EJTN AD On-line Classroom on Electronic Communication Law - 25 June 2021 Incentives for the deployment of Very High Capacity Networks (VHCN) J ...
←
→
Page content transcription
If your browser does not render page correctly, please read the page content below
EJTN AD On-line Classroom on Electronic Communication Law 25 June 2021 Incentives for the deployment of Very High Capacity Networks (VHCN) J. Scott Marcus With financial support from the Justice Programme of the European Union
Incentives for the deployment of VHCN • Introduction • Why full coverage with VHCN is difficult to achieve • Broadband coverage / penetration in the EU today • Regulatory instruments • Pricing flexibility and price controls • Non-discrimination • SMP Civil Engineering Infrastructure • Concluding observations ➢Portions are based on a 9 June 2021 public workshop for an ongoing study for DG CONNECT. 2
"Well, in our country," said Alice, still panting a little, "you'd generally get to somewhere else—if you run very fast for a long time, as we've been doing." "A slow sort of country!" said the Queen. "Now, here, you see, it takes all the running you can do, to keep in the same place. If you want to get somewhere else, you must run at least twice as fast as that! - from Through the Looking Glass 3
Market realities and regulation: Cause? Effect? • When the EU Regulatory Framework for Electronic Communications was first enacted in 2002: • There were 15 Member States, not 27. • Member states had near-complete copper coverage. • Limited cable coverage except NL/BE/MT. • National monopoly PTTs in most Member States. • Ten new Member States join in 2004, many in the east. • Historic under-investment in telecoms in the east. • Blessing and curse – a chance to deploy fibre and cable. • Cable rolls out in some new Member States (PL, HU). • Wholesale access enables competitive entry. • Local loop unbundling, bitstream, now VULA, also ducts. 5
The expansion of the EU in 2004 6
Historic evolution of EU electronic communications regulation • The initial RFEC sought to liberalise the sector and to open it up to competition. • This was effective – in most EU Member States, the majority of lines are provided by competitors. • Investment and innovation were explicit goals, but there were few explicit regulatory measures to promote them. • In an era of copper-based narrowband networks, this worked well enough, but it did not anticipate broadband needs. • Deployment of high speed broadband good but not great. • Multiple revisions in subsequent years sought to re-balance the system so as to do more to better promote investment. 7
Historic evolution of EU electronic communications regulation • A succession of regulatory instruments have sought to strike a progressively more pro- investment balance. • The Regulatory Framework for Electronic Communications (RFEC) (2002) • NGA Recommendation (2010) • Nondiscrimination and Costing Methodology (NDCM) Recommendation (2013) • Broadband Cost Reduction Directive (BCRD) (2014) • European Electronic Communications Code (EECC) (2018) • Also an increasing focus on access to civil engineering (ducts and poles), and on cooperative arrangements. 8
Competition? Investment? Both? • Art. 3 EECC (2018) establishes a series of general objectives, but without establishing a relative priority among them. • Two that are especially relevant here are: • to promote connectivity and access to, and take-up of, very high capacity networks, including fixed, mobile and wireless networks, by all citizens and businesses of the Union; • to promote competition in the provision of electronic communications networks and associated facilities, including efficient infrastructure-based competition, and in the provision of electronic communications services and associated services; … • Both are important, but there is tension between these two general objectives. • A sole focus on retail level competition would imply setting wholesale prices as low as possible, i.e. at (LRIC) cost. • Promoting investment implies setting prices higher. 9
Why full coverage with high quality broadband is difficult to achieve 10
The cost of last mile dominates • The human body is said to contain about 100,000 kilometres of arteries, veins and capillaries. • The vast majority of this length is in the capillaries. • For building a new network, or upgrading an existing network from copper-based to fibre- based, civil works costs associated with the last mile likewise tend to represent the bulk of the total cost.
Population density and dispersion • Population density is not the only driver of deployment costs, but it is a large driver. • The choice and cost of technology is also influenced by the labour costs, cost / availability of ducts and poles, deployed infrastructure (copper subloop lengths), and presence of cable. Source: Source: Center for International Earth Science Information Network (CIESIN). 12
Population density and dispersion • Cost and ARPU per customer per month for FTTH P2P Ethernet (Germany, 70% penetration) Source: WIK (2012), studies for German BMWi and LGI. 13
Population density and dispersion • Investment subsidy per customer required for FTTH P2P Ethernet (Germany) Source: WIK (2012), studies for German BMWi and LGI. 14
EU broadband coverage / penetration 15
Broadband in the EU • It is important to distinguish among: • Coverage (deployment), • Adoption (take-up), and • Usage. • Regulation of electronic communications deals almost exclusively with deployment, i.e. with the supply side. • A number of research results suggest that, once deployment is sufficiently widespread, demand side measures can be more effective than supply side in promoting usage. ➢The EU is doing well by many measures, but concern remains that we are not doing as well as we need to relative to some global competitors. 16
Broadband coverage in the EU • Next Generation Access (NGA) technologies (% of households) • VDSL incl. VDSL2 Vectoring • FTTP/FTTH • Cable DOCSIS 3.0 / 3.1 • Very High Capacity Networks (VHCN) • Any network providing a fixed-line connection with fibre roll out at least up to the multi-dwelling building; • Any network providing a wireless connection with fibre roll out up to the base station; • Other fixed and wireless networks subject to the quality delivered. - BEREC Guidelines Source: Broadband Coverage in Europe 2019 Mapping progress towards the coverage objectives of the Digital Agenda 17
Broadband coverage in the EU (% of households) Source: Broadband Coverage in Europe 2019 Mapping progress towards the coverage objectives of the Digital Agenda 18
Rural broadband coverage in the EU (% of households) Source: Broadband Coverage in Europe 2019 Mapping progress towards the coverage objectives of the Digital Agenda 19
EU broadband penetration in international perspective OECD Fixed broadband subscriptions per 100 inhabitants, by technology, June 2020 DSL Cable Fibre Satellite Fixed wireless Other Per 100 inhabitants 50 45 40 35 30 25 20 15 10 5 0 Source: OECD Broadband statistics [http://www.oecd.org/sti/broadband/broadband-statistics] 20
Questions up to this point? 21
Regulatory tools 22
Regulatory tools in the Access Recommendations • Price control and pricing flexibility • Price control and pricing flexibility • Price control and pricing flexibility • Nondiscrimination • Access to SMP operator Civil Engineering Infrastructure (CEI) • Geographic differentiation • Cooperative arrangements • Migration from copper-based to fibre-based networks ➢How much can be done with regulatory tools alone? 23
Pricing flexibility 24
Pricing flexibility • If a lack of effective competition means that the undertaking concerned may sustain prices at an excessively high level, or may apply a price squeeze, to the detriment of end-users, price control obligations must be imposed; • however, where (1) a demonstrable retail price constraint is present, and (2) obligations imposed including any Economic Replicability Test (ERT) ensure effective and non-discriminatory access, then the default approach should be pricing flexibility (no price control obligations) combined with nondiscrimination obligations. Art. 74(1) EECC ➢ Today, price control is about fixed network wholesale services. ➢ These provisions are used, but could be used even more. 25
The Economic Replicability Test (ERT) • The NDCM encourages the use Retail price of pricing flexibility where suitable conditions are met. Retail gross margin • Art. 74 EECC codifies core Wholesale price elements subject to there Possible additional being “a demonstrable retail wholesale profit price constraint” and where an “economic replicability test … ensures effective and non- discriminatory access”. • The ERT is a form of ex ante Presumed cost for Margin Squeeze Test (MST). wholesale service including WACC • For competitive entry to be possible, there has to be space between the wholesale price charged and the feasible retail price. NGA / VHCN 26
Price controls 27
Price controls • “Where the national regulatory authorities consider price control obligations to be appropriate, they shall allow the undertaking a reasonable rate of return on adequate capital employed, taking into account any risks specific to a particular new investment network project.” (Art. 74 EECC) • For regulatory purposes, the costs are generally estimated using bottom-up long run incremental cost (BU-LRIC) models. 28
The NGA risk premium • The NGA Recommendation recognises (point 23) that “costs of capital of the SMP operator for the purpose of setting access prices should reflect the higher risk of investment relative to investment into current networks based on copper.” • The WACC is the weighted average cost of capital. Cost of the Cost due to wholesale product WACC and Cost of the extra risk wholesale product Cost due to WACC Cost for Cost for wholesale wholesale service service Legacy NGA / VHCN 29
How high a risk premium? • The literature suggests (notably Bourreau, Cambini, Hoernig, and Vogelsang, 2020) that the higher the NGA risk premium, the greater the expected investment in NGA deployment. • One might argue on this basis for an arbitrarily large NGA risk premium; however, there are obvious problems in doing so. • There is no obvious objective basis on which to base the size of such a premium. • The approach potentially generates windfall profits for the SMP operator, to the detriment of competitors and consumers. • This is not the only way to promote more widespread deployment – there is also state aid, coverage obligations … • These considerations suggest that when estimating the cost of capital, NRAs should include an NGA risk premium that is high enough to compensate for all project-specific systematic risk, but no higher. 30
The risk premium: Are all relevant risks properly reflected? • Two aspects of systematic NGA/VHCN project-specific risk are rarely addressed in current EU regulatory practice. • The first seeks to enable investors to achieve an appropriate expected rate of return, taking into account both good and bad scenarios. Price caps limit the upside potential of the investment, while at the same time leaving investors fully exposed to the downside risks. Relatedly, there is the regulatory risk that the NGA risk premium is adjusted downward as soon as the project has succeeded. These asymmetries can deter investment if they imply that the expected returns at the outset of a seemingly profitable investment do not cover the expected cost of capital. • The second relates to the “option value” to the SMP operator of delaying the investment due to the expectation that uncertainties will to some extent be resolved in the future, allowing the investment to achieve a higher profitability. 31
The risk premium: Is the value of relinquishing the option to wait and see properly reflected? • Investments in NGA, FTTH or FTTC networks are characterised by irreversibility, uncertainty, and an implicit option to delay the investment until more information becomes available. • The option to “wait and see” might be worthless if the SMP operator is under substantial competitive pressure to deploy; in other cases, it might represent a meaningful cost for which risk is directly relevant. • Ofcom in the UK conducted a public consultation in 2005 that dealt with these aspects, and found them to be valid and relevant; however, they did not adopt, mainly because computation is challenging. • In Italy, AGCOM has been using Real Options since 2015. • The incremental cost can be quantified using Real Options methods such as Black-Scholes, binomial lattice methods or Monte Carlo methods. 32
A floor on wholesale prices? • The logic of the original RFEC was to enable retail service-based competition. • This implies the need for low prices for SMP wholesale access products. • Today, facilities-based competitors offer wholesale products in some Member States. ➢This might possibly imply a need for higher prices for SMP wholesale access products! 33
Non-discrimination 34
EoI versus EoO • In the EECC, “equivalence of inputs (EoI) is in principle the surest way of achieving effective protection from discrimination”. • It is not always proportional – for an existing service, switching from EoO to EoI imposes costs on all. • A well-crafted EoO regime (with good enforcement and suitable KPIs/SLAs/SLGs) might in principle be nearly as effective at protecting competition as an EoI regime. • The NDCM relies on EoI as a precondition for pricing flexibility. • The EECC calls for “strict non-discrimination obligations”. 35
KPIs, SLAs and SLGs • KPIs, SLAs and SLGs play a crucial role in implementing non-discrimination. • How they are set matters – in some Member States, a collaborative system overseen by the NRA involves both access seekers and the SMP operator. • In some Member States, penalties are too small to be dissuasive, or processes can drag on for years. 36
SMP Civil Engineering Infrastructure (CEI) 37
CEI is used less than it might be • Lack of availability: Some Member States have large numbers of ducts that are potentially usable by competitors, others have few or none. • Lack of quality: In many of the Member States, the quality of ducts has deteriorated. • Poor or lacking online directories (despite the fact the current Recommendation and the BCRD require them). • Segment-by-segment ordering processes. • Costly ancillary obligations, such as for SMP operator technicians to be present for installations or repairs. 38
SMP Civil Engineering Infrastructure (CEI) • In some Member States, SMP operators refuse CEI access to providers of non-FTTP VHCN (for instance, cable operators). • Some Member States require the SMP operator to designate firms qualified to deploy CEI on behalf of competitors. • In many Member States, database quality and ordering processes leave much to be desired. 39
Concluding observations 40
Concluding observations • Broadband policy: Revision of the broadband regulatory instruments (NGA Recommendation, Non- discrimination and Costing Methodology Recommendation (NDCM) in process. • Revision of the Broadband Cost Reduction Directive (BCRD) is likewise in process. • Some refinement should be expected, including fine tuning the balance between investment incentives versus competition. • There are, however, limits to what can be done • solely on the supply side, • solely with regulatory measures as distinct from industrial policy measures, • after 20 years of fine tuning have already been done. 41
Thank you! With financial support from the Justice Programme of the European Union 42
References • J. Scott Marcus, Christian Hocepied et al. (2021, forthcoming), Study on Regulatory Incentives for the Deployment of Very High Capacity Networks in the Context of the Revision of the Commission’s Access Recommendations. • J. Scott Marcus (2020, forthcoming), “Broadband Policy and Technology Developments: Review of the 2004 OECD Recommendation”, study for the OECD. • Francesco Caio, J. Scott Marcus and Gérard Pogorel (2014), “Achieving the Objectives of the Digital Agenda for Europe (DAE) in Italy: Prospects and Challenges”, a study for Prime Minister Letta. • J. Scott Marcus, Ilsa Godlovitch, et al. (2013), “Entertainment x.0 to boost Broadband Deployment”, study on behalf of the European Parliament's Committee on Industry, Research and Energy; October 2013, available at: http://www.europarl.europa.eu/committees/en/imco/studies.html#menuzone. 43
Backup slides
Legal underpinnings of the system: Draws on competition law concepts • Opening up market to competition was key in the RFEC • Telecoms regulation ex ante • Competition law (antitrust) ex post • Key asymmetric regulatory mechanisms in the RFEC • Each NRA identifies market susceptible to ex ante regulation, following a Commission Recommendation. • Each NRA identifies network operators that have Significant Market Power (SMP) on one of the markets. • Each NRA imposes proportionate remedies on any SMP network operators (accounting separation, wholesale access, price controls, …).
Definitions of NGA and VHCN • Next generation access (NGA) networks • … are “wired access networks which consist wholly or in part of optical elements and which are capable of delivering broadband access services with enhanced characteristics (such as higher throughput) as compared to those provided over already existing copper networks.” • They generally provide speeds greater than 30 Mbps - NGA Recommendation, 2010 • Very high capacity networks • Any network providing a fixed-line connection with fibre roll out at least up to the multi-dwelling building; • Any network providing a wireless connection with fibre roll out up to the base station; • Other fixed and wireless networks of comparable quality. BEREC Guidelines, 2020
Asymmetric Remedies • Unbundled local loop (ULL): a form of wholesale access where competitors can purchase access to the SMP operator’s copper or fibre circuit from the Main Distribution Frame to the customer premises. • Sub-Loop Unbundling (SLU): similar to LLU, but only the portion of the local loop from street cabinet to the customer premises is unbundled. • VULA: A virtual equivalent to ULL • Bitstream access: a virtual wholesale access product, generally delivered using ADSL over the copper network.
Capital expense for FTTCab/VDSL is favourable with short sub-loop lengths Cluster FTTH/P2P FTTCab Vectoring Delta in % • FTTcab/VDSL2 with vectoring 1 1,440 € 320 € 78% can cost considerably less per 2 1,650 € 350 € 79% household than FTTH, since it 3 1,740 € 370 € 79% 4 1,780 € 370 € 79% uses existing copper. 5 1,840 € 370 € 80% 6 1,940 € 380 € 80% • The exact difference depends 7 2,010 € 410 € 80% on population density. 8 2,180 € 420 € 81% 9 2,230 € 440 € 80% • This estimate shows the cost 10 2,410 € 480 € 80% 11 2,440 € 500 € 80% per home connected for 12 2,480 € 520 € 79% Germany at 70% penetration 13 2,560 € 560 € 78% in geotypes of progressively 14 2,640 € 600 € 77% 15 2,650 € 590 € 78% lower population density. 16 2,710 € 640 € 76% 17 2,670 € 680 € 75% 18 3,030 € 830 € 73% 19 3,410 € 1,020 € 70% 20 4,310 € 1,390 € 68% Total 2,410 € 560 € 77% Source: Karl-Heinz Neumann et al. (2014), „VDSL Vectoring reduziert Investitionsvolumen für Breitbandausbau deutlich“, in info (2014)
You can also read