affects the employment of asylum seekers, i.e. the most fundamental resource for economic self-sufficiency. In this paper, we analyze the effect of specific regulations regarding labor market access, social assistance and integration on the labor force participation of asylum seekers, i.e. people who have applied for asylum but have not yet received a decision. The institutional setting in Switzerland is well-suited to learning about conditions fostering or hampering the economic integration of asylum seekers. First, while there is national asylum legislation, the Swiss federal system offers its states (the cantons) substantial discretion in implementation of the law. This results in a significant variation in cantonal practices in integration measures, social assistance, and labor market access regulations, as documented by an in-depth survey undertaken by the Swiss Forum for Migration and Population Studies (SFM) (Wichmann et al., 2011). Second, the evaluation is not hampered by any self-selection of asylum seekers into different cantons, because they are randomly allocated to the cantons and are not allowed to relocate until the end of their asylum application process. Finally, it is very unlikely that asylum seekers look for employment outside the canton they were assigned to, as the probability of finding a position and getting the approval of the other canton is very low.3 We can therefore compare the Swiss cantons as independent, closed economies when it comes to asylum seekers. 1 An analysis in the context of the UK debate on immigration is, for example, provided by Mulvey (2010). 2 Despite its prominence in the policy debate (Mayblin, 2016), in a recent review of the empirical litera- ture only limited evidence has been found for this claim however (James and Mayblin, 2016). Specifically for the Swiss experience, Holzer et al. (2000) offer an evaluation of the asylum policy during the 1980s and 1990s, finding that the more restrictive recognition practice after the urgent federal resolution in October 1990 reduced applications from the traditional origin countries but not for people fleeing from the Balkan conflict. 3 Wichmann et al. (2011, p. 89) report on emerging tensions between cantons if, for example, an asylum seeker from the canton of Basel-Stadt wants to start working in the neighboring canton Basel-Land. 1
In Switzerland as in most Western countries, asylum seekers represent a small fraction of the foreign population,4 but a prominent one in the public debate. During our study period from 2011 to 2014, the employment rate among employable asylum seekers varied between 0% and 30.2% across cantons (with a standard deviation of 6.0%). Our results indicate that labor market access regulations are responsible for a substantial fraction of these differences, whereby an inclusive regime on average increases participation by 11 percentage points. In contrast, the activation and education of asylum seekers in integration programs is a substitute to early employment and related to slightly lower employment rates. We do not find any evidence that more or less generous social welfare payments are related to the take-up of employment. Further, our results indicate that inclusive labor market access regulations are more beneficial for asylum seekers who speak a language that is closer to the language in their canton of residence (the main languages in Switzerland being German, French and Italian). Our findings complement recent work on the economics and politics of refugee migration and integration. In an excellent review, Dustmann et al. (2017) emphasize the important role of the asylum process for economic integration, stating that “clear rules and support mechanisms are needed early on in the migration history, together with fast processing times, fast access to the labour market and active integration programs” (p. 501). Our evidence shows that small policy differences can play a decisive role in the economic inclusion of asylum seekers. Relatedly, Couttenier et al. (2016) report results indicating that more inclusive labor market regulations mitigate the risk that victimized asylum seekers will commit crimes. The effect of foreign citizens’ language skills on the labor market integration of refugees has been studied by Auer (2018). He exploits the random placement of asylum seekers across cantons in Switzerland, and thus across language regions, as a natural experiment. For asylum seekers registered as jobseekers, Auer finds positive effects on the probability of being employed if initial placements include good language matches. In another study exploiting the Swiss institutional setting, Hainmueller et al. (2016) show that long-term employment chances of refugees are substantially reduced when asylum processes take longer. Further, Marbach et al. (2017) show that an extension of the employment ban for Kosovar refugees in Germany reduced their long-term employment prospects. These latter findings underscore the importance of labor market access regulations for asylum seekers. The remainder of our paper is structured as follows. Section 2 describes the institutional setting and provides an overview of the policy options in the asylum process at the sub-federal level. The data used in our analysis are presented in Section 3. Section 4 presents the results of our empirical analyses. Section 5 closes with some concluding remarks. 4 Between 2011 and 2016, on average, 27,190 individuals applied for asylum in Switzerland per year. This amounts to about 0.33% of the Swiss population of permanent residents, including roughly 25% foreigners. 2
2 Institutional setting The asylum process in Switzerland is a shared responsibility of the federal and the cantonal governments. We first describe the framework of the asylum process at the federal level and then highlight the variation in its implementation in the 26 Swiss cantons. The remarks on the institutional setting prepare for our detailed description of the data and the corresponding coding in Section 3. 2.1 Federal asylum process People who seek asylum in Switzerland are initially brought to one of the six accommodation and provisioning centers run by the State Secretariat for Migration (SEM).5 The staff in these centers takes the initial decision on whether an asylum request is to be processed or dismissed. If an application is dismissed under Art. 31a of the federal asylum law (abbr.: AsylG), the applicant is obliged to leave the country.6 If the prerequisites for processing the asylum application are met, the applicants are granted a residence permit N – asylum seeker - for the rest of the asylum process. After a maximum of three months in the accommodation and provisioning centers, the asylum seekers are assigned to one of the 26 Swiss cantons. The asylum seekers have no impact on this allocation process. It is solely determined by an allocation key based on the population size of the cantons according to Art. 21 of the asylum decree 1 (abbr.: AsylV 1). In consequence, this leads to a virtually random allocation. The asylum seekers usually have no opportunity to relocate to other cantons until a final decision about their case is made.7 How long the asylum procedure takes differs widely from case to case.8 If asylum is granted, the applicant receives refugee status with a right to stay (permit B ). If the asylum application is rejected, the SEM 5 These centers (Ger.: Eidgenössische Empfangs- und Verfahrenszentren) are in Basel, Bern, Chiasso, Vallorbe, Kreuzlingen and Altstätten. For a more detailed description of the Swiss asylum procedure visit https://www.sem.admin.ch/sem/en/home/asyl/asylverfahren.html 6 An asylum application will be dismissed if the request is clearly unjustified or abusive. This is often the case if the applicant is able to return to a safe home or third country, or if asylum was already requested in a safe third country under the Dublin Procedure. 7 A change of cantons could be authorized by the SEM in cases of grave danger or family reunion and if both cantons involved give their consent. The right to family reunification usually only includes spouses and minor children/siblings (Hofmann et al., 2014, p. 18). 8 The main focus of recent revisions of the asylum legislation was to reduce the waiting period for asylum seekers. In 2016, the SEM reported that it takes, on average, 174 days until the official hearing for non-Dublin, and non-fast-track procedures, takes place (see https://www.nzz.ch/schweiz/ aktuelle-themen/beschleunigte-asylverfahren-gerechter-guenstiger-schneller-ld.7501). Note that the SEM decides after further hearings on whether asylum is granted. Couttenier et al. (2016, p. 45) mention a period of, on average, about 300 to 400 days for the completion of credible asylum requests between 2008 and 2010. Hainmueller et al. (2016, p. 2) document an average waiting time of 664 days (std. dev. 478 days) in their sample between 1994 and 2004. In extreme cases, applicants had to wait for several years until a final decision was reached (Lindenmeyer et al., 2008, p. 53). 3
has to examine whether it is possible to expel the asylum seeker from Switzerland. There might be humanitarian or technical reasons that prevent an expulsion. In such cases, the residence permit F – provisionally admitted foreigners/refugees (PAFs) - is given. It allows for temporary stay and subsidiary protection. The name of the permit might be confusing, since most PAFs will stay in Switzerland for a long time, if not for life (Wichmann et al., 2011, p. 84). 2.2 Cantonal asylum processes There is a distinctly federal structure in the Swiss asylum system (see, e.g., Belser 2015, Kurt 2017 or Spörnli et al. 1998). The national law leaves the cantons substantial freedom in setting their regulations when implementing the law. This has led to widely different asylum practices across cantons. In particular, the host cantons are responsible for the accommodation of asy- lum seekers, for the promotion of integration, for social welfare (partly financed by the federal government), for support in cases of personal hardship, and for regulation of access to the labor market. In order to understand any variation in the employment of asylum seekers, differences in integration measures, social welfare and labor market access policies are potentially most important. Labor market access Asylum seekers are initially prohibited from participating in the labor market due to a federal employment ban of three months starting with the filing of the asylum application (art. 43 para. 1 AsylG).9 After the ban is over, a potential employer has to apply for a work permit from the cantonal immigration authorities prior to employing an asylum seeker. The differences in cantonal practices mainly result from the conditions and circumstances under which such permits are issued (Wichmann et al., 2011, p. 89). The differences primarily emerge along five dimensions: A first dimension relates to the time asylum seekers are formally excluded from the labor market. Cantons have the right to extend the federal ban of three months to up to six months.10 Second, cantonal authorities can decide to grant work permits exclusively for certain industries with a shortage of labor (mainly agriculture, hospitality, construction and other low-wage sectors). Nearly half of all cantons use such restrictions (Wichmann et al., 2011, p. 89). Third, Art. 21 of the Federal Act on Foreign Nationals (FNA) states that people in the domestic workforce should be given priority on the labor market (in German: Inländervorrang). 9 In principle, the employment ban should account for the time the authorities need to investigate the main motivation behind an asylum request. Thus, there should be no incentive for economic migrants to apply for asylum (Dustmann et al., 2017, p. 513). 10 In a statement from the Conference of Cantonal Directors of Social Affairs (SODK) on a revision of the asylum legislation in 2012, four cantons (AI, JU, UR, ZH) stated that they might lengthen the time of the ban after which asylum seekers can obtain a work permit, while one canton (NW) gave no answer (SODK, 2012, Annex 2). 4
This means that a foreign person can only be employed if a suitable domestic employee cannot be found - a regulation that also applies to asylum seekers (Hofmann et al., 2014, p. 16).11 Cantons differ widely in how strictly they implement this article. According to responses to the survey of Wichmann et al. (2011), there are cantons in which it is necessary to prove that an employment position was posted at the regional employment center but no suitable domestic candidate could be found prior to being able to employ an asylum seeker, while other cantons did not mention such restrictions. An important fourth dimension refers to the duration of the application process for a work permit. While it is rather simple to obtain a permit in some cantons12 , it is a rather complicated process in others (Lindenmeyer et al., 2008, p. 42). Long and complicated application processes are especially unfavorable for asylum seekers, who are more likely to find work in sectors where a quick start of employment is essential. This might be of particular relevance in many of the industries to which the asylum seekers are granted access.13 Fifth, some cantons impose some kind of salary deduction for employed asylum seekers, in order to cover their health insurance and/or rent. This deduction is subtracted on top of a special charge gainfully employed asylum seekers face under Art. 86 AsylG.14 Basic assistance Asylum seekers are generally entitled to social welfare (Art. 81 AsylG). The cantons are respon- sible for the amount and distribution (Art. 82 AsylG). The social benefits are between 40 and 60% lower than the social benefits suggested by the Swiss Conference of Social Welfare (SKOS) for residents (Efionayi-Mäder, 2012, p. 58). The directive envisages that basic assistance is sup- plied in-kind rather than in the form of cash. Most cantons apply a two stage process in which asylum seekers first spend a considerable time in collective housing before being allocated to an apartment. In many cantons, asylum seekers in the early stage of the asylum process get pocket money ranging from 1 to 3 Swiss francs a day. In the second stage, the cash transfer increases to between 320 and 768 Swiss francs per month, the mean transfer lying between 400 and 500 Swiss francs (Wichmann et al., 2011, p. 86). The cantonal expenses for the basic assistance of asylum seekers are covered by the federal government.15 In the year 2012, cantons were compensated with 55.91 Swiss francs per day and asylum seeker, with some adjustments to the costs for rent and health insurance (SODK, 2012, Annex 1, p. 3). An inter-cantonal comparison of basic as- 11 For the future, it is planned to consider PAFs as domestic employees, see https://www.admin.ch/ opc/de/federal-gazette/2016/8917.pdf. 12 For example, cantons like Vaud offer close guidance and information on how to effectively apply for the permits (Wichmann et al., 2011, p. 89). 13 Wichmann et al. (2011, p. 89) document that it takes more than ten days until a permit is granted for asylum seekers in six cantons. In some of them the waiting period is even longer than a month (Lindenmeyer et al., 2008, p. 42). 14 The article states that asylum seekers are obliged to pay a special charge of up to 10% of their salary to cover the cost of the asylum procedure, a possible expulsion, and social assistance. 15 This also applies to PAFs in their first seven years of stay. 5
sistance to the asylum seekers shows strong heterogeneity in its generosity. While some cantons, for example, offer free tickets for public transport and support for exceptional expenses, other cantons only cover basic needs like food, housing, and health insurance (SODK, 2012, Annex 2).16 Integration promotion Since 2008, cantons receive an earmarked lump-sum transfer for every asylum seeker and PAF (“Integrationspauschale” of 6,000 CHF), to cover at least part of the costs of integration measures (Wichmann et al., 2011). There is no federal transfer for the integration of asylum seekers. If projects for the latter group are undertaken, they are financed by the cantons. Some cantons use some of the lump-sums for cross-subsidization, while others refrain from additional expenditures. Wichmann et al. (2011) report that, according to self-statements, eleven cantons dedicate their own resources to the promotion of the integration of asylum seekers. Integration measures, for example, involve basic and advanced language courses, courses for general education, occupation programs, as well as specific integration measures to promote employment-relevant skills, such as (paid or unpaid) internships or job coaches. 3 Data 3.1 Employment rates of asylum seekers Our dependent variable captures the rate of employment of asylum seekers who are employable by canton and country of origin. The rate is measured as of December 31st in the years of 2011 to 2014.17 Figure 1 shows the variation in the participation rate of asylum seekers in paid employment across cantons in 2011 (i.e., the year the regulations are measured). The employment rate was highest in the canton of Grisons (30.2%) and lowest in the canton of Appenzell Innerrhoden, with no asylum seekers employed. Table 1 provides descriptive statistics of the employment rate, once on the canton-year level, and also disaggregated to the canton-year-nationality level, leaving us with 4,014 observations. Employment rates vary substantially across nationalities. Table 3 in the Appendix lists them for asylum seekers from the nine largest nationality groups in Switzerland. While about 30% of the asylum seekers from Sri Lanka were employed in 2011, the corresponding rate for people from Eritrea was 1%. 16 A detailed list of the benefits payed by cantons to asylum seekers can be found in Annex 2 of SODK (2012). 17 The data is publicly available and provided by the SEM. The data for 2011 is available at https:// www.sem.admin.ch/sem/de/home/publiservice/statistik/asylstatistik/archiv/2011/12.html. 6
Figure 1: Employment rates of asylum seekers in 2011 Employment rate 13.9 - 30.2 11.7 - 13.9 8 - 11.7 5.5 - 8 0 - 5.5 Data source: Swiss State Secretariat for Migration. 3.2 Cantonal asylum policies The main explanatory variables on the different aspects of the asylum policies implemented in the cantons are based on unpublished raw data provided by the Swiss Forum for Migration and Population Studies (SFM). The data is based on a survey of representatives of cantonal immigration authorities and is extensively discussed in Wichmann et al. (2011). The cantons Nidwalden and Thurgau did not participate in the survey, leaving us with data for 24 cantons. We define three main measures of cantonal asylum policies: • Labor market access is an index quantifying the openness of the labor market for asylum seekers in a given canton, ranging from 0 (restricted access) to 1 (most inclusive ac- cess). The index captures four aspects: i) the temporal expansion of the employment ban (yes/no), ii) the duration of the work permit process, iii) whether there is restricted access to some sectors or strict application of the priority rule for domestic workers (yes/no), and iv) whether there are additional salary deductions (yes/no). For each aspect, the score is 1 if a canton does not apply an additional restriction and 0 otherwise. For the duration of the work permit process, a canton scores a 0 for a duration exceeding a month, 0.5 for a duration of between 10 and 30 days and a 1 for a shorter duration. The index is calculated as an unweighted average of the scores in the four categories. The labor market is thus considered to be more open, the higher a canton’s score in this index. • Basic assistance is an index quantifying the amount of social welfare and assistance in a canton ranging from 0 (merely basic needs are covered) to 1 (most generous in supplying social welfare). The measure captures six aspects: i) the monthly amount of social welfare 7
Table 1: Descriptive statistics No. of obs. Mean Std. dev. Min Max Dependent variable Disagregated by country of origin: Employment rate 4,014 4.935 15.079 0 100 Employment rate [2011 only] 1,028 5.589 15.848 0 100 Employment rate [in 2011; excluding cantons 1,018 5.644 15.916 0 100 applying an employment ban] Aggregated by canton: Employment rate 96 7.692 6.026 0 30.2 Independent variables Labor market access 24 0.65 0.252 0.167 1 Integration 24 0.507 0.362 0 1 Basic assistance 24 0.554 0.117 0.42 0.75 Control variables Population size [in thousands] 96 324.7 334.0 15.7 1’446.4 Population size, ln 96 12.145 1.146 9.662 14.185 Share of foreign residents 96 21.460 7.14 9.82 40.95 Rate of unemployment 96 2.771 1.26 0.9 6.0 GDP per capita [in thousands] 96 76.6 28.0 50.7 167.0 GDP per capita, ln 96 11.197 0.292 10.833 12.026 Yes-share “against illegal immigration” 96 47.23 8.20 30.3 59.3 Fraction of employment in - catering and lodging 96 5.524 2.649 2.7 14.6 - agriculture 96 4.489 2.86 0.04 12.91 - construction 96 7.883 2.085 4.157 12.038 Fraction of Romance language speakers 96 31.066 36.675 0 94.606 Interaction with language distance Language distance 3,621 0.905 0.084 0.061 1 Note: If not stated otherwise, the data refers to the sample period 2011 to 2014. Data sources: Wichmann et al. (2011), Melitz and Toubal (2014), Swiss State Secretariat for Migration, and Federal Statistical Office. a single asylum seeker receives excluding rent (over 600, between 400-599, or 300-399 Swiss francs), ii) the monthly amout a married couple with two minor children would receive excluding rent (over 1500, between 1250-1499, or 1000-1249 Swiss francs), iii) how the expenses for food, and iv) cloths are covered (cash benefits, vouchers, or in kind), v) how the canton covers health insurance expenses (by handing out the money, or by directly paying for the premium), and vi) whether the asylum seekers receive free tickets for public 8
transport (yes, only after assured necessity, or no). For each aspect, the score of 1 is given if the first (most generous) policy is applied for the respective aspect, a 0.5 for the intermediate cases and 0 for the most restrictive policy. A canton could thus score a maximum of 6 points. The index is calculated dividing the number of points of a canton by the maximum score possible. • Integration is an index quantifying the integration efforts of cantons. It ranges from 0 (the canton does not offer any integration measures for asylum seekers) to 1 (comparatively large number of integration projects). This index captures three aspects: i) what kind of social integration projects are offered for adult asylum seekers (0 points for none, 0.5 points for basic integration measures, and 1 point for advanced integration measures)18 , ii) what kind of professional projects are offered for adult asylum seekers (0 points for none, 0.5 points for courses about the Swiss labor law, individual career counseling or coaching, and 1 point if mentoring projects, internship programs in the private or public sector or advanced trainings on the job are offered), and iii) whether the canton dedicates own resources to the promotion of the integration of asylum seekers (1 point for yes, 0 points for no). A canton could thus score a maximum of 3 points. For the corresponding index, the number of points are again divided by the maximum score possible. Table 1 provides descriptive statistics for the three independent variables. Regarding labor market access, one fourth of the cantons have a rather inclusive regime. These cantons refrain from imposing any further extension of the employment ban, do not restrict employment to specific sectors, apply no additional salary deductions, and have low administrative hurdles when it comes to the employment of asylum seekers. Half of the cantons qualify as applying some form of integration promotion for asylum seekers. None of the cantons in the sample scores the minimum in the index for basic assistance. 3.3 Control variables We incorporate a range of additional variables in our multiple regression analyses in order to capture further determinants of the employment rate of asylum seekers. Moreover, we want to control for factors that might be correlated with the cantonal policies as well as the participation 18 Basic social integration projects include basic language courses, general education courses, courses in civic education, some kind of daily structure schemes and payed or unpayed community work. Advanced integration measures include advanced language courses as well as the promotion of integration in the first or second job market. If a canton offers all of the mentioned basic social integration projects, it receives 1 point as well. 9
of asylum seekers in the labor market.19 We concentrate on six factors: First, possible economies of scale in the economic integration of asylum seekers are captured by the logarithm of the size of the permanent resident population in a canton. The population size is the main variable in the allocation key of asylum seekers and therefore highly correlated with the absolute number of asylum seekers assigned to a canton. Second, we expect that it is more difficult for asylum seekers to find employment in cantons with a tight labor market. We therefore include the cantonal rate of unemployment as an additional explanatory variable.20 Third, as an additional measure for the state of the economy in a canton, we include the logarithm of the GDP per capita. Fourth, in order to control for more specific demand-side factors, we take the industrial composition of a canton into account. We do this by regarding the sectors with a relatively high demand for unskilled workers, i.e. catering and lodging, agriculture and construction. In particular, these are the industries to which some cantons restrict labor market access. We include the size of these three sectors measured as the fraction of employment in percent of total employment in the canton. Fifth, we further include the cantonal foreigner share in the population and a measure for attitudes towards asylum seekers. Together with the size of the construction, and lodging and catering sector, these factors have been identified as the main determinants of cantonal asylum policies (see, e.g., Spörnli et al., 1998). Reservations towards asylum seekers are approximated by the share of yes votes in the popular vote “against illegal immigration” (in German: Volksinitiative ‘gegen die illegale Einwanderung’), which was held in December 1996 and was seeking for a more restrictive asylum law in Switzerland. The latter control factors help us to exclude that any effect we measure is driven by the fact that cantons in which voters hold stronger reservations towards asylum seekers have more restrictive policies and at the same time also employ fewer asylum seekers. The sixth factor captures the proportion of people in a canton who speak a Romance language, i.e. French, Italian or Rhaeto-Romansh. This variable might capture some unobserved cultural differences across cantons in Switzerland. Descriptive statistics for the control variables are provided in Table 1. 3.4 Language distance In order to explore the interaction between access regulation of the labor market and language barriers, we incorporate a variable capturing the language distance (which might well also be correlated with cultural distance). Language distance is an index measuring the closeness of the main language in the country of origin of an asylum seeker to the main language spoken 19 Note that the fact that we observe the policy measures only for one year, i.e. 2011, prevents us from including canton fixed effects in the estimation specification. 20 The corresponding data is provided by the State Secretariat for Economic Affairs (SECO) in their monthly publication on the labor market situation (in German: Die Lage auf dem Arbeitsmarkt) and includes all registered unemployed people in a canton. 10
in the host canton. The index takes a value of 0 if the languages in two places are perfectly congruent and 1 if there is no congruence at all (i.e., the language distance is maximal). The source information is the common language index of Melitz and Toubal (2014).21 4 Estimation model We apply a simple linear model to empirically test whether a less restricted labor market access indeed leads to higher labor market participation of asylum seekers, and whether there are differences resulting from the heterogeneity in basic assistance and integration measures. For the basic estimates on the cantonal level we proceed from the following model: Yc,t = α + τ1 Accessc,2011 + τ2 Assistancec,2011 + τ3 Integrationc,2011 + βi0 X + υt + . Thereby, Yct is the employment rate of asylum seekers in canton c and year t. Access captures the measure for labor market openness, Assistance that for social benefits, and Integration that for integration promotion, respectively. As mentioned above, we additionally control for a set of control variables that might be correlated with the cantonal employment rate as well as the institutional arrangement. These variables are summarized in matrix X and comprise the log of the cantonal population size, the cantonal unemployment rate, the log of the cantonal GDP per capita, the employment shares in the catering and lodging, agriculture and construction industries, the foreigner share, a measure for attitudes towards asylum seekers, as well as the share of the population speaking a Romance language. In the estimates covering several years, we further control for a set of time fixed effects υ. In order to improve the precision of our estimation, we additionally estimate models based on disaggregated employment rates by country of origin and canton. These models additionally include country of origin fixed effects to control for the average level of employment for each nationality. Please note that the estimated effects for the institutional variables should remain stable because the assignment of asylum seekers to cantons is independent of the country of origin and thus exogenous to the cantonal policies. However, if there were any remaining selection driving the empirical findings, this extended specification should strongly change the estimated effects of our institutional variables. The disaggregated employment rates further allow us to explore any interaction effect between labor market access and language distance. Standard 21 Researchers at the French research center CEPII constructed the index on common official and native languages between two countries and the lexical similarity between 200 words of the spoken languages. Our index is modified by one minus the (estimated) common language distance for the country of origin to Germany, France or Italy, respectively, depending on the language spoken by the majority of the population in the host canton. This data is freely available for download at http://www.cepii.fr/ CEPII/en/bdd_modele/presentation.asp?id=19. 11
errors are clustered at the level where we measure our policy variable, i.e. the level of the canton. 5 Results Descriptive evidence Figure 2 shows preliminary descriptive evidence about the potential relationship between la- bor market access regulations for asylum seekers and their employment rate. It visualizes the development of the employment rate of asylum seekers between 2011 and 2014 in the cantons which are grouped by the relative openness of their labor market towards asylum seekers. The dark gray dashed line at the top of the graph represents the six cantons with the most inclusive policies (high openness). These cantons do not have any additional restrictions when it comes to access to the labor market. The group with medium openness indicated by the dashed dotted line comprises fourteen cantons that partly restrict access to the labor market. Finally, the light gray dashed line at the bottom shows the employment rate for the group of cantons with low openness. It is revealed that the employment rates are considerably lower in cantons with low openness. The difference between the group of cantons with the highest openness and the lowest one amounts to about 10 percentage points in 2011. The figure also shows an overall drop in the employment rate for all groups after 2013. Various factors could be responsible for this. One might be a revision of the asylum legislation in 2013, meant to reduce the duration of the asylum process. The pool of asylum seekers in later years thus includes people with a shorter duration of stay in Switzerland, who are more likely to face a binding employment ban and have had less time to seek for work. While this first descriptive finding is interesting, taking into account other potential determinants and confounders can help to evaluate whether it can be interpreted causally. Average effects of cantonal asylum policies Table 2 presents the estimation results when the full range of variation in all three cantonal policy measures is exploited and when potential confounders are simultaneously controlled for. In column (1), using data on the cantonal level between 2011 and 2014, we find that the employment rate of asylum seekers in cantons with the most liberal labor market access policy (index score of 1) is, on average, 11 percentage points higher than in cantons with the most restrictive policy (index score of 0). While taking potential confounders into account, this finding is very similar to the difference observed in the graphical representation. In column (2), we additionally include the two other policy indicators for basic assistance and integration. They barely change the 12
Figure 2: Employment rates of asylum seekers across groups of cantons Notes: This graph visualizes the employment rate of asylum seekers across cantons which are grouped by the openness of their labor market. High openness refers to a group of six cantons with a score for access to the labor market between 0.76 and 1.00. Medium openness includes fourteen cantons with a score between 0.41 and 0.75. Low openness refers to four cantons with a score between 0.00 and 0.40. The lines show the yearly average of the employment rate in each group. Data sources: Wichmann et al. (2011) and Swiss State Secretariat for Migration. coefficient of our main variable of interest. Basic assistance as such is not systematically related to asylum seekers’ labor market participation. In contrast, extended integration programs are related to a 2.6 percentage points lower employment rate of asylum seekers. However, note that the negative effect when in status N does not necessarily mean that integration measures have no positive (long-term) effect on the chance of being employed. Early integration measures initially compete with paid employment and the impact might be slow to take effect but long 13
lasting. Hence, the potentially positive impact would not materialize in the employment rates of asylum seekers, but rather in those of PAFs and refugees. Table 2: Determinants of the employment rate of asylum seekers Dependant variable Employment rate [0-100%] 2011-2014 2011-2014 2011-2014 2011 2011* (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) Mean dep. variable 7.692 7.692 4.935 5.589 5.644 Labor market access [0-1] 10.57*** 12.24*** 10.59*** 11.17*** 10.68*** (2.132) (2.330) (1.803) (3.608) (3.324) Basic assistance [0-1] -3.072 0.273 2.916 5.134 (5.655) (3.266) (4.190) (4.334) Integration [0-1] -2.587* -2.401* -2.551 -3.515* (1.376) (1.305) (1.966) (1.977) Population size, ln -2.186*** -2.084*** -0.556 -0.470 -0.541 (0.656) (0.622) (0.514) (0.965) (0.891) Share of foreign residents 0.166 0.176 0.0313 0.165 0.215 (0.143) (0.154) (0.109) (0.237) (0.218) Rate of unemployment -3.040*** -2.346* -0.061 -1.506 -0.070 (1.132) (1.259) (1.232) (1.982) (2.339) GDP per capita, ln -7.271** -7.462** -2.617 -6.301 -2.767 (2.945) (2.670) (2.745) (4.455) (5.136) Yes-share “against -0.179* -0.180 -0.146* -0.127 -0.015 illegal immigration” (0.100) (0.109) (0.080) (0.113) (0.115) Fraction of employment in - catering and lodging 0.840*** 0.849*** 0.335 0.204 0.383 (0.284) (0.287) (0.229) (0.367) (0.367) - agriculture -1.648*** -1.445*** -0.204 -0.292 0.730 (0.359) (0.404) (0.533) (0.811) (1.137) - construction -0.0654 -0.0594 0.200 -0.0382 -0.265 (0.579) (0.532) (0.512) (0.750) (0.713) Fraction of Romance -0.00266 -0.0233 -0.0244 0.0107 -0.00926 language speakers (0.0298) (0.0338) (0.0348) (0.0539) (0.0554) Year FE Yes Yes Yes No No Country-of-origin FE No No Yes Yes Yes No. of observations 96 96 4,014 1,028 1,018 No. of clusters 24 24 24 24 23 Adj.R2 0.736 0.745 0.181 0.197 0.203 Notes: Columns (1) and (2) use data at the cantonal level, and columns (3) to (5) exploit disaggregated data at the canton-nationality level. * The specification in column (5) is without cantons stating to apply a total ban. Standard errors are clustered at the cantonal level and are reported in parentheses. Significance levels: * .05 < p < .1, ** .01 < p < .05, *** p < .01. Data sources: Wichmann et al. (2011), Swiss State Secretariat for Migration, and Federal Statistical Office. 14
Column (3) presents the resulting estimates using the disaggregated data on the canton- nationality level (including fixed effects for the country of origin). The coefficient of our main variable of interest is now more precisely estimated. Moreover, it remains stable. This result validates that the assignment of asylum seekers is random with regard to nationality and can- tonal asylum policies.22 In column (4), we concentrate exclusively on data from 2011, as our policy measures were only collected in that year, and policies might have changed later on. The coefficient for labor market access again barely changes. Finally, to check whether our results are driven by the fact that one canton reports not granting labor market access to refugees at all, we exclude this canton in column (5).23 The effect remains very similar. Our setting does not allow us to include fixed effects for cantons in order to control for unob- servable cantonal characteristics, as the policy measures were only collected for one year. This might, of course, pose a challenge to the causal interpretation of the results presented. If there are unobserved factors correlated with both the employment rate of asylum seekers and the labor market access granted by the cantons, our results might be biased. However, we control for those factors that are most likely to partly determine employment and asylum practices, i.e. the size of the economy relying on low-skilled workers, the foreigner share, the state of the economy, and general attitudes towards asylum seekers (Spörnli et al., 1998). The results show that the partial correlation between labor market access and the employment of asylum seekers is robust to their inclusion. Overall, we find a sizeable positive effect of an open labor market policy on the employment rate of asylum seekers. We can exclude that our main result is driven by a self-selection of asylum seekers into cantons, which is the main concern for the identification of the effect of labor market access policies. Moreover, the observation that the coefficient of interest hardly changes from specification to specification further supports our interpretation of a causal relationship. Interaction between the effect of labor market access and language distance After finding that a more open-access type of regulation increases asylum seekers’ employment rate, we explore whether there is heterogeneity in the effect of openness depending on the language distance between the language spoken in the country of origin and the one spoken in the canton the asylum seeker is assigned to. To give an impression of language distances, for example, a person from Kongo DR or the Ivory Coast assigned to a French speaking canton would face a language distance of 0.875, while somebody from Georgia in a French speaking canton would be confronted with a language distance of 0.974. 22 The exogeneity of the assignment of asylum seekers to cantons has also been validated, for example, by Couttenier et al. (2016). 23 The information is from a statement in the section “travail” in the report of the SODK 2012. 15
In an extended estimation model, we interact the variable labor market openness with language distance. The sample is now restricted to asylum seekers from those countries for which infor- mation about language distance is available. The estimation results are reported in Table 4 in the Appendix. The main finding is summarized in Figure 3. It shows the marginal effects of an open labor market for different levels of language distance when the whole range of distance measures in our sample is considered (based on the coefficients reported in column (1) of Ta- ble 4). While the marginal effects are overall positive, we observe a clear negative relationship with increasing language distance, i.e. the greater the language distance, the lower the positive effect of labor market openness on asylum seekers’ employment rate. This seems intuitive, as for them it is likely more difficult to interact and to integrate in a company, and they can potentially be employed only for a more limited range of tasks. We undertake a few robustness checks as language distance is unequally distributed in our sample. Figure 7 in the Appendix shows a histogram for the distribution of language distances, revealing that only a few observations are characterized by a very short language distance. The mass of observations lies at values of 0.7 and above. To make sure that our finding is not driven by these potential outliers, we repeat our estimate excluding the lowest 5 percent and the lowest 10 percent of observations in terms of language distance. The results are reported in columns (2) and (3) in Table 4, and the marginal effects are visualized in Figures 5 and 6 in the Appendix, respectively. The relationship remains rather stable and the systematic negative interaction also remains, suggesting that the positive effect of a liberal labor market access policy is strongest for asylum seekers facing a relatively short language distance. 6 Conclusion Many Western countries struggle with the integration of refugees into the labor market (Fasani et al., 2017). This is not only a tragedy for the migrants themselves, who might be living in a precarious economic situation and miss opportunities for meaningful engagement. It is also a threat to social cohesion in the host countries, as it might challenge the support for redistribution. Recent evidence on employment bans shows that the absence of economic integration in an early phase of the asylum process can have large negative effects on long-term labor market participation (Marbach et al., 2017). In the absence of employment bans, there are potentially many other factors that affect the economic integration of asylum seekers. However, there is little quantitative evidence about what determines employment take-up during the initial phase of stay in the host country and how effective any regulation of participation is. This is probably due to the lack of high-quality data and the difficulty of comparing different asylum policies across jurisdictions. 16
Figure 3: Marginal effects of an inclusive labor market access regime for different levels of language distance Notes: This figure visualizes the marginal effect of the interaction between labor market access and language distance for the whole sample. In order to make the graph readable, we only visualize it for the top 90% of language distances. The graph for the complete range can be found in Figure 4 in the Appendix. For a language distance of 0.875 (bottom quartile), the marginal effect of an open labor market amounts to a 10.92 percentage point higher employment rate. The corresponding figure for a high language distance of 0.974 (top quartile) is 6.13 percentage points. The corresponding estimates are reported in column (1) of Table 4 in the Appendix. In our analysis, we focus on the early economic integration of asylum seekers and provide a macro evaluation of the experiences in Swiss cantons applying different asylum policies. We thus learn about the effects of asylum policies from the institutionalized trial and error process in the Swiss federal system (Mahnig and Wimmer 2003; Gundelach and Manatschal 2017). We can rely on detailed information about labor market access regulations, integration measures, and social welfare provisions for asylum seekers across Swiss cantons. All these policies are developed to implement the same federal law. Furthermore, in our setting a potential self- selection of employable asylum seekers into regions where employment is easier can be excluded, 17
as asylum seekers are exogenously assigned to their canton of residence (and are normally not allowed to move to a different canton). We find that during the period between 2011 and 2014, with a medium inflow of asylum seekers, cantons offering the most inclusive access to their labor market are able to successfully integrate many more asylum seekers into the local economy, as reflected in a 11 percentage point higher employment rate compared to cantons with the most restrictive regime. Integration programs compete in the short-run with employment and reduce its rate among asylum seekers by 2.6 percentage points. We do not find a systematic effect on participation in the labor market related to the incentives generated by specific provisions regarding social welfare. The immediate effects of an inclusive regime are found to be greater for asylum seekers originating from a country where the main language is relatively closer to the one in their host canton. While language skills are important per se for successful economic integration, they seem to work in a complementary manner to the inclusive labor market access regulations. Employment during the asylum process might be related to systematic long-term consequences for those asylum seekers who are granted refugee status. Employment experience seems partic- ularly valuable if asylum seekers have gone through a lengthy application process. According to the results in Hainmueller et al. (2016), the penalty of a one year longer process on the probabil- ity of being employed (a year after getting refugee status with subsidiary protection) is about 5 percentage points. They further find that employment during the application phase is a strong predictor of later employment. Employment in the year before the decision increases the like- lihood of employment in the subsequent year by 48 percentage points. Further, in the German context, Marbach et al. (2017) document that being exposed to a 7-month longer employment ban during the application period reduces the employment probability after admission by about 20 percentage points. Thus, our findings are particularly important if the admission of asylum seekers or their temporary stay is likely (a conclusion very similar to that in a recent report of the OECD 2016). Our results and considerations lead to several follow-up questions. First, we would like to better understand the conditions under which efforts to integrate asylum seekers into the labor market at an early stage of the asylum process lead to an increase in the inflow of asylum seekers. This is a pressing issue in the political discourse. Second, one might ask what motivates the different regulations of labor market access across cantons. What is the political economics behind it? And third, there are the interactions with migration policy more generally. In particular, it would be important to understand how inclusive labor market access regulations moderate the perception of asylum seekers and attitudes towards immigration. These issues must be left to future research. 18
References Auer, D. (2018). Language Roulette - The Effect of Random Placement on Refugees’ Labour Market Integration. Journal of Ethnic and Migration Studies 44 (3), 341–362. Bansak, K., J. Hainmueller, and D. Hangartner (2016). How Economic, Humanitarian, and Religious Concerns Shape European Attitudes Toward Asylum Seekers. Science 354 (6309), 217–222. Belser, E. M. (2015). Das föderalistische Migrationsrecht der Schweiz - vom Umgang mit Einheit und Vielfalt bei der Gestaltung einer Verbundaufgabe. In Europäisches Zen- trum für Föderalismus-Forschung Tübingen (EZFF) (Ed.), Jahrbuch des Föderalismus 2015: Föderalismus, Subsidiarität und Regionen in Europa, pp. 117–132. Baden-Baden: Nomos. Couttenier, M., V. Preotu, D. Rohner, and M. Thoenig (2016). The Violent Legacy of Victim- ization: Post-Conflict Evidence on Asylum Seekers, Crimes and Public Policy in Switzerland. CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP11079. Dustmann, C., F. Fasani, T. Frattini, L. Minale, and U. Schönberg (2017). On the Economics and Politics of Refugee Migration. Economic Policy 32 (91), 497–550. Efionayi-Mäder, D. (2012). Asylpolitik und mögliche (Des)Integrationseffekte. In M. für Inte- gration Baden-Württenberg (Ed.), Integrationspolitik im internationalen Vergleich - Beiträge zum internationalen Symposium des Ministeriums für Integration Baden-Württenberg an der Albert-Ludwigs-Universität Freiburg, pp. 57–61. Fasani, F., T. Frattini, L. Minale, et al. (2017). The (Struggle for) Labour Market Integration of Refugees: Evidence from European Countries. CReAM Discussion Paper Series No. 1716. Gundelach, B. and A. Manatschal (2017). Ethnic Diversity, Social Trust and the Moderating Role of Subnational Integration Policy. Political Studies 65 (2), 413–431. Hainmueller, J., D. Hangartner, and D. Lawrence (2016). When Lives are Put on Hold: Lengthy Asylum Processes Decrease Employment Among Refugees. Science Advances 2 (8), e1600432. Hangartner, D. and M. Sarvimäki (2017). Dealing with the Refugee Crisis. Background Report for Finland’s Economic Policy Council. Hatton, T. J. (2017). Refugees and Asylum Seekers, the Crisis in Europe and the Future of Policy. Economic Policy 32 (91), 447–496. Hofmann, A., K. Buchmann, and M. Trumme (2014). Fluchtland Schweiz. Informationen über das Asylrecht und Menschen im Asylverfahren (6 ed.). Bern: Schweizerische Flüchtlingshilfe SFH. 19
Holzer, T., G. Schneider, and T. Widmer (2000). The Impact of Legislative Deterrence Mea- sures on the Number of Asylum Applications in Switzerland (1986-1995). The International Migration Review 34 (4), 1182–1216. James, P. and L. Mayblin (2016). Factors Influencing Asylum Destination Choice: A Review of the Evidence. University of Sheffield, Asylumwelfarework.com, Working paper No 04/16.1. Kurt, S. (2017). A Modest Start: Integration Policies in the Field of Asylum. E-Magazine of the nccr - on the move. Highlights #2 , 12–16. Lindenmeyer, H., B. von Glutz, F. Häusler, and F. Kehl (2008). Arbeitsmarktintegration von Flüchtlingen und Vorläufig Aufgenommenen. Studie über erfolgversprechende Faktoren. Zurich: KEK-CDC Consultants Zürich. Mahnig, H. and A. Wimmer (2003). Integration without Immigrant Policy: The Case of Switzer- land. In F. Heckmann and D. Schnapper (Eds.), The Integration of Immigrants in European Societies. National Differences and Trends of Convergence, pp. 135–160. Stuttgart: Lucius & Lucius. Marbach, M., J. Hainmueller, and D. Hangartner (2017). The Long-Term Impact of Employment Bans on the Economic Integration of Refugees. Stanford-Zurich Immigration Policy Lab Working Paper No. 17-03. Mayblin, L. (2016). Complexity Reduction and Policy Consensus: Asylum Seekers, the Right to Work, and the ’Pull Factor’ Thesis in the UK Context. The British Journal of Politics and International Relations 18 (4), 812–828. Melitz, J. and F. Toubal (2014). Native Language, Spoken Language, Translation and Trade. Journal of International Economics 93 (2), 351–363. Mulvey, G. (2010). When Policy Creates Politics: The Problematizing of Immigration and the Consequences for Refugee Integration in the UK. Journal of Refugee Studies 23 (4), 437–462. OECD (2016). Making Integration Work. Paris: OECD Publishing. SODK (2012). Asylgesetzrevision (10.052): Unterstützungsleistungen der Kantone im Asylbere- ich. Online at http://sodk.ch. Spörnli, M., T. Holzer, and G. Schneider (1998). Diener dreier Herren? Kantonalbehörden und die Vollzugsvielfalt der arbeitsmarktlichen Bestimmungen im schweizerischen Asylrecht. Swiss Political Science Review 4 (3), 53–77. 20
Wichmann, N., M. Hermann, G. D’Amato, D. Efionayi, R. Fibbi, and D. Ruedin (2011). Les marges de manoeuvre au sein du fédéralisme: La politique de migration dans les cantons. Bern: Commission fédérale pour les questions de migration. 21
Appendix Table 3: Employment rates of asylum seekers from the most common countries of origin Rank Number of Employment rate [0-100%] employables 2011 2012 2013 2014 overall Eritrea 1 11,298 1.17 0.78 1.19 0.37 0.72 Sri Lanka 2 5,842 31.68 33.36 27.45 13.38 27.75 Syria 3 5,480 8.79 7.63 4.85 1.45 4.84 Afghanistan 4 4,517 6.6 6.25 8.22 4.67 6.77 China 5 3,965 1.12 1.45 2.91 4.46 2.5 Turkey 6 2,423 11.32 8.91 8.06 9.3 9.45 Iran 7 1,952 10.71 7.53 9.02 7.67 8.81 Nigeria 8 1,871 0.15 0 0 0 0.05 Tunesia 9 1,645 0.76 0.21 0 0.79 0.49 Others 19,745 4.58 2.98 3.82 3.37 3.69 Note: The number of employable people captures the total number of asylum seekers from a given country of origin between the ages of 18 and 65 who were allocated to one of the 26 cantons between the years 2011 and 2014. Data source: Swiss State Secretariat for Migration. 22
You can also read