Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

Page created by Enrique Maldonado
 
CONTINUE READING
Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership
1/22                                         Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

         26 JANUARY 2022 · RESEARCH BULLETIN NO. 91

         Younger generations and the lost dream of home
         ownership
         by Gonzalo Paz-Pardo[1]
         Homeownership among younger households has been decreasing in several major advanced economies.
         In this analysis, I show that increases in labour income inequality and uncertainty are key drivers of this
         trend. Confronted with high house prices and low, risky incomes, many young households cannot or do not
         want to risk making such a big, illiquid investment. As a result, they accumulate less wealth.

         Decreasing homeownership rates
         Chart 1 shows that, in the United States, younger generations are less likely to be living in their own
         homes than older generations were at the same age. Among households headed up by someone born in
         the 1940s, 70% owned their homes by age 35. This figure dropped to 60% for those born in the 1960s and
         about 50% for the early “millennials” born in the 1980s. In southern Europe, too, homeownership rates at
         age 35 have dropped – by over 10 percentage points when comparing those born from 1965 to 1979 with
         those born in the 1980s. At the same time, young people are taking longer to leave the parental home and
         live independently (Becker, Bentolilla, Fernandes, Ichino, 2008).
         Homeownership is a frequent subject of political debate. Owning a house is crucial for the wealth
         accumulation of most households (Paz-Pardo, 2021), and housing plays a role in a well-diversified
         portfolio (Chetty, Sandor, Szeidl, 2017). Shutting young people out of housing markets may distort their
         marriage and childbearing decisions (Laeven and Popov, 2017), and homeownership rates relate directly
         to the strength of local communities, social capital and political engagement (Glaeser, Laibson, Sacerdote,
         2002; Rohe, Van Zandt, McCarthy, 2002).
         What has driven these changes? To identify the key factors, I build a model of homeownership and
         portfolio choice over the life cycle with a rich structure of risks (Paz-Pardo, 2021). According to the model,
         it’s not about younger generations not wanting to buy their homes anymore: changes in the economic
         environment fully explain the magnitude of the drop in homeownership rates.

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2022/html/ecb.rb220126~4542d3cea0.en.html                         1/6
Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership
1/22                                          Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

         Chart 1
         Homeownership rates by age and decade of birth

         United States

         Southern Europe

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2022/html/ecb.rb220126~4542d3cea0.en.html        2/6
Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership
1/22                                          Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

         Source: Own elaboration based on the Panel Study of Income Dynamics (PSID; top panel) and the Household
         Finance and Consumption Survey (HFCS; bottom panel). Southern Europe is a population-weighted average of
         Greece, Spain, Italy, Cyprus, Malta and Portugal. The graph represents the share of households that are living in
         owner-occupied housing, by age and decade of birth of the head of household (reference man for PSID data;
         reference person following the Canberra Group statistical criterion for the HFCS, which is usually the highest-earning
         member of a couple).

         Role of changes in the labour market

         Table 1
         Relative contributions of different factors to changes in homeownership rates, age 30

                                                                     1960s generation                 1980s generation

        Labour market income dynamics                                68                               73

        Initial inequality                                                          61                                  41

        Risk                                                                        7                                   32

        Asset returns and business cycle                             33                               90

        House price trend                                                           63                                  45

        Cyclical factors                                                            -30                                 45

        Borrowing conditions                                         0                                -68

        Other factors                                                -1                               5

         Note: This table summarizes the contribution of different factors to the drop in homeownership rates, according to
         model counterfactuals. The percentage values represent the share of the drop in homeownership rates (when
         comparing the 1960s and 1980s generations, respectively, to the 1940s generation) accounted for by one particular
         factor, taking into account its contribution to possible interaction effects. Negative values imply positive contributions to
         homeownership, and the right-hand column within each generation represents the breakdown of the components in
         the left-hand column.

         Changes in earnings explain more than half of the decrease in homeownership rates (Table 1). For
         younger generations, career-long positions have become ever scarcer, unemployment spells are longer,
         and earnings inequality has increased (see Acemoglu and Autor, 2011; Goldin and Katz, 2009).[2] While
         the labour incomes of high earners have increased substantially over time in real terms, those on lower
         incomes have seen their real earnings stagnate or decrease. As a result, they find it harder to buy a home.
         Why? There are almost no homes on the market below a certain minimum price, quality or size threshold.
         Households too poor to access a mortgage for that minimum amount are thus shut out of the housing
         market.
         According to the decomposition, earnings inequality accounts for 61% of the drop in homeownership rates
         for the 1960s generation. For those born in the 1980s, earnings volatility also plays an important role,
         explaining 32% of the drop at age 30. With less stable incomes, households are wary of making a large
         investment like buying a home and of assuming a large amount of gross debt. As a result, they stay
         renters for longer (Fisher and Gervais, 2011).

         Favourable labour and housing markets at young ages are crucial
         Over the past 60 years, the price of the median home has been gradually increasing relative to the median
         income. This evolution, which can be linked to cohort sizes, housing supply constraints, land-use policies,
         building regulations, housing characteristics, and other policies and institutions, was also a key reason for
         the reduction in homeownership.

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2022/html/ecb.rb220126~4542d3cea0.en.html                                        3/6
1/22                                         Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

         The timing of fluctuations in house prices and the business cycle can leave a permanent mark on a
         generation. For instance, a generation that benefits from low house prices during its prime homebuying
         years is likely to be composed of more homeowners. And once households become homeowners, they
         tend to stay homeowners for most of their lives. Those born in the 1960s entered the housing market at a
         time when house prices were cyclically low, which helped counter other, negative forces impacting
         homeownership. For those born in the 1980s, the opposite was true, compounded by the effect of the
         2008 crisis on their earnings.
         Borrowing conditions have also fluctuated over time. In particular, loan-to-value (LTV) and loan-to-income
         (LTI) restrictions on mortgages were relaxed in the lead-up to the global financial crisis and became more
         stringent afterwards. The model suggests that easier borrowing conditions helped the 1980s generation
         get onto the housing ladder in the early 2000s.
         This decomposition abstracts from general equilibrium effects of earnings dynamics and borrowing
         conditions on house prices. For instance, easier financing pushed up house prices during this period
         (Favara and Imbs, 2015), which would moderate its positive contribution to homeownership rates.

         Implications for wealth accumulation
         For most households, their primary residence is both the largest asset they hold and the majority of their
         wealth. Households buy houses to save, but also because they enjoy owning or to insure against rising
         future rents. Besides, homebuying is the only time most households incur substantial leverage, which
         implies their wealth can increase very rapidly if house prices rise.[3] As a result, a household that is left out
         of the housing market because of LTI or LTV restrictions might accumulate less wealth than it otherwise
         would, particularly at a time of low mortgage rates. This channel can reinforce the increase in wealth
         inequality derived from low real rates (Greenwald, Leombroni, Lustig, Van Nieuwerburgh, 2021).
         Younger households are now more likely to participate in the stock market. However, these extra savings
         in the form of financial wealth do not seem to compensate for the missing housing wealth, as they are
         concentrated within richer households. In the United States, the median young household is less wealthy
         than a similar household was 20 years ago (Chart 2), and, because young households frequently hold little
         equity in their homes, these differences are likely to grow as they age.

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2022/html/ecb.rb220126~4542d3cea0.en.html                            4/6
1/22                                          Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

         Chart 2
         Wealth accumulation by generation

         Note: The figure represents the average wealth accumulated by households in a given generation and position in the
         wealth distribution. Wealth is measured as multiples of average income in the economy at the time (US data, Survey
         of Consumer Finances).

         Conclusions
         The evolution of homeownership rates is closely intertwined with labour markets, housing markets and
         financial conditions. Thus, the design of labour market regulations, fiscal policies and the macroprudential
         framework should take into account their potential impact on young households trying to get on the
         housing ladder.
         On the one hand, the 2000s boom-bust house price episode showed that there are risks for the financial
         system associated with highly levered homebuyers, and that building housing stock can divert resources
         from other productive sectors. On the other hand, a combination of policies that facilitates access to
         homeownership can help lower wealth inequality and increase social cohesion.

         References
         Acemoglu, D., and Autor, D. (2011), “Skills, tasks and technologies: Implications for employment and
         earnings”. Handbook of labor economics, Vol. 4, pp. 1043-1171, Elsevier.
         Becker, S.O., Bentolilla, S., Fernandes, A. and Ichino, A. (2008), “Youth emancipation and perceived job
         insecurity of parents and children”, Journal of Population Economics, Vol 23, pp. 1047-1071.
         Chetty, R., Sandor, L. and Szeidl, A. (2017), “The effect of housing on portfolio choice” Journal of Finance,
         Vol. 72, No 3, pp. 1171–1212.
         Davis, S. J. and Haltiwanger, J. (2014), Labor market fluidity and economic performance No. w20479,
         National Bureau of Economic Research.
         Favara, G. and Imbs, J., (2015), “Credit supply and the price of housing”, American Economic Review, Vol.
         105(3), pp.958-92.

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2022/html/ecb.rb220126~4542d3cea0.en.html                             5/6
1/22                                         Younger generations and the lost dream of home ownership

         Fisher, J. D. and Gervais, M. (2011), “Why has home ownership fallen among the young?”, International
         Economic Review, Vol. 52, No 3, pp. 883-912.
         Glaeser, E. L., Laibson, D. and Sacerdote, B. (2002), “An Economic Approach to Social Capital”,
         Economic Journal, Vol. 112, No 483, pp. 437-458.
         Goldin, C. D. and Katz, L. F. (2009), The race between education and technology, Harvard University
         Press.
         Greenwald D., Leombroni, M., Lustig, H and Van Nieuwerburgh, S. (2021), Financial and total wealth
         inequality with declining interest rates, Working paper.
         Johnson, J.E. and Schulhofer-Wohl, S. (2019), “Changing patterns of geographical mobility and the labor
         market for young adults”, Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 37(S1), pp. 199-241
         Jordà, O., Knoll, K., Kuvshinov, D., Schularick, M. and Taylor, A.M. (2019), “The rate of return on
         everything, 1870-2015”, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 134, No 3, pp. 1225-1298.
         Laeven, L. and Popov. A. (2017), “Waking Up from the American Dream: On the Experience of Young
         Americans during the Housing Boom of the 2000s”, Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 49, No 5,
         pp. 861-895.
         Paz-Pardo, G. (2021), “Homeownership and portfolio choice over the generations”, Working Paper Series,
         No. 2522, ECB, February 2021.
         Rohe, W. M., Van Zandt, S. and McCarthy, G. (2002), “Home ownership and access to
         opportunity”, Housing Studies, Vol. 17, No 1, pp. 51-61.

         1. The article was written by Gonzalo Paz-Pardo (Senior Economist, Directorate General Research,
         Monetary Policy Research Division). The author would like to thank Niccolò Battistini, Maarten Dossche,
         Michael Ehrmann, Alexander Popov and Zoë Sprokel for their comments, as well as Antilia Virginie for her
         assistance with the Household Finance and Consumption Survey (HFCS) data. The views expressed here
         are those of the author and do not necessarily represent the views of the European Central Bank and the
         Eurosystem.
         2. These developments have occurred jointly with what has been deemed as a reduction in the “fluidity” of
         the labor market (Davis and Haltiwanger, 2014): job finding rates, job losing rates, and job-to-job transition
         rates have declined over time. Furthermore, inter-state migration rates in the United States have
         decreased on average (Johnson and Schulhofer-Wohl, 2019).
         3. Historically, for many countries, the volatility-adjusted returns of housing, measured as Sharpe ratios,
         have been high and dominated those of stocks (Jordà, Knoll, Kuvshinov, Schularick, Taylor, 2019).

         Copyright 2022, European Central Bank

https://www.ecb.europa.eu/pub/economic-research/resbull/2022/html/ecb.rb220126~4542d3cea0.en.html                         6/6
You can also read