THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO TAXATION AND EMPLOYMENT IN INDONESIA - Health, Population, and Nutrition Global Practice - World Bank Document

Page created by Leon Osborne
 
CONTINUE READING
THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO TAXATION AND EMPLOYMENT IN INDONESIA - Health, Population, and Nutrition Global Practice - World Bank Document
Public Disclosure Authorized                             Public Disclosure Authorized   Public Disclosure Authorized   Public Disclosure Authorized

                                                        THE

                    Global Practice
                    Health, Population, and Nutrition
                                                        ECONOMICS
                                                        OF TOBACCO

                                                        EMPLOYMENT
                                                        IN INDONESIA
                                                        TAXATION AND
THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO TAXATION AND EMPLOYMENT IN INDONESIA - Health, Population, and Nutrition Global Practice - World Bank Document
Cover photos (clockwise from left): Hand holding green tobacco leaf. Photo by bdspn / iStock. Smiling Asian
lady. Photo by joakimbkk / iStock. Gateway on the road to oil palm plantations. Photo by Flore de Preneuf /
World Bank. Man in crop of tobacco plants. Photo by ribeiroantonio / iStock.
THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO TAXATION AND EMPLOYMENT IN INDONESIA - Health, Population, and Nutrition Global Practice - World Bank Document
THE
ECONOMICS
OF TOBACCO
TAXATION AND
EMPLOYMENT
IN INDONESIA
Health, Population, and Nutrition
Global Practice
THE ECONOMICS OF TOBACCO TAXATION AND EMPLOYMENT IN INDONESIA - Health, Population, and Nutrition Global Practice - World Bank Document
SMOKING HAS
BEEN A MAJOR
CONTRIBUTOR TO
THE DISEASE BUR
IN INDONESIA.
SMOKING
PREVALENCE AM
WORKING-AGE
INDIVIDUALS HA
EXCEEDED 30
LIST OF ACRONYMS
BPJS   Badan Penyelenggara Jaminan Sosial
FGD    Focus Group Discussion
FT     Full-time
FTE    Full-time Equivalent
GDP    Gross Domestic Product
KIS    Kartu Indonesia Sehat
KKS    Kartu Keluarga Sejahtera
KPS    Kartu Perlindungan Sosial
NCD    Noncommunicable Diseases
PBI    Penerima Bantuan Iuran
PPP    Purchasing Power Parity
Rp     Indonesian Rupiah
SKM    Machine-made kretek
SKT    Hand-made kretek
SPM    White cigarettes
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
Indonesia has one of the most complex cigarette excise tax structures in the world.
The current cigarette excise tax is divided into 12 tiers, which are based on manufacturers’
type of cigarettes, the number of cigarette productions, and per-unit retail price. The tiers
in the cigarette excise tax structure aim to accommodate small-scale cigarette firms, espe-
cially hand-rolled kreteks (SKT) firms. The rationale for such a structure is that smaller SKT
firms account for more than half of the total factories in the tobacco industry. Moreover,
these firms are responsible for employing a significant share of the workers in tobacco
manufacturing. Such a system favors downward substitution to lower priced products and
has a limited impact on smoking reduction.

This report aims to contribute to the policy debate over the tobacco excise tax
reform and, specifically, any effects it might have on employment in Indonesia. It
uses data from the Central Bureau of Statistics to observe the trends in employment and
output in the tobacco sector and estimate the potential impact on tobacco employment
(gross effect) from raising cigarette taxes in Indonesia.

The report shows that tobacco manufacturing represents only a small share of
economy-wide employment (0.60 percent). Additionally, the contribution of tobacco
manufacturing to employment in the manufacturing sector is quite small (5.3 percent) in
comparison to the contribution of the food (27.43 percent), garment (11.43 percent), and
textile (7.90 percent) sectors. Although small, tobacco manufacturing jobs are heavily con-
centrated, with about 94 percent of tobacco manufacturing workers in Central Java, East
Java, and West Nusa Tenggara. In these provinces, several districts are quite dependent
on tobacco sector employment, for example, Kudus (30 percent), Temanggung (27.6 per-
cent), and Kediri (26 percent).

We found that most tobacco manufacturing workers are females and unskilled.
The share of female workers in tobacco manufacturing is 66 percent, which is the highest
in the manufacturing industry. Other sectors in which most workers are female are the
garment sector (63 percent) and textiles sector (56 percent). About 69 percent of total
workers in the tobacco sector completed at most, junior high school. Among tobacco
households, the share of tobacco households with female tobacco workers is 78 percent.
Average years of schooling completed by tobacco manufacturing workers is among the
lowest at 8.22 years, which is comparable to the average years of schooling completed by
workers in the food processing sector (8.50 years), manufacturing of wood products sec-
tor (7.31), nonmetallic metal products sector (7.42), furniture sector (8.77), and recycling
sector (5.20).

Tobacco households are partially dependent on income from tobacco employment,
which represents 60 percent of household income, on average. Additionally, among
these households, only 9 percent have a female as the primary income earner. These find-

4 // Executive Summary
ings from secondary data (the Sakernas data) are consistent with the ones from the World
Bank/ACS kretek workers survey in Indonesia—the proportion of wage income from kretek
is 54 percent and the share of female tobacco workers as primary earner is about 10 per-
cent (World Bank, 2017a).

Productivity of tobacco sector workers, measured by the output per worker, is rela-
tively low in comparison to productivity of workers in the comparable sector. A typi-
cal worker in the medium and large tobacco firms can produce IDR 104 million (US$7,761)
worth of products annually. For comparisons, a typical worker in the food and drink, and
textile industries can produce IDR 265 million (US$19,776) and IDR 300 million (US$22,388)
worth of products respectively.

The estimated output elasticity of labor demand for the cigarette manufacturing
sector is 0.160. This means that a 1 percent decrease in output results in a 0.16 percent
decrease in employment in the cigarette manufacturing sector. On the other hand, the
estimate for the tobacco processing sector implies that a 1 percent decrease in output
corresponds to a 0.092 percent decrease in employment in the tobacco processing sector.

We predict that raising cigarette taxes by an average of 47% and simplifying the
cigarette tax structure to 6 tiers will reduce cigarette demand by 2 percent, increase
government revenue by 6.4 percent, and reduce gross employment in tobacco
manufacturing sector by less than 0.50 percent. That means that a reduction of 2,914
tobacco manufacturing jobs, most of them in the SKT industry (2,245 less jobs). Given the
additional revenues government will obtain with the reform (IDR 10,915 billion), there is
scope to implement measures to reduce the impact on the tobacco workers’ livelihoods
(such as cash transfers or expanded access to social safety nets) or to find alternative occu-
pations for the workers affected (retraining programs, educational grants, etc.).

The evidence presented in this report clearly shows that the gross employment
impact of reforming tobacco excise taxes and structure in Indonesia is not as big as
previously thought. Analyses presented here are complemented by other evidence pre-
sented in the World Bank/ACS Indonesia Tobacco Studies, which highlighted the economic
and social costs of tobacco workers’ and farmers’ livelihoods. Given the additional reve-
nues the government will obtain with the reform (IDR 10,915 trillion), there is an oppor-
tunity to implement measures to reduce the impact on the tobacco workers’ livelihoods
(such as cash transfers or expanded access to social safety nets) or to find alternative occu-
pations for the workers affected (retraining programs, educational grants, etc.).

It is important to note that these estimates represent the gross employment effect
of lower cigarette consumption. When prices of cigarettes increase, consumers may
shift their consumption to other goods and services which will create jobs in these sec-
tors. Evidence has shown that the job losses in the tobacco sector (gross effect) are usually
compensated with job creation in the other sectors (net effect). For Indonesia, Ahsan and
Wiyono (2007) estimated positive effects varying from 84,340 to 281.153 jobs with tax
increases of 25 percent and 100 percent, respectively (Ahsan and Wiyono, 2007).

                                                                                            5
•   For kretek hand-rollers

    o    First, the most vulnerable groups in the affected population who would need
    immediate income support in the event of job loss include the workers who are less
    educated, older, heads of their households, and who contribute a significant pro-
    portion of total household income from kretek rolling. The government can provide
    income support to these workers with less than 2% of the revenue gained from a tax
    increase; and

    o    The government (Ministry of Finance and Ministry of Social Affairs) should provide
    temporary income support using the existing Social Assistance programs (such as
    the unconditional cash transfer program, Bantuan Langsung Sementara Masyarakat
    - BLSM) and identify alternative employment or income-generating opportunities in
    the affected regions. The re-training of laid-off kretek workers should be designed to
    accommodate transitions into these alternative employment opportunities.

•   For (tobacco and clove) farmers:

    o    The government should help to improve supply chains and value chains for
    other goods in tobacco-growing areas. Many former tobacco farmers are making
    a better living growing other common, locally grown crops (e.g., corn, sweet potato,
    and green vegetables), an outcome that could be further enhanced with even small
    investments by governments in improved supply chains for these products. Results
    from the World Bank/ACS survey suggest that current tobacco farmers are already
    growing many of these crops, so it is an issue of shifting their factors of production to
    maximize economic opportunity.

     o The government should help to facilitate access to credit for tobacco
    farmers. Greater access to capital through improved credit schemes could help to
    improve the possibilities for tobacco farmers to cultivate other crops and/or develop
    other nonagricultural economic enterprises. That could be in the form of grants or
    low-interest loans to farmers willing to move away from tobacco cultivation; and

    o    Specifically, on clove farmers, it is important to emphasize that clove
    farming is not particularly profitable for most clove-producing households in
    at least a couple of major clove-producing districts. The government needs to
    research which alternatives could be viable and target the least profitable areas for
    switching and help these farmers make successful transitions to growing other crops
    and/or economic activities.

6 // Executive Summary
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The preparation of this report was carried out under the World
Bank Global Tobacco Control Program coordinated by Patricio
V. Marquez, with the support of the Bill & Melinda Gates
Foundation and the Bloomberg Foundation.

The report is part of the Indonesia Tobacco Employment Studies
and was prepared by a team comprised of:

  Gumilang Aryo Sahadewo (Research Faculty Universitas Gadjah Mada
  and Consultant World Bank);
  Roberto Iglesias (Director, Center of Studies on Integration and
  Development, CINDES, Brasil);
  Edson C. Araujo (Senior Economist and Task Team Leader, World Bank);
  Nigar Nargis, PH.D. | Scientific Director, Economic and Health
  Policy Research
  Pandu Harimurti (Senior Health Specialist and Task Team Leader,
  World Bank);
  Jeffrey Drope (Scientific Vice-President, American Cancer Society)
  Qing Li (Senior Data Analyst, American Cancer Society);
  Josefine Durazo (Survey Specialist, World Bank);
  Firman Witoelar (Director of Research, SurveyMeter); and
  Bondan Sikoki (Chairperson, SurveyMeter).

The report greatly benefited from comments, inputs, and advice provided
by Violeta Vulovic (Economist, World Bank), Frank Chaloupka (Professor,
Institute for Health Research and Policy, University of Illinois, Chicago),
Jeremias N. Paul (Coordinator of Tobacco Control, WHO) and Michael Weber
(Senior Economist, World Bank).

                                                                              7
TABLE OF CONTENTS

List of Acronyms                                                             3
Executive Summary                                                            4
Acknowledgments                                                              7
List of Tables                                                               9
List of Figures                                                              9

1. Introduction                                                             11

2. The Economics of Tobacco Taxation                                        15
      2.1 — Tobacco Consumption, Health Outcomes, and Economic Costs        15
      2.2 — Tobacco Taxes and Tobacco Consumption                           17
      2.3 — Tobacco Taxation and Tax Revenues                               18
      2.4 — Employment Impacts of Tobacco Taxation                          19

3. Cigarette Tax Policies in Indonesia                                      27
      3.1 — Effects of Cigarette Consumption, Revenues, and Employment      29

4. Employment in the Indonesian Tobacco Sector                              35
      4.1 — Data Sources                                                    35
      4.2 — 23 Employment in the Indonesia Tobacco Farming Sector           36
      4.3 — Employment in the Tobacco Manufacturing Sector                  38

5. Simulations on the Effects of Raising Cigarette Taxes on Employment      51

6. Conclusion                                                               61
References                                                                  63
Annex I. Estimation of the Wage Equation                                    67
Annex II. Sample Selection Procedure for the Manufacturing Industry Data 68
Annex III. Estimation of Output Elasticity of Labor Demand                  70
Annex IV. Estimation of Price Elasticity of Demand                          72
Annex V. Simulation of the Effects of Raising Cigarette Prices on Employment 74

8 // Table of Contents
List of Figures
     Figure 1. Trends of the Cigarette Excise Tax in Indonesia in real terms, 2010–2017             29
     Figure 2. Revenue from the tobacco excise, 2005–2015                                           31
     Figure 3. Trends of cigarette production in Indonesia, 2010–2016                               32
     Figure 4. Number of tobacco farmers and share of tobacco farmers to total workers, 1990–2011   37
     Figure 5: Number of medium and large tobacco manufacturers, 2000–2014                          40
     Figure 6. Share of tobacco employment to total manufacturing employment, 2014                  41
     Figure 7. The concentration of tobacco manufacturing workers, 2014                             42
     Figure 8. Number of workers per firm by industry                                               43
     Figure 9. Productivity of workers, 2000–2014                                                   47
     Figure 10. Relationship between output and labor in medium and large industry, 2000–2014       47

List of Tables
     Table 1. Selected studies on net employment impact of tobacco control policies                 21
     Table 2. Type of external tobacco trade and likely net employment impacts                      22
     Table 3. Cigarette excise tax in Indonesia, 2017                                               28
     Table 4. Distribution of tobacco farmers across regions, 2014                                  38
     Table 5. Distribution of clove farmers across regions, 2014                                    39
     Table 6. Employment structure of the Indonesian tobacco industry, 2014                         40
     Table 7. Concentration of workers in selected districts, 2014                                  43
     Table 8. Characteristics of tobacco sector workers, 2011, 2013, and 2015                       44
     Table 9. Estimation results of the wage equation, 2001–2015                                    46
     Table 10. Estimation of own-wage and output elasticity of labor demand, 2000–2014              48
     Table 11. Analysis of the 2018 Cigarette Excise Tax Regulation                                 52
     Table 12. Simulations on the effects of the 2018 Tax Law on excise revenue                     53
     Table 13. Estimated number of workers in each tax tier                                         54
     Table 14. A hypothetical government scenario                                                   56
     Table 15. The effects of raising taxes on revenue: a hypothetical government scenario          57
     Table 16. The effects of raising taxes on employment: a hypothetical government scenario       58
     Table 17. The effects of raising taxes on employment: World Bank and ACS scenario              59
     Table 18. Summary statistics, National Labor Force Survey Sample                               67
     Table 19: Selected sample, Annual Survey of Manufacturing Industry                             68
     Table 20: Summary statistics, Annual Survey of Manufacturing Industry                          71
     Table 21: Estimation of price elasticity of cigarette demand, 2015                             73

                                                                                                    9
SMOKING HAS
 The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

BEEN A MAJOR
CONTRIBUTOR TO
THE DISEASE BUR
IN INDONESIA.
SMOKING
PREVALENCE AM
WORKING-AGE
INDIVIDUALS HA
EXCEEDED 30
 10 // Table of Contents
1
    INTRODUCTION
    Smoking has been a major contributor to the disease burden in Indonesia. Smoking
    prevalence among working-age individuals has exceeded 30 percent since 2001. In 2013,
    smoking prevalence among males was 66%, while among females was 6.7%. Smoking
    prevalence among children ages 10–14 in 2013 was 3.7%, twelve times higher than in
    1995 (IAKMI, 2014; Ahsan, 2015). Diseases attributable to smoking include hypertension,
    acute respiratory infection, coronary heart disease, cardiovascular diseases, selected can-
    cers, and perinatal disorders (IAKMI, 2014; Kosen et al., 2012; Kristina et al., 2015). In 2013,
    healthy years lost at the population level due to smoking-induced diseases was estimated
    to be 6.2 million disability-adjusted life years or DALY (IAKMI, 2014).

    The government of Indonesia continues its efforts to reform the cigarette excise
    tax system. The main objectives of the excise tax reform are to reduce smoking preva-
    lence and to increase tax revenues. Studies suggest that a 10 percent increase in cigarette
    excise tax would lead to a reduction in cigarette consumption by 0.9 to 3 percent and an
    increase in government revenue by 6.7 to 9 percent (Hidayat and Thabrany, 2010; Setyo-
    naluri et al., 2008). Currently Indonesia has one of the most complex cigarette tax struc-
    tures in the world, which favors downward substitution to lower priced cigarettes (World
    Bank, 2015). Cigarette prices across all tiers increased at a modest rate between 2010 and
    2017 as the government continued to increase cigarette taxes; nevertheless cigarette
    prices were more affordable in recent years than they were in 2000 owing to a faster
    income growth (NCI-WHO, 2017). The main argument against adopting such a complex
    cigarette tax structure was to protect employment by differentiating firms with different
    production scales with those that employ more workers, such as hand-rolled kreteks (SKT)
    workers.

    Despite the concerns, tobacco manufacturing represents only a small share of
    the economy-wide employment (0.60 percent). Additionally, the contribution of the
    tobacco manufacturing to employment in the manufacturing sector is quite small (5.3
    percent) in comparison to the contribution of the food (27.43 percent), garment (11.43
    percent), and textile (7.90 percent) sectors. Although small, tobacco manufacturing jobs
    are heavily concentrated in Central Java, East Java, and West Nusa Tenggara, where about
    94% of tobacco manufacturing workers are employed. In these provinces, several districts
    are quite dependent on sector employment, as for example Kudus (30 percent), Temang-
    gung (27.6 percent), and Kediri (26 percent). A tax change shock that affected the tobacco
    sector would affect these districts most.

                                                                                                       11
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

The objective of this report is to analyze the recent employment trends in the
Indonesian tobacco industry and estimate the potential effects of raising cigarette
taxes on employment in the tobacco manufacturing sector. The report provides new
evidence to contribute to the ongoing debate about the effects of raising cigarette taxes
on tobacco sector employment. It complements the current analytical work conducted
by the World Bank, in partnership with the American Cancer Society, to explore the
employment conditions and livelihoods of tobacco and clove farmers and kretek rollers in
Indonesia. The report is part of the World Bank technical assistance to the government of
Indonesia in the areas of revenue policy reform and health systems reform.

This report is structured as follows: Section two provides a review of the global
evidence on the impacts of raising cigarette taxes on population health outcomes
and on the economy. It briefly reviews the economic issues around tobacco taxation,
including a summary of the global evidence on the effects of taxation on smoking reduc-
tion, fiscal revenues, tobacco production and employment in the sector. Section three
presents an overview of the cigarette tax reforms in Indonesia in recent years and dis-
cusses the government of Indonesia’s plans for reforming the cigarette tax structure. Sec-
tion four discusses the employment trends in the tobacco industry in Indonesia, analyzes
workers’ characteristics and compares workers to similar sectors and socio-demographic
profiles. The section also discusses the potential impacts of raising cigarette taxes on
employment by presenting results of simulations. The final section, section five, discusses
the results in light of the current debate over cigarette tax reform in Indonesia and pro-
vides policy recommendations on the employment aspects of the reform.

12 // Introduction
13
SMOKING HAS
BEEN A MAJOR
CONTRIBUTOR TO
THE DISEASE BUR
IN INDONESIA.
SMOKING
PREVALENCE AM
WORKING-AGE
INDIVIDUALS HA
EXCEEDED 30
2
    THE ECONOMICS OF
    TOBACCO TAXATION
    Raising cigarette prices through taxes is a cost-effective way to reduce cigarette
    consumption as recommended by the World Health Organization Framework Con-
    vention on Tobacco Control (WHO FCTC, 2003). The objective of raising cigarette taxes
    is to decrease consumption of cigarettes through higher prices.1 Additionally, raising cig-
    arette taxes can increase government’s tax revenues, which can be allocated to finance
    complementary tobacco control policies and social investments such as health and
    education. Experiences in both high and low-and middle-income countries (LIMCs) show
    how tobacco tax revenues can be used to expand health care coverage. In France, for
    example, tobacco tax revenues are used to supplement the funding for public health ser-
    vices. In Philippines, higher tobacco and alcohol tax revenues have been used to expand
    health coverage for the poor. On the other hand, the tobacco industry argues that lower
    consumption of tobacco products due to higher tobacco tax can have negative effects
    on production and, consequently, on employment. This section presents a summary of
    the global evidence on the impacts of tobacco consumption on population’s health and
    the impacts of tobacco taxation on fiscal revenues and employment.

    2.1 Tobacco Consumption, Health Outcomes, and Economic Costs
    Smoking is a major cause of morbidity and premature mortality. Tobacco consump-
    tion has been directly linked to diseases of the circulatory system (e.g., ischemic heart
    and cerebrovascular diseases); cancers of the trachea, bronchus and lung, esophagus,
    oropharynx, larynx, stomach, liver, pancreas, kidney and ureter, cervix, bladder, colon/
    rectum, as well as acute myeloid leukemia; chronic respiratory diseases (e.g., asthma,
    chronic obstructive pulmonary disease); and metabolic diseases such as diabetes mel-
    litus (U.S. Department of Health and Human Services, 2014). Besides the harm of direct
    consumption, it has been proven that secondhand smoking (sometimes referred to as
    passive smoking, environmental tobacco smoke, or tobacco smoke pollution) also has
    damaging health consequences. Secondhand smoking is quite dangerous because there
    are at least 50 carcinogenic chemicals inhaled by those who are around smokers, and the

    1 We use the term cigarette taxes and tobacco taxes interchangeably because cigarettes are a major form of tobacco product in
    Indonesia.

                                                                                                                                    15
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

scientific evidence shows that there is no safe level of exposure to secondhand smoking
(US NCI-WHO, 2016). The World Health Organization (WHO) estimates that approximately
7.2 million deaths per year worldwide are attributable to smoking, more than 6 million of
those deaths are the result of direct tobacco use, while around 900 000 are the result of
non-smokers being exposed to second-hand smoke (WHO, 2017a). Half of these deaths
occurred in LMICs. By 2030, the annual death toll could reach 10 million if no tobacco
control measures are taken (WHO, 2008).

Smoking is one of the major risk factors for noncommunicable diseases (NCD)
deaths. NCDs kill 40 million people each year, which is equivalent to 70% of all deaths
globally. Each year, 15 million people die from a NCD between the ages of 30 and 69
years; over 80% of these premature deaths occur in LMICs (WHO, 2017b). Worldwide,
approximately 14% of adult deaths from NCDs are attributed to tobacco use, includ-
ing 10% of all adult deaths from cardiovascular diseases (14% among men, 6% among
women), and 22% of all adult deaths from cancer (32% among men, 11% among
women). The clear majority (71%) of adult lung cancer deaths (78% among men, 53%
among women) were attributable to tobacco. In addition, 36% of all adult deaths from
diseases of the respiratory system were attributable to tobacco (42% among men, 29%
among women) (WHO, 2012). Tobacco smoking is also an important risk factor for chronic
obstructive pulmonary disease (COPD). In 2004, about 49% of the COPD deaths among
adult men and 34% of COPD deaths among adult women were attributable to tobacco
(WHO, 2012).

NCDs have become a major public health concern in Indonesia. The WHO estimates
that the proportional mortality due to NCDs has increased from 50.7% in 2004 to 71% in
2014 (WHO, 2014). Tobacco smoke is the fourth risk factor that contributes to most death
and disability combined from NCDs, after dietary risks, high blood pressure, and high fast-
ing plasma glucose (IHME, 2017). In 2012, NCDs accounted for more disability-adjusted
life years (DALYs) than communicable diseases—approximately 476 million and 240 mil-
lion DALYs, respectively (WHO, 2014).

Smoking is also responsible for deaths from communicable diseases. Approximately
5% of global deaths from communicable diseases are attributed to tobacco, including
7% of all deaths due to tuberculosis (TB) and 12% of deaths due to lower respiratory
infections (WHO, 2012). A systematic review of the literature found a significant positive
relationship between exposure (passive or active) to tobacco smoke and TB infection and
disease, independent of various potential health issues including alcohol use and socio-
economic status (Salma et al., 2007). Recurrent TB and mortality resulting from TB were
also associated with active smoking. This relationship is particularly important in Indo-
nesia, given that the country has one of the highest TB infection rates in the world and
where tuberculosis is one of the top causes of death (USAID, 2009).

16 // The Economics of Tobacco Taxation
The risk of death due to smoking declines with the length of time from an individ-
ual quits smoking. In other words, the sooner one quits smoking, the longer she/he will
live. Studies have been conducted for the United States (Burns et al., 1997), India (Jha et
al., 2008), and Germany (Neubauer et al., 2006) that have provided a quantitative relation-
ship between the length of smoking, smoking cessation, and benefits of quitting smok-
ing concerning mortality, showing that the reductions in relative risk of heart disease and
stroke are more immediate than the effects on respiratory disease and cancer. Due to the
lengthy time lags for the development of cancers and chronic respiratory diseases asso-
ciated with tobacco smoking, deaths from these illnesses in LMICs may continue to rise,
even if smoking prevalence remains the same or decreases (US NCI and WHO, 2016).

Smoking imposes a substantial economic burden on countries due to increased
health care costs and worker’s productivity losses. Goodchild and colleagues (2016)
measured the economic costs of smoking in 152 countries, representing 97% of the
worldwide smoking population. They considered direct costs related to health care
treatment and indirect costs from productivity losses due to tobacco-related premature
mortality and morbidity. The estimated total economic cost of smoking was equivalent in
magnitude to 1.8% of the world’s annual gross domestic product (GDP) in 2012 and 40%
in LMICs. Of those, 76% are indirect costs related to productivity losses due to morbidity
(35%) and premature mortality (65%). The direct health care costs were estimated at pur-
chasing power parity (PPP) $467 billion (PPP international dollars), which is equivalent to
5.7% of global total health expenditures. The findings from this study highlight the urgent
need to implement comprehensive tobacco control measures to reduce the economic
costs of smoking.

2.2 Tobacco Taxes and Tobacco Consumption
Increasing tobacco and cigarette taxes reduces consumption and, consequently,
can reduce smoking-attributable mortality and morbidity. The impact of tobacco
taxation on the reduction of mortality depends on (i) the magnitude of the price increase
resulting from a tobacco tax increase, (ii) the reaction of consumers to price changes,
that is the price elasticity of demand,2 which is related to smoking behavior (initiating,
reducing intensity, or quitting), and (iii) the relationship between mortality and quitting
smoking. The price of tobacco products in relation to income, i.e. affordability, also mat-
ters on initiation decisions, intensity, or quitting.3 Empirical studies in high- and low- and
middle-income countries have found a negative relationship between cigarette prices

2 Technically, the price elasticity of demand is the percentage change in the consumption of a product in response to a 1% change in
the price of the product, with all else remaining constant.
3 To be effective in reducing tobacco demand, tax and price increases need to be significant to counteract the effect of income
growth on tobacco demand and reduce affordability.

                                                                                                                                  17
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

and smoking. Once prices increase, smokers adjust their decision of consuming through
quitting or smoking reduction. Additionally, higher prices, due to a higher tax, act as a deter-
rent for new smokers, particularly among the youth or the poor. In high-income countries
(HICs), price elasticity estimates are clustered around –0.4 percent (IARC, 2011). In LMICs
also show a negative price-elasticities of tobacco demand, ranging from –0.1 to –1.0, with
estimates clustered around –0.5 percent (John et al., 2010; Jha and Chaloupka, 2012; Szabo
et al., 2016). In other words, in HICs, a 10 percent increase in the price of tobacco is expected
to decrease tobacco consumption by 4 percent. In LMICs, a 10 percent increase in price
would be expected to decrease tobacco consumption by 5 percent (IARC, 2011). A recent
global simulation study shows that an 80 percent increase in excise per pack may lead
to 42% increase in price, reduce global annual cigarette consumption by 18 percent and
global smoking prevalence by 9 percent (Goodchild, Perucic, and Nargis, 2016).

Studies also show that smoking reduction after a tax increase has positive impacts
on individual and public health. Several studies show the health benefits of quitting
smoking due to tax increases (John et al., 2010; Blakely et al., 2015; Goodchild, Perucic and
Nargis, 2016; Szabo et al., 2016). A recent systemic review of studies, published in English
between 2000 and 2012, also concludes that tobacco taxation is a highly cost-effective
policy, because the costs of intervention are minimal and significantly save health care
costs after the tax increase implementation, although many health benefits of quitting
take time to materialize (Contreary et al., 2015).

2.3 Tobacco Taxation and Tax Revenues
Tobacco and cigarette excise taxation can also be efficient sources of fiscal reve-
nue. Given that tobacco demand is relatively inelastic, due to consumer addiction and
the lack of close substitutes, tobacco taxes can generate considerable amounts of tax rev-
enues, particularly if sales are large. Tobacco taxes may also create fewer distortions in the
markets than would result from taxes on goods and services with more elastic demand.
Also, given the small number of producers, tobacco taxes are relatively easy to collect
at low administration and enforcement cost, as compared to general consumption and
income taxes. Experiences in numerous countries indicate that an increase in tobacco
taxes will increase nominal (as well as real) tax revenues in the short to medium terms.

The magnitude of tobacco and cigarette tax revenue that a government can gen-
erate largely depends on the tax system and the demand characteristics. Given a
certain income level, per capita or total, a country’s tobacco excise revenue depends on:
(i) the level of taxation per unit of tobacco product (either as percent of the price or abso-
lute amount of tax per pack); (ii) the number of different tax tiers; (iii) the price elasticity
of tobacco demand; and (iv) the volume of tobacco sales. Normally, low levels of tobacco
excise revenues are associated with low levels of taxation per unit of product (Chaloupka

18 // The Economics of Tobacco Taxation
et al., 2012). Different tax tiers, such as in Indonesia, allow producers to reduce their tax
burden, expanding production through less taxed products. Also, smokers could avoid
higher rates by switching to lower taxed cigarettes. The result may be lower revenues
than potentially anticipated. The more inelastic the demand, the more government rev-
enues can be generated with a certain tax rate increase. With an inelastic demand, the
proportional reduction in cigarettes purchased by the consumer after the tax increase is
smaller than the proportional increase in tax revenue. As the price elasticity of demand
increases in absolute value, the possibility to raise revenues for a given tax rate change
decreases. Finally, the volume of tobacco sales will determine the possibility of revenue
expansion, given certain demand elasticity and percent changes on the taxation level.

Tobacco taxes are likely to remain high after a significant tax increase, even with
a considerable decline in tobacco use. Chaloupka et al. (2012) argue that over time,
inflation will erode the value of tobacco tax revenues, unless those taxes are increased
often enough to keep pace with inflation. Similarly, as tobacco use declines in response
to other tobacco control efforts, revenues from tobacco taxes will also decline, unless
taxes are increased periodically. Nevertheless, it is possible that tax revenues may remain
higher many years after a significant tax increase than they were before, even in the wake
of a considerable decline in tobacco use. For example, in the case of California, tax rates
increased by 770% between 1989 and 1999, while cigarette sales declined by more than
60% between 1989 and 2010, and tobacco excise revenues increased from US$250 mil-
lion before 1989 up to US$845 million in 2010 (Chaloupka et al. 2012). In Brazil, the excise
tax amount per cigarette pack was increased in real terms by 81.4% between 2011 and
2015, while total cigarettes sales decreased by 35% in the same period. However, real
excise revenues in 2015 were still 17% higher than in 2011 (Iglesias, 2016).

2.4 Employment Impact of Tobacco Taxation
Despite its effectiveness in reducing tobacco consumption and increasing tax rev-
enues, there is often a debate over the effects of tobacco tax employment in the
tobacco industry. The tobacco industry generates jobs in diverse parts of the economy,
including farming, manufacturing, and wholesale sectors. However, it is important to
differentiate the employment that is from core-tobacco sectors (directly dependent on
tobacco production, such as farming and manufacturing) compared to tobacco-related
employment (jobs that are just partially dependent on tobacco, such as retail). Historic
analyses of the tobacco industry show that the industry has significantly reduced employ-
ment because, over time, the industry has become more capital intensive and farming
has become more efficient, so that job losses have occurred even in the absence of
tobacco control measures (NCI-WHO, 2017). The tobacco industry has sponsored studies

                                                                                                19
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

to document the employment contribution of the sector. Usually these studies argue
that tobacco control measures, such as higher taxation, would result in job losses in the
tobacco industry and, consequently, increase unemployment (Zhang, 2002).

In contrast, most academic studies have shown that tobacco control policies, such
as taxation, have an overall neutral or positive impact on employment. Zhang (2002)
argues that the (industry-sponsored) studies use unrealistic assumptions about impacts
of sales drop, overestimate the number of jobs associated with the tobacco industry and,
consequently, overestimate the possible negative impact of tobacco control measures on
overall employment. However, the main problem is that those studies do not consider:
(i) the expansionary employment effect of consumption substitution of smokers who
redirect their expenditure toward other products after the tax increase—tobacco expendi-
tures do not disappear from the economy; rather, they are redistributed to the consump-
tion and production of other goods and services; and (ii) the expansionary employment
effect of higher public expenditure after the tax increase.4

Studies simulating the impacts of tobacco control policies on employment depend
on key assumptions. For example, studies applying input–output models first estimate
the change in final consumer demand for goods and services resulting from a tobacco
control policy (US NCI and WHO, 2016). The change in demand is composed of two com-
ponents: (i) the reduction of tobacco consumption, and (ii) the expansion of expenditures
in other products, according to consumers (smokers) preferences. These studies then
calculate the induced changes in outputs based on input–output tables that describe the
flow of goods and services within the economy. Finally, changes in outputs are converted
into changes in employment to obtain the employment impacts. The critical assump-
tions these studies rely on are: the impact of tobacco control measures—estimated price
and income elasticities in the case of tax increases; and, more importantly, the type of
consumption substitution that smokers display after the tax increase or tobacco control
measure. The normal assumption is that ex-smokers would follow the average expendi-
ture pattern or the most recent quitter expenditure pattern. If other selected goods and
services have a larger direct and indirect employment input than tobacco product
production, the net employment effect is positive.

The challenge to measure the employment impacts of higher tobacco taxes is
that employment losses could be relatively concentrated, whereas employment
gains tend to spread throughout the economy. Table 1 presents a selection of recent
independent studies in low- and middle-income countries (LMICs). Under the assump-
tions discussed above, four out of the six studies resulted in net employment gains after

4 This expansionary effect depends on fiscal policy decisions; greater public revenues do not mean automatically higher public
expenditures.

20 // The Economics of Tobacco Taxation
Table 1: Selected studies on net employment impact of tobacco control policies

 STUDIES            MODEL AND ASSUMPTIONS                                                                  CONCLUSIONS

 South Africa       Static input–output model                                                              Net gain of 50,236
                                                                                                           jobs occurred in 1995
 Van der Merwe      Domestic consumption expenditures were eliminated, and the rate of consumption
                                                                                                           by eliminating tobac-
 and Abedian,       decline in 1995 doubled.
                                                                                                           co expenditures, with
 1999               Expenditures were allocated by recent quitter and average expenditure pattern.         consumers acting as
                                                                                                           recent quitters and with
                                                                                                           the same government
                    Government spending was reduced or kept at the same level by increasing other taxes.
                                                                                                           spending

 Zimbabwe           Static input–output model

 Van der Merwe,     Domestic consumption expenditures and tobacco production in 1980 were eliminated.
                                                                                                           Net loss of 87,798 jobs
 1998                                                                                                      in 1980, and 47,463 jobs
                    Average input–output pattern changed, and all tobacco production was shifted to        when all output went to
                    alternative agriculture products.                                                      alternative agriculture
                                                                                                           products
                    Because of increases in other taxes, no change in government spending occurred.

 Bangladesh         Static input–output model

 Van der Merwe,     Domestic consumption expenditures and all tobacco production for tobacco products
 1998               and bidis in 1994 were eliminated.
                                                                                                           Net gain of 10,989,192
                    Average input–output pattern changed, and all tobacco production was shifted to        jobs in 1994
                    alternative agriculture products.

                    Because of increases in other taxes, no change in government spending occurred.

 Bulgaria           Static input–output model

 Petkova and        Domestic consumption expenditures and tobacco production in 1999 were eliminated.
 colleagues,                                                                                               Net loss of 5,567 jobs
 2003               Average input–output pattern changed, and all tobacco production was shifted to        in 1999
                    alternative agriculture products.

                    Because of increases in other taxes, no change in government spending occurred.

 Egypt              Static input–output model

 Nassar and         Domestic consumption expenditures and tobacco production in 1999 were eliminated.
 Metwally, 2003                                                                                            Net loss of 5,567 jobs
                    Average input–output pattern changed, and all tobacco production was shifted to        in 1999
                    alternative agriculture products.

                    Because of increases in other taxes, no change in government spending occurred.

 Indonesia          Static input–output model                                                              Net gain of 84,340 jobs
                                                                                                           with a 25% tax increase;
 Ahsan and          Percentage increases of 25%, 50%, and 100% occurred in the cigarette tax.              net gain of 140,567 jobs
 Wiyono, 2007                                                                                              with a 50% tax increase;
                    Expenditures were allocated by the average expenditure pattern.
                                                                                                           and net gain of 281,135
                                                                                                           jobs with a 100% tax
                                                                                                           increase

Source: National Cancer Institute and World Health Organization (2017), Table 15.3, page 560.

                                                                                                                           21
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

tobacco control policies. Generally, the net effects were not significant, except in the case
of Bangladesh and Egypt. Reductions occurred in core tobacco sectors, including tobacco
farming and manufacturing; in tobacco-related sectors, such as wholesaling and retailing;
and in ancillary sectors, such as the paper and pesticide industries. The net gains
in employment depended on several factors, such as: the assumed structure of
population (smoker) consumption; the production structure of the economy, i.e., the
extent to which final products, inputs, and services were produced domestically or
imported in the tobacco industry and in the industries where ex-smokers would spend
their money; and the labor intensity of tobacco growing/manufacturing versus the rest
of the industries composed of the average consumer expenditures. For example, Ahsan
and Wiyono (2007) found that, in Indonesia, the top five sectors that would experience
increased employment include rice, tea, coffee, sugarcane, and root crops, which have
higher labor intensity than tobacco growing (Ahsan and Wiyono, 2007)

Table 2: Type of external tobacco trade and likely net employment impacts

 TYPE OF EXTERNAL               MEANING                                LIKELY EMPLOYMENT IMPACTS
 TOBACCO TRADE THAT A
 COUNTRY HAS

 Net exporter of tobacco        Production of tobacco leaf and         Domestic tobacco demand is not the only determinant
 products                       cigarettes is higher than domestic     of production/employment in the core sectors.
                                consumption                            Drop of domestic tobacco demand could be compen-
                                                                       sated with production directed to external markets,
                                Tobacco employment distribution        and employment effects could be minimized.
                                in domestic sales or exports would     The relative effects of global and domestic policies
                                depend on the share of exports to      depends on the share of production that is exported.
                                total sales

 Balanced tobacco economy       Domestic production of tobacco         Domestic tobacco control policies may have negative
                                leaf or cigarettes is used primarily   net employment effects. Smoking prevalence and
                                for local consumption. Self-suffi-     size of control policy could be important for absolute
                                cient in tobacco                       impact on net employment.

 Net importers of tobacco       Produce less tobacco leaf or ciga-     Tobacco control policies in countries with small
 products                       rettes than they consume               tobacco/cigarette production may increase overall
                                                                       employment. Not affected by global tobacco demand.

 Mixed tobacco economy          Significant grower and producer,       U.S. is an example: tobacco leaf producer, importer
                                and imports and/or exports a sub-      and exporter of large amounts of tobacco leaf.
                                stantial share of tobacco leaf and     Changes in both domestic and global tobacco control
                                tobacco products                       policies would affect employment.

Source: Own elaboration based on US NCI and WHO (2016).

22 // The Economics of Tobacco Taxation
The possible employment impacts varied depending on whether the country was
a net exporter or net importer of tobacco leaf. When tobacco control policies reduced
the demand for cigarettes, a country was likely to have lower employment losses if that
country imported a significant percentage of the cigarettes smoked and/or leaf used
to make them, and domestically produced a large portion of the rest of the products
included in the average consumption expenditure. Conversely, the more the tobacco
leaf and other inputs and cigarettes were nationally grown and/or produced relative to
the local content of the things people buy instead, the greater is the likelihood that there
was some employment losses locally. The higher the production diversification of the
economy, the higher was the domestic employment created by the demand switch from
tobacco toward other products. In contrast, the higher the expenditure on tobacco and
the lower the sectoral diversification of domestic production, the smaller (or even neg-
ative) was the net employment impact. The United States National Cancer Institute (US
NCI) and the WHO published a report that presented a classification of countries and the
likely employment impacts, based on a country’s situation in terms of tobacco trade: net
exporter, net importer, balanced economy and mixed situation (US NCI and WHO, 2016).
As shown in Table 2, domestic tobacco control policies likely had a larger impact in coun-
tries with a balanced tobacco economy—self-sufficient in tobacco, because the employ-
ment destruction reduction of tobacco demand could not be offset.

Decline in tobacco consumption as a result of taxation or tobacco control policies
may occur gradually. Although most of the studies presented in Table 1 assume a sharp
and total reduction in cigarette consumption, smoking prevalence reduction occurred
gradually even when a significant tax increase was implemented in the short term.5
Tobacco control policies normally gradually reduce smoking, distributing adjustment
costs through time and diluting them in decades (US NCI and WHO, 2016). The adjust-
ment costs of labor-intensive segments of the industry, such as tobacco farming, depend
on the existence of viable alternatives. In many LMICs, such as Brazil and the Philippines,
tobacco farmers are diversified, producing other crops, which may facilitate the transition
to other crops. The result from the World Bank/ACS survey on the economics of tobacco
farming unequivocally demonstrated that former tobacco farmers were growing many
of the same crops as current tobacco farmers, and were simply increasing production of
these crops. Moreover, these former tobacco farmers were typically generating higher
revenues and incurring lower costs than their neighbors and peers who continued to
grow tobacco.

5 The Philippines, for example, increased the excise taxes for the cheapest cigarettes by 341% in a one-year period that resulted in a
decline of tobacco use prevalence by approximately 20% Global Adult Tobacco Survey (GATS).

                                                                                                                                     23
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

The employment issue has lost preeminence in the debate of tobacco control
policies in many countries. Since the first half of the last decade, there have been few
studies about the employment effect of tobacco control policies from either side of
the debate; instead the debate has concentrated on other issues, such as illicit trade in
tobacco products. For example, in the recent Brazilian experience of large increases of
tobacco taxes (2011–2016), effects on employment were not an issue, because the export
share of leaf production in the country increased. In the Philippines (2012 onward) poten-
tial employment impact was a big issue during Congressional deliberations, but since
80% of tobacco leaf was exported, the Ministry of Finance recognized that the employ-
ment impact risk on tobacco farmers was low. Furthermore, a budget was also allocated
to help those that may be adversely affected—15% of the incremental tobacco tax reve-
nues was allocated to tobacco farmers to encourage them to shift to alternative crops.

24 // The Economics of Tobacco Taxation
25
SMOKING HAS
BEEN A MAJOR
CONTRIBUTOR TO
THE DISEASE BUR
IN INDONESIA.
SMOKING
PREVALENCE AM
WORKING-AGE
INDIVIDUALS HA
EXCEEDED 30
3
    CIGARETTE TAX POLICIES IN
    INDONESIA
    Indonesia has one of the most complex cigarette excise tax structures in the world.
    The current cigarette excise tax system has 12 tiers, which are based on manufacturers’
    types of cigarettes, the scale of cigarette productions, and per unit retail price.6 There are
    three types of cigarettes: machine-made kreteks (SKM), machine-made white cigarettes
    (SPM), and hand-rolled kreteks (SKT).7 Manufacturers of either SKM or SPM are considered
    as a Class I if they produce more than 3 billion cigarettes annually and as a Class II if they
    produce less than the 3 billion cigarettes. On the other hand, manufacturers of SKT are
    considered a Class I if they produce more than 2 billion cigarettes annually, a Class II if
    they produce between 500 million to 2 billion cigarettes annually, and a Class III if they
    produce less than 500 million cigarettes annually.

    Excise taxes for cigarettes produced by larger manufacturers increased at a modest
    rate between 2010 and 2017 (Figure 1). As shown in column 4 of Table 3, the excise
    taxes for machine-made kreteks (SKM, Class I) and white cigarettes (SPM, Class I) increased
    by 27 and 46 percent, respectively in real terms between 2010 and 2017. Note that
    changes in the tariffs for the small-scale manufacturers were relatively smaller compared
    to changes for the Class I SKM and SPM manufacturers. For example, excise taxes for Class
    II SKM manufacturers increased 24 percent while excise taxes for Class II SPM manufactur-
    ers increased 35 percent. It is important to note that tax increases that occurred have not
    been enough to reduce cigarette affordability. The US NCI and WHO show that cigarettes
    in Indonesia were much more affordable in 2013 than they were in 2000 (US NCI and
    WHO, 2016).

    The tiers in the cigarette excise tax structure aimed to accommodate small-scale
    cigarette firms, especially SKT firms. The rationale for such a structure was to protect
    smaller SKT firms that accounted for more than half of total factories in the tobacco indus-
    try (column 5 of Table 3). Moreover, these firms were responsible for employing a signifi-
    cant share of the workers in tobacco manufacturing. For example, the per-unit tariffs for a
    SKM produced by Class I manufacturers and sold for a minimum of IDR 1,120 per unit was
    IDR 530 (47.3 percent of retail sale price), while the per-unit tariffs for a SKT produced by

    6 Ministry of Finance Decree Number 43/PMK.04/2005.
    7 In addition to SKM, SPM, and SKT, there are hand-rolled white cigarettes with filters. The structure of the excise tax for these products
    are identical to the structure for SKM..

                                                                                                                                           27
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

Table 3: Cigarette excise tax in Indonesia, 2017

  TYPE OF                                                 CATEGORY                        PER-UNIT                % NOMINAL            NUMBER
  CIGARETTE                                               (PRODUCTION)                    TARIFFS                 CHANGE               OF
                                                                                          (TIERS), IN             (REAL),              FACTORIES
                                                                                          RUPIAH                  2010-2017            (2015)

  Machine-made kreteks (SKM), hand-rolled                 Class I, > 3 billion                    530                    78 (27)          14
  kreteks with filter (SKTF), hand-rolled white           sticks
  cigarettes with filter (SPTF)

  Hand-rolled white cigarettes with filter (SPTF)         Class II, ≤ 3 billion                335-365                   75 (24)          232
                                                          sticks

  Machine-made white cigarettes (SPM)                     Class I, > 3 billion                    555                   106 (46)           1
                                                          sticks
                                                          Class II, ≤ 3 billion               290-330                    90 (35)          25
                                                          sticks

  Hand-rolled kreteks (SKT)                               Class I, > 2 billion                 265-345                   66 (18)          16
                                                          sticks
                                                          Class II, 500 million–2              155-165                   64 (15)          21
                                                          billion sticks
                                                          Class III, ≤ 500 million             80-100                    38 (-2)          404
                                                          sticks

Source: Peraturan Menteri Keuangan (Ministry of Finance Decree) abbreviated as PMK: PMK Number 181 2009,
PMK Number 190 2010, PMK Number 167 2011, PMK Number 205 2014, PMK Number 198 2015, PMK Number
147 2016.
Note: For parsimony, per-unit tariffs for Class II and Class III categories are simplified from per-unit tariffs for Class
IIA, Class IIB, Class IIIA, and Class IIIB. Real change in per-unit tariffs accounts for changes in prices of goods and
services in the economy.

Class I manufacturers and sold for a minimum of IDR 1,215 per unit was only IDR 345 (28.4
percent of retail sale price). These numbers imply that per-unit tariffs for SKT was half of
the per-unit tariffs for SKM of a similar tier. The ratio between the highest and the lowest
per-unit tariffs in the 2017 tax structure was quite high at 6.7. Changes in real excise tax
for SKT between 2010 and 2017 was also quite low at 18% or lower. Additionally, SKT pro-
duced by Class III producers were cheaper, in real terms, in 2017 than they were in 2010.

Despite the low tax rates, there was a downward trend in the sale of SKT in the
market. In 2001, the share of SKT in the market was about 40% (Ministry of Industry,
2009). The share decreased to 35.5% in 2005, to 30% in 2011, and to just 26% in 2013. We
argue that the shift away from SKT was not likely the result of higher cigarette taxes. 8
First, as shown in Table 3, taxes imposed on SKT were among the lowest in the cigarette

8 Particularly because, as noted above, the tax increases were not enough to reduce affordability. cigarettes in Indonesia were much
more affordable in 2013 than they were in 2000 (US NCI and WHO, 2016).

28 // Cigarette Tax Policies in Indonesia
Figure 1. Trends of the Cigarette Excise Tax in Indonesia in real terms, 2010–2017
EXCISE TARIFF PER STICK, IN REAL TERMS

                                         400                                                                          400

                                         300                                                                          300

                                         200                                                                          200

                                         100                                                                          100

                                               2010     2011      2012   2013    2014      2015      2016   2017             2010     2011     2012      2013      2014      2015       2016   2017

                                                  HRK Class I, layer 1        HRK Class I, layer 2                               HRK Class II, layer 1          HRK Class II, layer 2
                                                  MMK Class I                 MMW Class I                                        MMK Class II, layer 1          MMK Class II, layer 2
                                                                                                                                 MMW Class II, layer 1          MMW Class II, layer 2

                                               Note: the pre - 2009 tariffs are calculated based on the current 12 layers
                                               Source: : Peraturan Menteri Keuangan (PMK) 181 2009, PMK 190 2010, PMK 167 2011, PMK 179 2012, PMK 205 2014, PMK 198 2015, PMK 147 2016

     Source: Peraturan Menteri Keuangan (Ministry of Finance Decree) abbreviated as PMK: PMK Number 181 2009,
     PMK Number 190 2010, PMK Number 167 2011, PMK Number 205 2014, PMK Number 198 2015, PMK Number
     147 2016.
     Note: The pre-2009 tariffs were calculated based on the current 12 layers.

     industry, and the changes of the taxes in real terms were quite small. Second, despite the
     decreasing share, productions of SKT were still increasing over time at least up to year
     2010 (Tobacco Control Support Center, 2014). The shift away from SKT have been driven
     by changing preferences among smokers for machine-made products due to income
     growth. It may also have reflected substitution of more capital-intensive technology away
     from labor-intensive hand-rolling in cigarette production.

     3.1 Effects on Cigarette Consumption, Revenues, and Employment
     Previous evidence suggests that raising cigarette prices through taxes may have
     potential to reduce consumption in Indonesia. A review by Setyonaluri and col-
     leagues (2008) reported price elasticities of demand ranging from –0.26 to –0.76. These
     estimates suggest that raising prices through taxes can reduce consumption. Ahsan
     (2011) suggested that a 16 percent increase in cigarette tax would reduce consumption
     by 4.7 percent, implying a price elasticity of –0.29. The impacts of raising cigarette tax on
     health were also potentially significant. A study suggested that raising cigarette taxes to
     50 percent of retail prices can reduce expected mortality rate by 2 to 5 percent, depend-
     ing on the price elasticity of demand (Setyonaluri et al., 2008).

                                                                                                                                                                                                      29
The Economics of Tobacco Taxation and Employment in Indonesia

This report updates earlier elasticity estimates. To do so, we used the 2015 National
Socioeconomic Survey (Susenas) to estimate the price elasticity of cigarette demand.9
The NSS contains data on whether an individual smoked kreteks or white cigarettes,
the number of cigarettes smoked in the past week, and total expenditure for cigarettes.
The limitation of our estimation was that we could not differentiate between hand-made
and machine-made kretek. However, obtaining separate estimates for kreteks and white
cigarettes offered a significant improvement over the existing literature. This information
allowed estimating price elasticity of demand for SKT and SKM separately. Results showed
variation in price elasticities of demand between kreteks and white cigarettes. The esti-
mated price elasticity of demand for kreteks was about –0.42 while for white cigarettes
was about –0.51 (within the range of –0.26 and –0.76 reported in previous studies). We
acknowledge our price elasticities may be underestimated because they do not account
for substitutions to cheaper products. For example, individuals can easily switch to
cheaper cigarettes if cigarette prices increase because of higher excise taxes.

An important aspect is to observe the impact of tobacco excise tax across income
groups. The global evidence suggests that cigarette tax was regressive and showed that
the young and the poor were more responsive to price changes. For example, Nasrudin
and colleagues (2013) estimated price elasticities of –0.15 to –0.16 among individuals in
the first two income deciles and price elasticities of –0.20 to –0.28 among individuals in
the third to ninth deciles. The authors estimated that the tax burden as a percentage of
income of individuals in the first two deciles was between 3 to 10.63 percent and the tax
burden of individuals from the other income groups was below 2 percent (Nasrudin et al.,
2013). These results may be explained by the policy of keeping kreteks cheap. However,
the study did not consider the benefits of raising cigarette taxes. A more recent study
showed that once indirect benefits (such as lower health care expenditures and higher
productivity) of raising cigarette taxes were accounted for, a tobacco tax increase was
actually progressive (Fuchs and Meneses, 2017).

In Indonesia, annual excise tax revenues from tobacco products had been increas-
ing monotonically since 2005 (Figure 2). In 2007, the realized excise tax revenue was
IDR 43.54 trillion (US$4.87 billion). The figure grew to IDR 55.38 trillion (US$5.33 billion) in
2009, IDR 103.6 trillion (US$9.90 billion) in 2013, and IDR 139.5 trillion (US$11.76 billion)
in 2014 (IAKMI, 2014; Dwi Kurnaini, 2016).10 Historically, tobacco excise accounts for more
than 95 percent of total excise revenue. Simulation studies suggest that a 10 percent
increase in cigarette tax would increase excise revenues by 6.7 to 9.0 percent (Setyonaluri
et al., 2008). Another simulation suggests that a 16 percent increase in cigarette tax would

9 We report the estimations of price elasticity of demand in Annex III.
10 The exchange rates were IDR 8,938/US$ in 2004, IDR 10,389/US$ in 2009, IDR 10,461/US$ in 2013, and IDR 11,865/US$ in 2014
(OECD, 2017).

30 // Cigarette Tax Policies in Indonesia
You can also read