How Did Finance Capital Infiltrate the World of the Urban Poor? Homeownership and Social Fragmentation in a Spanish Neighborhood

Page created by Ron Park
 
CONTINUE READING
bs_bs_banner

                                                    International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
                                                                               DOI:10.1111/1468-2427.12055

How Did Finance Capital
Infiltrate the World of the
Urban Poor? Homeownership
and Social Fragmentation
in a Spanish Neighborhood
JAIME PALOMERA

Abstract
When working-class localities in developed countries are in question, social
fragmentation is often analyzed along ethnic lines. Instead, this article claims that it
is more critically fruitful to explore fragmentation in terms of people’s relations with
the state and different forms of capital. It does this by considering housing in Spain as
a key resource that connects state policies both with the forms of reproduction and
(dis)organization of the disadvantaged, and with the development of real estate and
finance capital. First, it unfolds the historical formation of the Spanish ‘homeownership
culture’ and the construction–finance complex. Second, starting from an in-depth
ethnography of a peripheral neighborhood in Barcelona, it emphasizes the
embeddedness of recent financialization in the livelihood strategies of poor households.
Finally, it shows how the process led to a commodification and erosion of those
social relations on which it partially depended, thereby exposing problems for class
reproduction and fracture lines among the urban poor.

                                    ‘Let’s make a country of homeowners, not proletarians.’
                                                                  José María Arrese, first Spanish
                                                                   Secretary of Housing, 1957–60

                                    ‘Immigration is going to be the number one problem in Spain over
                                    the next decade. If ETA [the Basque terrorist group] is a problem
                                    of the twentieth century, immigration will be the main problem for
                                    our coexistence.’
                                                 Jaime Mayor Oreja, member of the Spanish Partido
                                                     Popular and Secretary of the Interior, May 2000

Preliminary versions of this article were presented at the meetings of the Grup d’Estudis de
Reciprocitat, Barcelona (2010) and at the workshop ‘Multiculturalism, Migration and Heritage in Europe’
(University of Massachusetts–University of Barcelona, February 2012). I greatly benefited from the
reactions of participants in those events. I am also grateful to the people who read the essay
and provided insightful comments: Jaume Franquesa, Marc Morell, Susana Narotzky, Gavin Smith,
Jacqueline Urla and the IJURR reviewers. Research funds were provided by the Spanish Department of
Science (FPU fellowship and Project SEJ2007-66633).

© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited. Published by John Wiley & Sons Ltd. 9600 Garsington Road, Oxford OX4
2DQ, UK and 350 Main St, Malden, MA 02148, USA
2                                                                               Jaime Palomera

In recent years the face of urban Spain — to recast Gerald Brenan’s expression —
experienced a radical transformation. On the one hand, the territory was swept by a
housing boom of unprecedented proportions. Suffice it to mention that between 1998 and
2008, prices increased by more than 180%,1 whereas in another financialized market, the
US, they increased by 104%.2 On the other hand, the rapid expansion of the economy
positioned the country as one of the most prominent centers of attraction for
transnational workers. At the turn of the century only 2.3% of the population were of
foreign origin; in 2008 they amounted to 11.4%, thus accounting for most of Spain’s
demographic growth. Just like the subprime populations in the US, these highly
dispossessed fractions became crucial in the prolongation of the Spanish housing boom:
between 2003 and 2007 — when prices were peaking — roughly one million migrants
from the global South were granted mortgages to buy homes.
    A process like this unleashed a residential revolution. In many deprived
neighborhoods a substantial part of the better-off categories moved to less degraded
locations and sold their inflated properties to migrant buyers. And these incoming
homeowners, having to face stagnating wages and rocketing mortgage repayments,
often resorted to unconventional livelihood strategies. In order to finance part of their
mortgage, many of them moved their families into one bedroom and sublet the rest of the
rooms. Thus, behind the glossy and publicly celebrated picture of a buoyant society of
‘middle-class’ proprietors lay a world of informal room renting and poverty.
    Soon, sporadic tensions, particularly between established old-timers and foreign
residents, started cropping up in the media and became a recurrent object of public
fascination. In fact, public commentators have come to portray these neighbourhoods as
potential ‘powder-kegs’, fuelling the idea that the growth of immigration and the
concentration of different ‘cultures’ might have generated, by itself, insoluble conflicts
— the underlying assumption being that there is an ongoing process of ethnic
stratification and that it should be primarily attributed to cultural intolerance.
    Similarly, a lot of the academic literature that directly or indirectly addresses
working-class spaces in Europe has emphasized the new forms of racism (Stolcke, 1995;
Holmes, 2000) and the way in which minorities are prevented from acquiring full
citizenship (Koopmans et al., 2005). Discussions on the problems of ‘coexistence’ in
multiethnic neighborhoods (Agustoni and Alietti, 2007), on the effects of ‘diversity
policies’ (Uitermark et al., 2005) and on the so-called ‘crisis of multiculturalism’
(Vertovec and Wessendorf, 2009; Lentin and Titley, 2011) are actually gathering
momentum.
    These analyses are very important. However, a frequent shortcoming is that many of
them focus on the ways in which racial discrimination is promoted or hindered without
looking at how these intersect with broader shifts in the macrostructures of the economy
and polity. Racism and the formation of ‘identity politics’ are important factors, but they
can become an obfuscating screen unless we analyze the deeper socioeconomic vectors
of division on which they are predicated, which are directly linked with the particular
development of capitalism in each country.
    In this article I claim that it is more critically fruitful to understand the current
problems of working-class people in Spain in terms of their relations with the state and
different forms of capital (chiefly real-estate and finance) than purely in terms of cultural
difference. Financialization processes based on the housing industry, as observed on both
sides of the Atlantic, have, in fact, already been widely discussed. Several authors have
offered macroeconomic perspectives on the expansion of finance capital (Brenner, 2009;
Fine, 2010) and the ways in which states have built and rebuilt mortgage markets in
order to implement the use of securitization and predatory lending (Gotham, 2009;

1 This and the rest of the statistical facts on Spain are according to the INE (Instituto Nacional de
  Estadística) Database.
2 According to Freddie Mac’s Conventional Mortgage Home Price Index (CMHPI).

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
Homeownership and social fragmentation in a Spanish neighborhood                                       3

Immergluck, 2009; Wainwright, 2009). Similar debates have focused on the exploitative
dimension to financial transactions taking place in the sphere of consumption,
particularly in access to housing (Dymski, 2009; Lapavitsas, 2009).3 Some ethnographic
approaches have even dealt with the internal mechanisms of the financial sector (Ho,
2009; Holmes, 2009; Ouroussoff, 2010). However, social scientists have not yet revealed
the mechanisms that allow financialization processes to take root in specific social
formations, and the way in which these relate with social fragmentation and the politics
of racism and identity. In other words: how does financialization actually hit the ground?
   Here, I consider housing in Spain as the key causal link4 that connects state policies
with the forms of reproduction and internal (dis)organization of the most disadvantaged,
and with the development of the construction–finance sector. First, I unfold the historical
formation of the Spanish ‘homeownership culture’. I examine policies since the end of
the 1950s and demonstrate that the privatization of housing among the proletariat was a
project deliberately encouraged and subsidized by the Franco regime. These policies
contributed to shaping the kind of sociopolitical structures (especially and paradoxically
among the poor) that have persistently sanctioned new rounds of domestic property
expansion and the eventual ascent of finance capital in full-fledged neoliberal style. What
emerges from this analysis is that the Spanish working classes have gradually found
themselves with virtually no alternative other than the private property market in order to
solve their housing needs, thus becoming a target for financial institutions.
   Second, starting out from an in-depth ethnographic study of Ciutat Meridiana (a
housing project in the periphery of Barcelona), I show how the recent expansion and
financialization of the real estate market in impoverished spaces was strongly dependent
on and sustained by moral networks that became gradually commodified. The
embeddedness of the formal property market in an informal rental market allowed real
estate and finance capital to increase prices exponentially.
   Finally, I examine the pernicious consequences of this form of market expansion,
manifest in an erosion of the social fabric that revealed deep problems of class
reproduction and internal fracture lines between old and new migrants. By not securing
the conditions for reproduction of the new working classes, the state stimulated the kind
of social differentiation on which racist discourses are currently being predicated.5

The promotion of homeownership among the working classes
In Spain, it is estimated that prior to the financial crisis, 87.1% of the housing stock was
privately owned. Leaving aside post-socialist countries, the country figured among those
with the highest homeownership rate in the EU-27, well over the average (66.8%) (EMF,
2009).
   In the last two decades, media representations have tended to ascribe the supremacy
of private property over other alternatives, such as rent, to an almost genetic
predisposition of Spanish citizens to ‘own their homes’. A frequent claim is that Spain

3 Marx (1991: 745) originally defined credit lending for workers as ‘secondary exploitation’, running
  ‘alongside the original exploitation that takes place directly within the production process itself’.
  Lapavitsas (2009) has rephrased it as ‘financial expropriation’: a process whereby workers and
  other non-capitalist strata are systematically drawn into the financial system in order to secure
  access to resources such as housing, or to manage savings. In this process, the systematic
  inequalities between financial institutions and the holders of personal income allow the former to
  engage in secondary exploitation of the latter, leading to extreme forms of predatory lending
  (Dymski, 2009).
4 Obviously, there are others areas of state action — such as education, health care and employment
  — which I do not have the space to analyze here.
5 The sections on moral networks, class fragmentation and the politics of identity and racism are,
  inevitably, not fully developed in the current article, but these are key issues that will be addressed
  in subsequent publications.

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
4                                                                                      Jaime Palomera

Table 1 Tenure status of primary households in Spain 1950–2007 (%)

Years          Owned           Private Rent            Public Rent         Leaseback        Other Forms
1950             49.0                       –                     –                –                  –
1960              51.9                   41.0                  2.0                 –                  –
1970             63.4                    28.1                  2.0               4.6                1.9
1981              73.1                   18.8                  2.0               3.1                3.0
1991              78.3                   13.2                  2.0               4.5                2.0
2001             80.7                     9.3                  2.0               6.0                1.0
2007             87.0                     7.6                   1.5              3.9                  –
Sources: EMF (2009), Instituto Nacional de Estadística (2011), Trilla (2002)

has a ‘property tradition’ or ‘culture’: owning the house one inhabits is presented as a
transhistorical trait, part of some sort of peninsular essence that would naturally justify
its preeminence. This discourse has no historical basis. In fact, up until the 1960s,
practically half of the housing stock consisted of homes for rent (see Table 1). However,
repeated ad nauseam and transformed into ‘common sense’, in Gramsci’s (1971) terms,
these explanations have functioned as screens concealing the key role that the state plays
in structuring the real estate market. In this sense, it is worth remembering what Tedd
Gurr and Desmond King (1987: 4) point out: ‘those who hold and use state power can
allow the fate of cities to be determined mainly in the private economy, but that is a
matter of public choice rather than iron necessity’. Therefore, if it is possible to talk
nowadays about a ‘homeownership culture’ or, more appropriately, about the existence of
dispositions among the Spanish that make them more inclined to buy a house, it is
necessary to point out that such dispositions are the result of very specific and recent
historical policies.
   Certainly, economic choices in respect of housing depend, as Bourdieu (2005: 15)
states in The Social Structures of the Economy, ‘on the one hand, on the (socially
constituted) economic dispositions of the agents — particularly on their tastes — and the
economic resources they can summon and, on the other, on the state of supply of
dwellings’. But both terms of this equation, against what neoclassical economic theory
would suggest, are strongly dependent on ‘a whole set of economic and social conditions
produced by housing policy’. By means of direct public instruments — housing plans,
control over land, regulation of rental options — and more indirect ones — aid in the
form of tax measures, regulation of the conditions of access to financial credit — ‘the
state — and those who are able to impose their views through it — contributes very
substantially to producing the state of the housing market’ (ibid., emphasis in original).
As a matter of fact, demand, and especially the tendency of individuals to buy or rent,
usually depends to a large extent on the particular state of the supply, which is in turn the
result of the structure of possibilities generated by housing policies. Therefore, it should
be no surprise to read Bourdieu’s conclusion (2005: 128): ‘there are, no doubt, few
markets that are not only so controlled as the housing market is by the state, but indeed
so truly constructed by the state’.
   In Spain, the housing policies of the last 50 years have turned the property market into
the only way to have a roof over one’s head for most of the population. There has been
a clear and relentless evolution from the years of Franco’s desarrollismo (1960s) until
today, from a situation of relatively even distribution between property and rental to
a near absolute predominance of homeownership. The importance of state action
throughout this period became especially clear through the laws regulating rental
agreements, housing plans, fiscal policy and the growth of real estate and financial
capital.

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
Homeownership and social fragmentation in a Spanish neighborhood                          5

Making rent unattractive
The various laws regulating rental agreements have been a clear disincentive for this
form of accommodation. After the Spanish Civil War, the Urban Rent Law (1946)
established an indefinite extension of leases together with a freeze on prices during
inflationary periods. However, this measure was to have a shrinking effect on this market,
since it penalized new private investments in rental housing (Cotorruelo, 1960 in Leal,
2005). During the subsequent period of economic expansion (known as desarrollismo
and extending from 1959 until 1975) the new Urban Rent Law (1964) added to the
previous one the imposition of permanent limits to the possibilities of updating rental
contracts. This change played a major role in the reduction of the proportion of housing
for rent during the next two decades. Since letting became an uninteresting alternative for
owners themselves, buildings for rental suffered gradual deterioration (García-Montalvo,
2003: 9). Later on, the Royal Decree of 1985 did not alter the trajectory: by allowing the
effective upgrade of leases and abolishing the obligation (on the landlord’s side) to
extend rental contracts, it severely reduced tenants’ rights. Furthermore, this loss of
rights was aggravated by the Decree of 1994, which introduced the possibility for
landlords to use one-year contracts.

Privatizing social housing
Housing plans regulating the new developments of the last 50 years have distinguished
themselves by the practical absence of new public housing for rent. The effects of this
transformation are crucial, bearing in mind that more than 66% of the Spanish housing
stock was built after 1960 (Trilla, 2002: 87).
   Until the beginning of the 1960s, there had been a construction policy of social
housing districts with units for rent that were publicly owned. However, the great urban
expansion carried out by the Francoist government, embodied in the Housing Plan
1961–76 and supported by the Plans for Social and Economic Development implied
a break with the preceding policies. The aim of this plan, a true flagship of the
desarrollismo period, was to build new residential developments for the working classes
with a preponderance of state-subsidized housing (it represented 66% of the total,
whereas private homes amounted to 34%). But the most crucial aspect is that most of
these new flats could be privately owned (Sánchez Martínez, 2002). This favored, in the
long run, the somewhat contradictory incorporation of state-subsidized apartments into
the private market, in what has been accurately defined as a ‘Thatcherism avant la lettre’
(López and Rodríguez, 2011). In fact, the concentration of direct action through the
public promotion of housing for sale has remained a salient feature of Spanish housing
policies until today. This is something that clearly differentiates them from the plans that
were being advanced across Europe in the 1960s and 1970s, where the expression
‘social’, ‘public’ or ‘state-subsidized’ was generally associated with rent.
   The majority of new homes that were labeled as protegidas (‘protected’ from the
private market, i.e. state-subsidized) during this period were built under the Law of
Limited-income Housing (1954): the state directly subsidized the developers, financing
60% of the total value of the new developments, which allowed the price of housing units
to be reduced (Leal, 2005: 69). To make sure that the new owners of these homes would
be able to afford them, the state created the Spanish Mortgage Bank, a public institution
that guaranteed the loans that financial capital did not want to provide due to their low
profitability and fears of default. As we will see below, the granting of loans for the
working classes would not become a significant business for private banking until the end
of the 1980s. The epitome of the desarrollismo period are the polígonos de vivienda
which, like the English new towns or the French grands ensembles, were built on the
periphery of great cities, especially in Madrid, Barcelona and the Basque Country. These
were big residential complexes designed for the working-class masses that had emigrated
from rural parts of the country and had been settling for more than two decades in
informal shantytowns, due to the shortage of affordable housing in the private market.

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
6                                                                               Jaime Palomera

   The Spanish ‘invention’ (Leal, 2005: 70) of building state-subsidized housing for
private ownership was prolonged, albeit in much smaller numbers, throughout the 1980s,
in the form of new housing plans (1981–83, 1984–87; see Ministerio de Obras Públicas,
Transportes y Medio Ambiente, 1996). By the end of that decade, and in accordance with
the European Union’s neoliberal turn, free-market housing was already becoming the
only form of new development.

Rewarding homeowners, making it hard for tenants
Since then, the state has changed its approach: from direct intervention via the
development of subsidized housing to the stimulation of aggregate demand through
indirect measures such as tax relief. In 1996, the state decided to fiscally reward
homeowning while penalizing renting. If at the beginning of the 1990s tax deductions for
the purchase of a property represented approximately 50% of all the virtual investment
in housing by the state, by 2003 they amounted to more than 80% (Leal, 2005: 76). It is
estimated that, during the last decade, public support for the purchase of housing
financed between 20% and 50% of the total price (García-Montalvo, 2008).

Shaping the dispositions of a social class
The social consequences of these policies are expressed in phrases that became popular
over recent years, such as ‘buying deducts’ or ‘renting is wasting your money’. In fact,
such political measures would have not been possible without the dispositions they
contributed to shaping in Spanish society during this long wave of 50 years, particularly
among the working classes. It was in the red belts of big cities that the tendency to buy
became more acute: in Ciutat Meridiana, for example, the rate of homeowners in 2001
was 87.5%, whereas the average for Barcelona was 68.1%.
   Again, the origins of this change have to be traced back to the 1960s, the years of the
desarrollismo, during which the massive supply of state-subsidized housing for private
ownership had a short-term political aim: the payment of monthly installments was a
mechanism to tame the working classes, since workers’ demands could bring about the
loss not only of their job but also of their home. But the transformation of the objective
structure of possibilities for housing provision was also going to have long-lasting effects
on the reproductive strategies of the working classes. By turning workers into owners of
their new apartments, the state promoted a change akin to what Bourdieu (2005: 34)
identifies in his study of a French suburban area of small houses:
    Categories previously disinclined to see the purchase of their dwelling as a major form of
    financial investment and who would have represented a natural clientele for a policy aimed at
    promoting the building of public housing for rent (single-family houses or blocks of flats) have,
    thanks to credit and government assistance, come to subscribe to the logic of the accumulation
    of an economic heritage, thus creating a role in their reproductive strategies for the direct
    transmission of material goods.

This alteration in the dispositions of the working classes undoubtedly contributed to
creating an environment of political legitimacy for the continuing expansion of the
property market in the following years. Moreover, it also explains the weak opposition to
socially regressive policies such as tax deductions for the purchase of housing.
   The result of this is what Jim Kemeny (1981) argues in The Myth of Home Ownership:
there is a relation of causality in the fact that countries with a high rate of homeownership
have a weak welfare state.6 According to Kemeny, in a society where buying a house and
a car become high priorities, the tendency is to develop a strong opposition to the kind
of fiscal measures that would facilitate the provision of universal and egalitarian public

6 Spain’s welfare state is weak compared to the rest of countries in the EU-15 (Navarro, 2006).

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
Homeownership and social fragmentation in a Spanish neighborhood                           7

welfare: the perception is that these political measures would delay such essential
purchases. The direction in this relation of causality (that is, whether a strong tendency
to buy one’s dwelling leads to the weakening of the welfare state or vice versa) is unclear
(Castles, 1998: 18), but they are two poles of the same equation and tend to reinforce
each other in a vicious circle. By stimulating what some call the ‘democratization’ of
homeownership, the state transfers the responsibility for the provision of such a
fundamental resource to private households. Simultaneously, by entering into the logic of
accumulation and transmission of a property, citizens tend to become more resistant to
the kind of fiscal policies that would affect their small assets, therefore weakening the
state and the possible construction of social housing for subsequent generations.
   The obvious result of this circle is that social inequalities increase. In the year 1988
more than 70% of tax deductions were already concentrated in the top 30% of Spanish
households, those with the highest incomes (Leal, 2005:76). In fact, many of the fiscally
regressive measures approved during the last decade have tended to weaken the public
sector and favor strategies of asset accumulation, precisely at a time of unprecedented
growth in the property market: reduction of personal income tax for top earners and
corporate income tax; suppression of and exemptions from property tax and inheritance
tax in several regions, etc. Thus, by privileging home-buying and making progressive
taxation unattractive, the redistributive function of the state is undermined, benefiting the
upper classes and producing more precariousness among the working classes.

The growth of the real estate and finance complex
The policies analyzed so far have decisively contributed to the expansion of the private
property market and are narrowly related to the weight that real estate capital has
historically acquired in the Spanish model of economic growth.
   The origins of this process are again to be found in the great expansion of the 1960s,
during which, as Castells (2001: 172) points out, the government provided the market: ‘it
bought the land, loaned the capital, paid for the construction, channeled the demand,
created fiscal exemptions and “forgot” to regulate the legal norms and requisites for an
urban infrastructure’. The lucrative business of building public housing for sale gave
birth to a new real estate network, together with a strong construction industry. Big
developers absorbed most of the demand and created some of the most important Spanish
companies (Llordén, 2003).
   Ever since, the construction sector has gradually acquired greater weight due to
optimal conditions guaranteed by state action. It should be no wonder that the cyclical
construction of new residential developments for sale has acquired a fundamental role in
the Spanish model of economic growth, becoming what Harvey calls a ‘secondary circuit
of capital’ (Harvey, 1978: 106). Certainly, after the long crisis of the 1970s, the Spanish
economy has relied on internal housing bubbles (1987–91, 1996–2007) in order to
sustain the circulation of capital and its growth rates, something akin to the dynamic in
other Western countries, such as the United States or the United Kingdom (Harvey,
2008). In these processes of growth, real estate capital has acquired an increasing
dependence on the involvement of finance capital, more than in any of the other
commodity markets. As in all the advanced capitalist countries during the 1980s,
persistent downward pressure on wages led fictitious capital to emerge as the mode to
sustain a double circle of rising aggregate demand and capital gains without raising
public spending. In Spain, during the last housing boom the average wage in the private
sector increased by only 0.7% (the lowest rate among the EU-15 countries) whereas
capital gains surged by 73%, compared with an average of 33% in the EU-15 (Navarro
et al., 2009).
   In order to pave the way for an expansion of the financial sector, the state undertook
gradual deregulations. Until the beginning of the 1980s, the issue of mortgage bonds had
been exclusively reserved to the Spanish Public Mortgage Bank. However, this began to
change with the Mortgage Market Act of 1981, which authorized commercial banks to

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
8                                                                            Jaime Palomera

grant mortgages and extended both their length and the maximum legal loan-to-value
percentage. Also, it introduced the possibility of turning them into marketable securities,
a change that was formalized in 1992 with the Law of Securitization Vehicles and given
a new impulse in 1998 with further deregulation. From that year and throughout a further
decade, mortgage securitization boomed and became the means to finance a large portion
of bank lending in the country (Carbó et al., 2011). Simultaneously, the residential
mortgage debt to GDP ratio grew from 23% to 62% (EMF, 2009).
   These state regulations and financial activities cannot be detached from a series of
changes at a global scale, promoted by supranational entities such as the European
Central Bank. It was in the context of a general easing in credit, declining inflation, and
real interest rates declines that the Spanish housing boom could unfold. The international
capital markets became an apparently endless international pool whence the expanding
Spanish banks could issue securities and fund their mortgage growth. Thus, between
1998 and 2009, housing prices surged relentlessly and the country reached the highest
levels of residential development in its history, 10.9% of the GDP (García-Montalvo,
2006).
   As a result of a state policy that favored homeownership and the growth of the real
estate–finance complex, Spain has practically no public housing. State-subsidized stock
barely amounts to 1.5% of the housing market (see Table 1), a very low figure compared
to other European states such as England (20%) or France (17%) (Allen et al., 2004).
This fact is especially important for the working classes, since both workers and the poor
are always those who most crucially depend on the public provisioning of social housing
for rent (Harloe, 1995). In this sense, by allowing the question of lodging to be
determined in the private market, the state leaves the underprivileged at the mercy of
finance and real estate capital, which can exploit a fundamental human need like finding
a place to live. The pernicious consequences of this domination became dramatically
visible in the last decade, during which finance capital penetrated all social sectors,
including the most precarious fractions of the working classes.

How working-class neighborhoods became fields of financial
speculation: the case of Ciutat Meridiana (Barcelona)
Ciutat Meridiana is a particularly interesting place to understand the extent of the
housing boom that swept across the Spanish geography. Unlike other areas that generally
constitute the empirical basis of speculative processes, it is the complete opposite of
a gentrified or touristy neighborhood. Located in the north-eastern limits of Barcelona,
at first glance it is little more than a collection of apartment blocks climbing the damp
steep slopes of Collserola, crammed between the mountain and a frontier of roads and
railway tracks. Like other polígonos de vivienda made up of apartment units for sale, it
was built at the end of the 1960s by a private developer, under the above-mentioned
Limited-income Housing Law. The alleged aim was to provide housing for the
working-class migrants who had left rural areas of Spain (Andalusia, Aragon, Navarre)
and had been living for several years in conditions that were officially demonized and
deemed as ‘anti-hygienic’: mostly in informal shantytowns, but also in rented rooms,
stables and caves in the hilly parts of the city.
   Positioned in the lowest regions of the socioeconomic hierarchy of urban spaces from
the beginning,7 Ciutat Meridiana is seen as an unattractive place by many of the people
who visit it for the first time and also by a significant proportion of its inhabitants: the

7 Ciutat Meridiana was the most economically impoverished neighborhood of Barcelona in 2005,
  according to the Index of Social Inequalities elaborated by the Ajuntament de Barcelona (Recio,
  2008: 195).

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
Homeownership and social fragmentation in a Spanish neighborhood                             9

orographic obstacles, the very low quality of the apartment blocks, the scarcity of public
space and the neighborhood’s clear segregation from the urban fabric are all aspects that
seem at first sight to impede the development of a good quality of life. These elements
generate the perception among many residents that Ciutat Meridiana is a sort of parallel,
autonomous world. Barcelona is an unknown city to many; administratively speaking,
they belong to it, but there is a historical feeling of institutional disregard, largely due to
infrastructural deficiencies inherited from the Franco period and aggravated by the
relative abandonment suffered during the first 20 years of democratic government
(compared to other working-class areas that benefited during the same period from big
public investments).
   It was the expansion of finance capital at the end of the 1990s that allowed a cast-off
area such as Ciutat Meridiana to enter the logic of real estate speculation. By then, the
situation in urban Spain was relatively analogous to that of the 1960s: economic growth
had generated a huge demand for labor, attracting workers from many places in the
global South. Their precarious position in a highly deregulated, informal labor market,
coupled with the continuing increase in land prices made getting a place to live difficult
for this population.
   However, the state’s solution to the housing problem differed from that of the
desarrollista stage: now, the government did not intervene via subsidies or the creation
of a Public Mortgage Bank, but mainly through the deregulation of the limits imposed on
finance capital (besides the fiscal policies described above). If the 1960s had been
marked by a sort of Keynesianism (whereby consumerism had been boosted through the
state’s strong investment), in the age of full-fledged neoliberalism Spain became a
laboratory of what Brenner (2006) calls ‘asset-price Keynesianism’ or ‘bubblenomics’
(López and Rodríguez, 2011). The massive production of credit allowed both aggregate
demand and prices to grow, despite stagnating wages.
   This allowed the most precarious strata of the working classes to be seen as potential
demand, thereby becoming a target for real estate agencies and banks. Foreign workers,
relegated to socioeconomic marginality, constituted a key group during the real estate
market boom. On the production side, legal limitations imposed by immigration laws
facilitated the exertion of pressure on their wages, with many workers entering
the informal sectors of the construction industry (Portes and Sassen, 1987). On the
consumption side, the expansion of credit allowed real estate profits to be sustained
without migrants’ low wages being raised.
   The new demand, ever greater due to a gradual reduction of the restrictions on the
granting of credit, was channeled towards impoverished neighborhoods where the
most affordable housing was concentrated. Thus, unknown and slightly stigmatized
neighborhoods such as Ciutat Meridiana were introduced onto the maps of potential
buyers. A good example of this is a group of Dominican women who, until the end of the
1990s, had been moving between rooms in apartments for rent that were highly degraded
and had no appeal for more established residents. After years of internal domestic
service, these women had acquired their residence permits and were now working in
wealthy uptown houses. In 2002 they started learning through their acquaintances about
estate agencies that were offering ‘affordable’ apartments for sale. These agencies
belonged in many cases to important developers, and they sent potential buyers to the
offices that they had been opening in areas such as Ciutat Meridiana. In fact, between
2002 and 2007, Ciutat Meridiana saw the opening of 7 new estate offices. Some of the
agents who focused on attracting and channeling these impoverished migrants to Ciutat
Meridiana described themselves as ‘specializing in immigration’.
   Moreover, the endeavors of these agencies were reinforced by, and benefited from, the
role of buyers’ social networks, which emerged as informal intermediaries in the process.
The first homeowners who settled in Ciutat Meridiana told their relatives and fellow
countrymen about the possibility of getting their own affordable homes. Some agencies
even engaged these first buyers to act as brokers: they gave them a sum of money in
exchange for persuading their friends and relatives to buy an apartment through them. ‘At

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
10                                                                          Jaime Palomera

Figure 1 Prices per square meter 2000–06, Barcelona and Ciutat Meridiana (source:
Departament d’Estadística de l’Ajuntament de Barcelona, 2000–2006)

the time’, as one informant told me, ‘they were selling more apartments than apples in a
fruit shop! Agencies were full of immigrants’.
   The spectacular growth of this ‘migrant demand’, combined with the spread of credit
and the apparently unstoppable increase in property values created a general feeling of
opportunity for social mobility in a place like Ciutat Meridiana. Many households turned
their apartment into what people routinely called a ‘bridge-flat’: a primary dwelling used
as a financial guarantee, often prior to being actually sold, in order to get a mortgage and
buy a new home of higher economic value. This allowed many second-generation
migrants from rural Spain to move to suburban locations often considered more
attractive. Eventually, the general feeling of a ‘gold rush’ turned homes into mere
financial assets, devoid of use-value. This phenomenon was epitomized by agents and
residents who bought apartments simply with the intention of selling them one or two
years later, and making a profit that could be reinvested.
   The process implied an increase of house prices in Ciutat Meridiana, proportional to
other central and gentrifying areas of the city (as in Figure 1).8 Moreover, it led to a huge
residential transformation: in less than a decade, practically half of the population in a
neighborhood of 11,000 people was replaced by a new wave of residents, mostly
foreigners. In fact, between the years 2000 and 2007, the number of foreign migrants in
the area rose from 200 to 4,200, becoming almost 40% of the total population
(Departament d’Estadística de l’Ajuntament de Barcelona, 2001–09).
   Nevertheless, it is important to bear in mind that behind the message of the bubble as
an opportunity lay the fear, promoted by local agents, that prices would never stop
increasing. This, for a population inclined to see their home as a source of familial
heritage and social security, became a haunting threat. In other words, what was often
described as a great chance hid an imperative for the most disadvantaged, who saw,
despite the availability of credit, how prices increased dramatically in relation to their
sources of income.
   By deregulating the granting of mortgage credits, the state allowed financial
institutions to exploit without restrictions the needs of the new migrant population. In
fact, even though the legal limit for mortgage granting had already been extended to 80%

8 Prices soared in Barcelona and across Spain in the same proportion between 2000 and 2007: they
  rose by 110% (Instituto Nacional de Estadística, 2011).

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
Homeownership and social fragmentation in a Spanish neighborhood                                  11

of the home value, the great majority of banks — in collusion with valuation and
appraisal companies — found enough grey areas to generally offer credits that covered
up to 120% of the price.
   The new foreign residents had neither savings nor assets that could function as a form
of guarantee, which obliged them to borrow great sums of money from the banks. In fact,
since the loans they received were usually above the price of the apartment, the extra
money was frequently invested in other expenditures, such as furniture, renovations for
the new home, or the acquisition of a car. In order to grant these potential clients a
mortgage, banks and estate agencies only needed to ask for two kinds of requirement: on
the one hand, buyers had to be formally employed, even if most of them had 6-month
contracts and an income that could hardly pay the first installment on the mortgage; on
the other hand, they needed some kind of guarantee. However, unlike young Spanish
buyers, migrants had no relatives with a property of their own who could act as
guarantors. To bypass this obstacle, banks and estate agencies encouraged potential
buyers to tell their relatives or friends to get a mortgage too and buy an apartment. The
idea, then, was to get both parties to buy their new apartments, and use them as mutual
guarantors. This practice, termed a ‘crossed guarantee’, was supposedly forbidden, but
bankers could sidestep the soft regulation of the Bank of Spain if they were able to close
the mutual transaction in less than a month. Whenever a potential buyer refused to
encourage their relatives to take part in this form of fictitious endorsement, agents
attempted to get random buyers to guarantee each other, often without them actually
knowing.
   Due to the dissymmetry of information between buyers and financial institutions,
many migrants were victims of other abuses. For instance, potential clients were often
persuaded to get variable rate mortgages, and reassured that installment prices would not
increase. Not long after signing the contract, these buyers were shocked to find out that
their monthly installments had almost doubled. Also, in many cases, estate agents
and bankers inflated the loans in order to increase their own commissions, and they
sometimes added unnecessary insurance contracts without informing their clients.
   In a context of mania and seemingly unstoppable growth, local bankers and agents
were pushed, through both incentives and coercion, to ignore the few existing forms of
control and offer as many financial products as possible. From the point of view of
migrant buyers, the ‘wealth effects’ of the credit and housing bubble acted as an
encouragement: the general idea was that the constant appreciation of home values
would be an antidote to their weak and unstable sources of income. In their migration
process, the acquisition of a property was seen not only as a way to get a relatively stable
place to live in, but also as a valuable commodity that could be eventually transformed
into a powerful form of remittance or investment in their homeland.

The invisible bonds between credit and social networks
If credit and the ‘wealth effects’ of the bubble were a temporary ‘solution’ to the housing
problem and the rollback of the state, the other pillar was the capacity of buyers to build
networks of moral obligations around them. In fact, in order to secure their profits, banks
and agents leaned on the social relations of the people they granted mortgages to.9
    On the one hand, by ‘crossing guarantees’ between different individuals, banks tried
to secure the payment of installments: borrowers who did not pay knew that they would
put their guarantors in a real predicament, and vice versa. On the other hand, bankers
granting credits to migrants with low and precarious wages knew of the existence of a

9 It should be noted that the lending process described here resembles in many ways the microcredit
  operations in several countries of the global South, as exemplified by Rahman (2001) in Bangladesh.

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
12                                                                          Jaime Palomera

growing subletting market in the neighborhood. That is, financial institutions did not
grant loans on the basis of the buyers’ wages, which were often below the price of their
first installments, but on their capacity to find other sources of income, mainly through
the informal activity of subletting rooms. This was possible due to the existence of a huge
number of migrants who needed to find accommodation, usually undocumented,
unemployed or working in the informal economy, and who were therefore legally
unsuitable for a mortgage. Also, the specifications of the blocks in a polígono de vivienda
like Ciutat Meridiana, containing apartments of 65 square meters with three bedrooms,
allowed new owners and their main household to live in one of the rooms while
subletting the other two.
    Hence, it is possible to assert that the prolongation of the housing boom through its
final years (2004–7), during which practically one million migrants (out of six million)
became homeowners, was partly possible to the existence in these working-class spaces
in a subletting market. Following Polanyi (1957), part of the formal market was
embedded in moral relations between formal owners and informal tenants. The payment
of the legally regulated debt that new owners contracted with their banks depended on the
payment of the morally regulated debt that they created with their relatives, friends or
simply with cohabitants. These relations of moral debt are usually asymmetric, since the
payment of the rent by the tenant implies an accumulation of value by the owner.
However, the difference from a purely contractual relationship lies in the higher degree
of mutual understanding, especially when the link is established between relatives or
fellow compatriots.
    Let us describe the case of Saray, a Dominican woman who managed to save a small
amount of money as a domestic worker and got different loans to buy two apartments in
Ciutat Meridiana. By subletting all of the rooms in one apartment and some of the rooms
in the apartment that she and her boyfriend inhabited, Saray was able to pay her
installments regularly, and even obtain a surplus that she used to open a small fruit shop.
    Saray has many connections, not only with relatives from her homeland, but also with
different individuals and families she has met since she arrived in Barcelona in 1989.
Once she had settled in her new apartment in Ciutat Meridiana, this 40-year-old woman
started getting news from relatives who wanted her ‘to bring them’ to Barcelona, as
people usually say when established migrants use their resources to help others migrate.
When two female cousins landed in the city, with no work or residence permits, Saray
offered to put them up in one of her rooms. She also put them in touch with one of her
old employers, a wealthy Catalan woman who lived uptown, and who before long offered
them an informal job in her house. For the two cousins, the fact that Saray offered them
a roof and a job, besides keeping them company, is a form of moral support that they will
not forget. Also, they both know that whenever they have been unemployed and lacked
the money to pay the rent for their rooms, Saray has tried to give them enough time to get
it. In exchange, besides this payment, she expects them to voluntarily offer their support
in small tasks such as cooking or taking care of her shop counter.
    Thus, an ambiguous and often flexible form of reciprocity and patronage is established,
whereby these homeowners give access to key resources. In the process, they can increase
their prestige and achieve enough moral authority to expect their protégés to be disposed
to show their solidarity whenever it is required. What holds the relationship together is the
feeling that they all receive as much as they give. And the key element in the evaluation of
legitimacy on the part of the protégés is the relation between the degree of services he or
she gets and the degree of services they offer. The higher the ‘value’ they get from the
patron, the greater the possibility that they will see the link as legitimate (Scott, 1977). In
these networks, the fact that individuals in a legally vulnerable situation have access to a
room of their own and work through another migrant is usually perceived as a favor that
dilutes the economic relationship. Conversely, some relationships tend to be short-lived
precisely because they are explicitly perceived as exploitative: such is the case of owners
who sublet beds in crowded apartments in poor conditions and for prices that are higher
than what is deemed acceptable.

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
Homeownership and social fragmentation in a Spanish neighborhood                          13

   Since moral debt is not formally regulated, nor legislatively sanctioned, there is a
strong need to reaffirm it on a frequent basis, not only through small acts but also
verbally. Among Saray’s group of relatives, friends and countrywomen, there is a phrase
that is sometimes uttered: ‘we, the Dominicans, are very united’. Although it is usually
said as a way of making a positive judgment on the fact that some of them provide each
other with mutual support, the phrase also functions as a mode of coercion on those acts
that are suspected of evading the moral debts that sustain group solidarity. These
affirmations exert what Bourdieu (1992) appropriately calls symbolic violence, which
differs from the explicit violence that legally binds clients to banks. However, it can turn
out to be fundamental in securing the fulfillment of an invisible debt on which they
depend for their survival.
   Nevertheless, these forms of mutual responsibility are highly precarious and change
depending on the situation. When I met Saray, in 2007, at the peak of the housing boom,
I was able to see how she hosted an unemployed friend from Honduras who had become
pregnant and had been unable to meet her payments after four months. But in 2009,
almost two years after the crash and in the midst of a debt crisis, Saray began to change
her attitude, as she struggled to reconcile her moral sense of obligation towards her
relatives and friends with her own need to have reliable renters. Seeing that her shop was
losing money and that she was having trouble paying the bank, she started complaining
about tenants who did not pay her on time or asked her to let them pay less. Once, she
indignantly told me: ‘these people don’t understand how one suffers to pay the mortgage,
they think it’s easy for us!’ During the same period, I met other homeowners who for the
same reason had began adopting a ‘personal policy’ of subletting their rooms to people
other than compatriots or relatives. These impersonal relationships allowed them to ‘kick
them [tenants] out’ as soon as they stopped paying their rent, thus steering clear of
emotional conflicts.
   To sum up, regardless of the degree of moral debt at any given juncture, different
forms of bonds emerge between subjects, becoming an important source of social capital.
And this form of private solidarity is perfectly embedded in the housing market dynamic.
Rooms sublet by homeowners, and the relations that sustain these transactions, are an
asset not only for them but also and especially for financial institutions. Ultimately, banks
absorb the majority of resources that informally circulate through these networks, at the
expense of impoverishing most of their members.

The erosion of the social fabric: old and new migrants
The new reality of the working classes, epitomized in Ciutat Meridiana by the emergence
of a wave of migrants living in rented rooms, provides a stark contrast with the situation
of the more established residents, who usually live in homes with only one household.
   Although the population that settled in housing projects like Ciutat Meridiana at the
end of the 1960s and throughout the 1970s mostly came from very poor backgrounds,
getting an apartment of their own constituted a form of upward mobility. The
replacement of the shack with the apartment was combined with a model for the working
classes very much in the image of the ‘one home for each family’ middle-class ideal. In
other words, the social and economic project of turning proletarians into homeowners
came with its own cultural coating, designed to wipe away a complex world of extended
families living together in shantytowns — vilified by social hygienists as ‘promiscuous’.
The new propaganda is illustrated in the posters that were used to promote Ciutat
Meridiana in 1967, in which we see the image of a young couple — married or soon to
be married — eager to get a new apartment. That is, apartments were publicized as ideal
spaces for the newlyweds to start their family, very much in harmony with the logic of
the Fordist social division of labor: the female occupied with the tasks of reproduction
and the male at the factory.

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
14                                                                                  Jaime Palomera

    From the point of view of established residents, the recent residential transformation
emerges as a form of threat to the symbolic and material stability they had reached. The
housing boom and the countless transactions to buy and sell apartments (many of them
short-term) have eroded many of the communal spaces in the buildings. In the building
where I resided between 2008 and 2009, six out of ten homeowners had become
established there during the housing boom. As in many other blocks (especially those
without elevators and of lower quality) Spanish residents had seen many of the most
established residents leave.
    As a result of the speculative process, many old properties were acquired by new
residents: mostly foreigners who sometimes hosted relatives from their extended family
and often rented some of their rooms in order to finance their mortgages. Therefore, their
material conditions differ from those of old-timers. In these new homes, there were all
sorts of situations coexisting under the same roof: on the one hand, a situation of job
insecurity and legal vulnerability that afflicted room tenants, who often stayed only for
short periods due to their problems with meeting payment deadlines. On the other hand,
having acquired a stable legal status did not prevent new owners from getting into
trouble, for example, losing their job or being unable to find room tenants who could pay
them on a regular basis.
    Some homeowners have had to move to a relative’s apartment or a room and sublet their
entire apartment in order to keep paying their monthly installments and avoid foreclosure.
The Spanish Mortgage Law, unlike US legislation, does not free homeowners from their
debt once they are foreclosed. After the foreclosure, the property is auctioned, and since
there are no bidders, the bank that foreclosed on the house acquires it for half of what it cost
during the boom, when prices were peaking. As a result, foreclosed owners are left without
a roof and owing 50% of the mortgage to the bank for the rest of their life. Many
homeowners, aware of this reality that is already afflicting many neighbors (between 2008
and 2012 there were more than 300 foreclosures in Ciutat Meridiana according to the
Residents’ Association, and 350,000 in the Spanish state according to the anti-eviction
movement10), do everything they possibly can before losing their home.
    Consequently, the combination of high housing prices (worsened by the increase in
mortgage rates) and job insecurity makes living conditions very unstable for many of the
new residents.
    Additionally, during the housing boom many second-generation residents left and
sold their homes (or their deceased parents’ homes) to new migrants of similar age to
themselves. The result of this is that the new social and spatial division between
‘established’ and ‘precarious’ residents also contains a generational element. In the
building where I lived for a longish period, the four households of Spanish nationality
were married couples aged between 60 and 80, whereas the newly acquired homes were
all inhabited by migrant couples, aged between 20 and 40, with small children. Thus, a
significant proportion of the established residents who remained in Ciutat Meridiana
after the boom are retired and receiving a pension. However, these pensions tend to be
very small and some of them have difficulties ‘putting a dish on the table’, as an elderly
woman told me.
    Therefore, despite their homeowner status, the older generation is not so ‘established’.
In this context, the emergence of a new generation of impoverished migrants is perceived
not only as a symbolic threat to the ‘one-family-one-home’ lifestyle, but also to their own
material possibilities for social reproduction and mobility. One of the most widely spread

10 The name of the civil organization behind this social movement is Plataforma de Afectados por las
   Hipotecas (‘Movement for the people affected by mortgages’). It has received increasing public
   support ever since it began mobilizing against what it has called ‘financial genocide’ and a ‘scam’. Its
   main aims are to make the Spanish Parliament change the mortgage law, thus allowing people to
   cancel their financial debt once they lose their home, and to turn foreclosed homes into a stock of
   social housing for evicted families (including all those who have already lost their homes since
   2008).

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
© 2013 Urban Research Publications Limited
You can also read