How to shift the EU's spending priorities? The multi-annual financial framework 2007 - 13 in perspective

Page created by Jesse Crawford
 
CONTINUE READING
RJPP299838                                Techset Composition Ltd, Salisbury, U.K.   3/3/2008

      Journal of European Public Policy 15:4 June 2008: 531 – 549

      How to shift the EU’s spending
      priorities? The multi-annual financial
5
      framework 2007 – 13 in perspective
      Joachim Schild
10

15
          ABSTRACT At the Lisbon European Council in 2000, heads of state and govern-
          ment made strong political commitments to invest in Europe’s future, in order to
          transform its economy into ‘the most competitive knowledge based economy in
          the world’ by 2010. To what extent were the Lisbon goals translated into a shift
20
          in spending priorities during the negotiations on the EU’s multi-annual financial
          framework (2007 –13)? Could the stated competitiveness goals be underpinned by
          a reallocation of scarce financial resources in the EU’s budget? This paper starts
          with theoretical considerations on the odds of shifting financial priorities in the
          EU’s ‘consensus democracy’. Then it gives an overview of the slow pace of change
          to be found in the new financial perspective which is to be compared to earlier
          deals on the multi-annual budget since 1988. In order to explain this result, the
25
          political context and the sequence of decision-making is examined, looking at
          the respective roles of the Commission, the European Council, and the European
          Parliament.
          KEY WORDS EU budgetary politics; financial perspective; intergovernmental
          bargaining theory; joint decision trap; Lisbon goals; spending priorities.
30

      INTRODUCTION
      ‘As it stands today, the EU budget is a historical relic. Expenditures, revenues
35    and procedures are all inconsistent with the present and future state of EU inte-
      gration’ (Sapir et al. 2003: 162). This harsh criticism led the authors of the
      quoted study, commissioned by the European Commission and known as the
      ‘Sapir Report’, to formulate a number of reform proposals. The key intention
      was to transform the European budget so that it could become a major instru-
40    ment for the achievement of the Lisbon goals.
         At the Lisbon European Council in 2000, the European Union (EU) set itself
      the objective of becoming ‘the most competitive knowledge based economy in
      the world’ by 2010. Heads of state and government made political commit-
      ments to increase research budgets and to invest in Europe’s future. Of
45    course, the attainment of the Lisbon goals is primarily the responsibility of
                                     Journal of European Public Policy
                      ISSN 1350-1763 print; 1466-4429 online # 2008 Taylor & Francis
                                     http:==www.tandf.co.uk/journals
                                   DOI: 10.1080/13501760801996725
532    Journal of European Public Policy
     the member states. But the question still remains: How can the stated
     competitiveness goals be underpinned by a reallocation of scarce financial
     resources in the EU’s budget?
         The decisions on the multi-annual budget had to be taken against the back-
50   ground of ‘low-growth malaise’ in the EU and the failure to meet the goals of the
     Lisbon agenda, especially its competitiveness goal. One of the key questions
     with regard to these thorny budget negotiations was the following: Would the
     EU succeed in transforming its budget into a ‘Prodi/Barroso budget’, empha-
     sizing the competitiveness goals of the Lisbon agenda, after having had a ‘de
55   Gaulle budget’ which almost exclusively financed the common agricultural
     policy (CAP) in the 1970s, and a ‘Delors budget’ (Lafan and Lindner 2005:
     199) since the late 1980s, which channelled ever more money into cohesion
     policy and the structural funds?
         A cursory look at the first analyses and comments on the budget deal struck in
60   the early morning hours of 17 December 2005 points in the opposite direction: ‘A
     prolongation of the status quo’ (Becker 2006) or ‘New budget, old dilemmas’
     (Begg and Heinemann 2006). In this article, I shall try to have a closer look at
     the balance between the reform ambition of some – the Commission, the Euro-
     pean Parliament (EP), the British presidency – and the final results; at the balance
65   of innovative versus status quo elements. The paper starts with some theoretical
     considerations on the odds of shifting financial priorities in the EU’s ‘consensus
     democracy’. Then it gives a broad overview of the pace of change which is to
     be compared to earlier deals on the multi-annual budget since 1988. In order
     to explain the results, the sequence of decision-making – concentrating on the
70   expenditure side of the budget – is examined, looking at the respective roles of
     the Commission, the European Council, and the EP.

     THEORETICAL CONSIDERATIONS AND EMPIRICAL
75
     INDICATORS
     There are plenty of good reasons which lead us to expect that budgetary politics
     in the political system of the EU is status quo oriented and, at best, slow to
     change.
        The EU can be described as a political system quite close to Arend Lijphart’s
80   ideal type of a consensus model of democracy (Lijphart 1999: 42 – 7). Consen-
     sus democracies perform strongly in accommodating very divergent interests of
     their citizens, social groups or constituent parts; but they certainly do not have
     the reputation of being particularly well suited for swift shifts of political and
     financial priorities in response to new challenges and changed economic
85   circumstances.
        In the field of budgetary politics, the consensus features of the EU’s political
     system are clearly visible. The most important forum for striking a deal in the
     process of negotiating the financial framework of the EU is the European
     Council (Laffan and Lindner 2005: 196). Heads of state and government
90   have to broker a final political compromise after protracted bargaining in the
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   533
      Council. These periodic strategic bargains on large financial packages are subject
      to the condition of unanimous decision-making. In a later stage of decision-
      making, the European Commission and the EP must be taken on board in
      order to sign an ‘Interinstitutional Agreement’ (IIA) between the Commission,
95    the Council, and the EP. The IIA gives the political compromises of the Euro-
      pean Council a binding force with respect to the overall amount of the budget
      and the distribution of resources among the different budget headings. Theor-
      etically, the necessity of signing an IIA adds two further veto players to the
      process: the Commission and especially the EP, as the second branch of the
100   EU’s budgetary authority.
          A rational choice-oriented institutionalist interpretation of budgetary politics
      might point to the very high number of veto players – no less than 27 (25
      member states, the Commission, and the EP) at the latest round of negotiations
      on the multi-annual budget. This decision-making framework seems ideally
105   suited for resistance to change. It is also an ideal framework for defending
      vested interests, especially agricultural interests. Veto player analysis would
      then predict a small ‘win set’ and a high degree of policy stability (Tsebelis
      2002). Budgetary politics in the framework of the EU’s financial perspective
      thus quite closely resembles the ‘joint decision trap’ as analysed by Fritz
110   Scharpf (Scharpf 1988): the actors produce lowest common denominator
      decisions with widely undesired outcomes, at least from a European point of
      view, if one takes the financing of European public goods as the yardstick for
      evaluating the results of negotiations (Begg 2005: 17). Actors find themselves
      locked in a situation producing systematically suboptimal outcomes, heavily
115   favouring the status quo, and seemingly unable to change the decision-
      making rules to overcome this situation.
          A historical-institutionalist account of budgetary policy might point to the
      framing of single-point negotiations on the budget by the established practice
      of mid-term financial frameworks based on interinstitutional agreements, creat-
120   ing institutional and procedural path dependencies and preventing individual
      member states from leaving the table. Budgetary negotiations are seen as
      embedded in established institutional practices, behavioural norms and a pro-
      cedural acquis (Laffan 2000; Lindner 2006). Not to sign an interinstitutional
      agreement on the mid-term budget and instead to return to the conflict-
125   ridden annual budget negotiations of the 1970s and 1980s can be seen as
      running against the prevailing ‘logic of appropriateness’. This has important
      consequences for the ability of the EU to shift its expenditure priorities. The
      multi-annual financial perspectives are relatively rigid, and since 1993 spending
      priorities are fixed for no less than seven years. The price to pay for improving
130   efficiency and reducing conflict in budgetary politics through a rule-bound and
      predictable procedure was to reduce flexibility and to introduce a status quo bias
      (Enderlein et al. 2005: 27).
          Nevertheless, change does occur. It may even occur at a tremendous pace in a
      short period of time. Why and under which circumstances is change possible or
135   even likely?
534   Journal of European Public Policy
        Five sources of policy change might be identified:
      . Package deals between member states, linking the negotiations on the budget
        to a broader agenda of integrative steps.
140
      . The policy environment: high economic growth rates and sound national
        budgetary situations allow not only for a higher EU budget but also for
        shifts in the structure of the budget owing to above-average growth rates of
        prioritized budget headings.
      . Changes in the interests of individual member states.
145
      . Changes in the configuration of member states’ interests.
      . Strong institutional political leadership, especially an agenda-setting power of
        the Commission.
         An intergovernmentalist or ‘exchange’ explanation of budgetary nego-
      tiations would point, first of all, to large package deals and the use of
150   side-payments in their context as a possible tool for change. This tool has
      been widely used in the past, especially in negotiating the so-called Delors
      I and Delors II packages in 1988 and 1993. The structure and composition
      of the EU’s budget were changed quickly and profoundly, the share of struc- Q1
      tural funds within the overall budget rising from 15 per cent in 1988 to no
155   less than 30 per cent in 1992 and reaching a peak in 1999 at 36 per cent of
      the budget.1 The major reason is to be found in the logic of side-payments.
      In the two cases of the Delors I and Delors II packages, the Commission
      took advantage of a favourable configuration of member state interests that
      provided it with a ‘window of opportunity’ for itself and a group of
160   member states. The pursuit of the single European market project in the
      second half of the 1980s and of the historical project of building the econ-
      omic and monetary union (EMU) at the beginning of the 1990s, high on the
      agenda of the economically most advanced member states, afforded the less
      advanced member states tremendous negotiating power. They obtained
165   huge compensation payments, the doubling of structural fund resources
      from 1988 to 1992, and a further steep increase of structural funds as well
      as the creation of the cohesion fund in 1993 (Allen 2005: 217– 22; Gerbet
      1999: 435; Moravcsik 1998: 374).
         The political economy of these changes was such that the increasing share
170   of the structural funds and the cohesion fund could be financed by an overall
      increase in the budget, that is ‘on top’ and not at the expense of other budget
      headings such as the CAP. The financial burden was shifted to taxpayers,
      especially in those member states, such as Germany, which had to foot the
      bill.
175      Thus change in spending priorities seems most likely under two conditions:
      If there is a ‘big integration project’ highly prioritized by a critical mass of
      member states in a policy environment of a growing budget, when the shift
      in spending priorities is gradual in nature, without imposing net sacrifices
      for vested interests and creating the impression of a positive sum game. On
180   the other hand, change is much less likely in a situation where national
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   535
      finance ministers are keeping a tight hold on their governments’ purse strings
      owing to high deficits in their national budgets. In such a case, a zero-sum
      logic of budgetary decision-making is likely to prevail, creating clearly ident-
      ifiable loser groups.
185       From an intergovernmental bargaining point of view, room for change in
      spending priorities also depends very much on changes in the political prefer-
      ences of member states (which usually do not change quickly) and changes in
      the configuration of preferences. The latter might occur following enlargements
      of the EU, increasing the heterogeneity among member states in their level of
190   prosperity and affecting the balance of power between net receivers and net con-
      tributors to the budget (Lindner 2006: 29).
          Hence intergovernmental bargaining theory leads us to believe that quite
      favourable conditions must be met in order to shift spending priorities under
      the condition of unanimous decision-making. This is probably the case as
195   long as calculations of net balances of budget flows are used by individual
      member states as a proxy variable for their ‘national interests’.
          A neofunctionalist interpretation would point to the power of supranational
      institutions, especially the agenda-setting power of the Commission. Under
      favourable circumstances, the Commission might use a ‘policy window’
200   (Kingdon 1984) to press for change. This might be the case if the Commission
      can rely on the support of a transnational coalition of interests (Laffan 1997:
      63– 9, 103– 6). Following this line of reasoning, the agenda-setting and nego-
      tiating skills of the Delors Commission are frequently cited in the literature
      in order to explain the setting-up of the first financial framework in 1988 and
205   the steep increase in structural fund spending (Hooghe 1996; Laffan 1997:
      63– 9; Laffan 2000: 730– 3).
          But what exactly do we mean when we speak of a change in spending priori-
      ties? The following empirical indicators will be used in order to track changes to
      Lisbon-related spending priorities:
210
      . The budget share of research and development (R&D) Expenditures.2 This
        can be seen as the most clear-cut expression of the ‘future-oriented nature’
        of the budget.
      . The planned evolution of so-called goal (1a) expenditures (‘Competitiveness
215     for growth and employment’) which, according to the Commission, should
        translate the Lisbon goals in a newly introduced separate budget heading.
        This budget heading includes, amongst other things, R&D expenditures,
        funds for transport and energy, for education and training, and for a compe-
        titiveness and innovation programme. As R&D expenditures represent the
220     main item in this budget heading (65 per cent of the total sum), it is close
        to the first indicator.
      . Besides these quantitative indicators, I will look for qualitative changes in the
        ways the structural funds are to be spent and how the Commission will make
        sure that the Lisbon goals guide the selection of projects to be co-financed by
225     the Community.
536     Journal of European Public Policy

      THE OVERALL PICTURE: HOW MUCH CHANGE?
      Let us first look at long-term trends in the overall increase in the budget before
      turning to its structure. In order to get an impression of the political will to
230
      change the budget, we might compare the rate of change as reflected in the
      decisions on the financial perspectives since 1988. It seems better not to look
      at real spending in the past, but at the projected change of spending patterns
      at the time of decision-making in order to make a judgement on the willingness
      of political decision-makers to listen to the ‘winds of change’.
235
          The first two multi-annual financial frameworks of the Community, the
      so-called Delors I and Delors II packages, contained a substantial increase in
      the maximum amount of own resources available at the Community level.
      Since 1999 and the ‘Agenda 2000’ package, however, ‘stabilisation of
      expenditure was the main concern of the member states during the negotiations’
240
      (European Commission 2002: 81).
          As an indicator for the pace of change, we can compare the average annual
      growth rate (in constant prices) of all financial perspectives up to now, as
      projected at the time of decision-making and expressed in the respective IIAs.
      See Table 1. It is quite clear that the new financial perspective marks a
245
      turning point with regard to budget growth rates. New political priorities are
      hard to finance in an ‘on-top’ manner when the average annual growth rate
      falls below 1 per cent in real terms, staying well below the projected gross
      national income (GNI) growth rate of 2.3 per cent. The question of how a
      slowly increasing Brussels pie is cut into slices becomes all the more important.
250
          In order to have a more detailed picture of the amount of change, we can
      start by looking at the empirical indicator which should tap the ‘future-
      oriented’ nature of the budget in the most direct way. Figure 1 displays the
      ratio of R&D expenditures as a share of the global budget3 for the timespan
      1968 to 2004, expressed in real payments, and 2005 to 2013, expressed in
255
      appropriations for commitments. It is evident from Figure 1 that the EU is

      Table 1 Average real annual budget growth rates: comparison of financial
260   Perspectives 1988 – 2013

      Delors I              Delors II             Agenda 2000             Agenda 2007
      1988 – 92             1993 –99               2000 – 06               2007 – 13

      3.9 %                   3.3 %                  2.6 %                    0.9 %
265
      Sources: Own calculations, figures up to Agenda 2000 based on: European
      Commission, DG for Budget, ‘European Union. Public finance’, Luxembourg 2002,
      pp. 38, 57 and 82; figures for 2007 –13 in: Interinstitutional Agreement between
      the European Parliament, the Council and the Commission on budgetary discipline
      and sound financial management, Official Journal of the European Union, 2006/C
270   139, June 2006, p. 10.
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   537

275

280

285

      Figure 1 R&D expenditures (percentage share of the overall budget)6                  Q4

      making an effort to bring the budget more in line with the Lisbon goals. The
290
      part of R&D expenditures as a share of the global budget will rise by 2.7 per-
      centage points from 4.3 per cent in 2007 to 7 per cent in 2013, representing an
      increase of 75 per cent from 2006 to 2013 (in constant prices).4 Nonetheless,
      this remains well below the initial proposal of the Commission, which foresaw
      in increase of no less than 166 per cent for the same period (2006– 13) to a
295
      share of 8.6 per cent of the budget in 2013).5 Our second empirical indicator,
      the overall share of the ‘Lisbon’ heading inside the financial perspective, dis-
      plays indeed a growing segment for the years to come, rising from 7 per
      cent of the overall budget in 2007 to 10.2 per cent in 2013.7
          Change there is, but only of a slow and incremental nature. It does not in any
300
      way come close to the sweeping change introduced in the budget structure and
      its priorities over time reflected in the Delors I and Delors II packages. As the
      long-term evolution of the EU’s budget structure makes clear (see Figure 2),
      there were times in the past when profound changes in spending priorities
      could be agreed upon and were translated into the annual budgets. The question
305
      of why there was no serious effort to use the budget as a tool-kit for reforms
      becomes all the more important.

310
      THE COMMISSION: AN AGENDA-SETTER WITH CLIPPED
      WINGS
      The agenda-setting power of the Commission has been tightly constrained in
      this round of budgetary policy-making. The first major decision was taken in
      October 2002. During the final stage of the negotiations opening the way for
315   Eastern enlargement, France and Germany found a compromise on CAP spend-
538   Journal of European Public Policy

320

325

330

      Figure 2 Share of different policies in total EU spending 1958 – 2005 (percentage
      payments)
      Source: European Union. Financial Report 2005, Luxembourg: Office for Official
      Publications of the European Communities, 2006, Annex I, Table 11 (Community
335   budget only).

      ing up to 2013. This bilateral agreement was endorsed, with little change, by the
      European Council of Brussels.8 France got its way in securing the financial inter-
340   est of French farmers. As a consequence of this decision, the most important
      budget subheading was politically locked in until 2013. Shifting financial priori-
      ties in favour of the competitiveness goals of the Lisbon agenda without rever-
      sing this European Council decision could only mean redistribution among the
      other budget headings.
345      The second important constraint with regard to the agenda-setting power of
      the Commission was to be found in a joint letter from six member states, all net
      contributors to the EU budget, to the president of the Commission dating from
      December 2003.9 In this letter, Austria, France, Germany, the Netherlands,
      Sweden and the UK warned the Commission that they would not be prepared
350   to accept a budget beyond the actual level of the EU’s expenditures of 1 per cent
      of the EU’s GNI. For the first time since the introduction of the multi-annual
      financial frameworks, a powerful group of countries did not even wait for the
      Commission to put its proposal on the table before publicly building coalitions
      and loudly stating their preferences.
355      After hot internal disputes (Steenblock and Hartwig: 2004: 85) the Commis-
      sion took a rather cautious approach. In its proposal, published in February
      2004,10 it anticipated the member states’ reluctance to increase the budget in
      an environment of sluggish growth rates by foreseeing average yearly spending
      commitments of 1.14 per cent of GNI and a lower growth rate of the budget
360   than in the past. Furthermore, the Commission did not want to reopen the
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?        539
      debate on CAP spending. In view of this rather conservative approach, the
      Parliament reproached the Commission for not playing ‘its role of “honest
      broker” between the Parliament and the Council’ and for its ‘tendency to
      play in favour of the Council’.11
365       Nevertheless, the Commission proposal contained a pronounced shift in the
      allocation of resources between the different budget headings ‘towards growth
      and employment with a focus on knowledge based activities such as research
      and innovation’.12 In particular, subheading (1a) ‘Competitiveness for growth
      and employment’, heading (3) ‘Citizenship, freedom, security and justice’, and
370   heading (4) ‘The EU as a global partner’ foresaw important increases in spending
      (see Table 2). However, what looks at first glance like a bold proposal must be
      seen in the light of the aforementioned constraints on the negotiations. It was
      clear right from the start that the final result would lie somewhere between the
      Commission’s proposal and the 1 per cent limit set by the net contributors. It
375   was also equally clear that the CAP heading would be almost completely
      exempted from downward adjustments and that the second largest budget
      item, cohesion policy, would have important defenders among the member
      states. The odds of deep cuts by the Council into the headings with the highest
      percentage increase in the Commission’s initial proposals were thus quite high.
380       The proposal nevertheless contained a number of innovative elements point-
      ing towards the realization of the Lisbon goals. Most importantly, the Commis-
      sion advocated some qualitative changes in cohesion policy. It made it clear that
      it would push towards the integration of the Lisbon goals with the national or
      regional development plans to be negotiated in the cohesion policy between
385   itself and the member states. This push would be based on strategy papers to
      be adopted by the Council on the spending priorities for cohesion policy

      Table 2 Shift in the allocation of resources between budget headings 2006–13
390   according to the Commission’s proposal from February 2004 (in constant 2004 prices)

                                                       2006        2013      Difference %

      1 Sustainable growth                            46,621      75,950          63
        (1a) Competitiveness for growth and           8,791       25,825         194
395     employment
        (1b) Cohesion for growth and employment       37,830      50,125              33
      2 Preservation and management of natural        56,015      57,805               3
        resources
        of which: agriculture – market-related        43,735      42,293          23
400     expenditure and direct payments
      3 Citizenship, freedom, security and justice    2,342       4,455               90
      4 the EU as a global partner                    11,232      15,740              40

      Sources: Own computation, figures based on European Commission. Commission
      tables’ detailed proposals for Community spending for 2007 – 13, IP/04/910, Brus-
405   sels, 14 July 2004.
540    Journal of European Public Policy
      funds, eventually giving the Commission a lever to channel more money
      towards innovative industries or research instead of spending on infrastructure
      projects. Particularly in the second objective of the cohesion policy, the ‘regional
      competitiveness and employment’ goal, the Commission made it clear that
410   ‘interventions would need to concentrate on a limited number of policy priori-
      ties linked to the Lisbon and Goteborg agenda.’13 The ‘Lisbon rhetoric’ was skil-
      fully used by the Commission in its institutional self-interest to push for a bigger
      budget and for tighter control of the member states’ cohesion policy.14
         But the ability of the Commission to set the agenda for the upcoming budget
415   debates was narrowly circumscribed. The limited role of the Commission
      during the agenda 2007 negotiating process stands in distinct contrast to its
      earlier performance in contributing to a shift in political and financial priorities,
      especially in the 1988 and 1992 negotiations on the Delors I and Delors II
      packages.
420

      BARGAINING IN THE COUNCIL
      Within the Council, there were few advocates for change in the Lisbon goals.
      Such an advocacy role in favour of making the competitiveness of the EU the
425   overriding goal would have found its expression in:
      (a) calling into question the locking-in of the CAP budget up to 2013;
      (b) a clearly expressed preference for high expenditures under budget heading
          (1a) ‘Competitiveness for growth and employment’;
430
      (c) a preference for an enlarged budget, allowing for a higher share of Lisbon-
          related items in the budget without cutting back the absolute volume of
          CAP and cohesion policy funds.
      It is no surprise that this last option found the greatest number of supporters,
      especially among the member states receiving net flows from the budget.
435   During the negotiations in the Council, the member states held widely diver-
      ging views on the overall level of EU spending, ranging from strong support
      of the Commission’s proposal by many delegations to the position outlined
      by the six net contributors in their joint letter. In terms of appropriations for
      commitments, the Commission’s proposal suggested an average figure of 1.26
440   per cent of GNI, whereas the six net contributors made clear during the nego-
      tiations that their figure of 1 per cent of GNI did not refer to appropriations for
      spending but for commitments (usually substantially higher then appropriations
      for spending, let alone effective spending levels).15 Because of the joint ‘letter of
      the six’ in December 2003, the member states receiving net flows and pleading
445   for a rising overall scope of the budget in an enlarged Union found themselves
      on the defensive right from the beginning.
          Shifting financial priorities under the condition of a stable upper ceiling of
      expenditures (relative to GNI) and the balanced budget rule would have
      meant redistributing resources not only between budget headings but also
450   between member states. The only way to avoid conflicts in redistribution
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   541
      would be to reallocate resources only at the margins, translating the growth-
      driven rise in the overall budget into differential growth rates for individual
      expenditure headings. During the earlier phases of the negotiating process,
      only Sweden pushed for bringing the CAP issue back on to the table (Becker
455   2005: 187). Great Britain raised the CAP issue too, but this was only done in
      the latest stages of the process in response to increased French political pressure
      to abolish the British budget rebate (as France is the member state bearing the
      greatest burden of financing this rebate). Tony Blair had accepted, grudgingly,
      the compromise on CAP spending in October 2002, and during the whole
460   negotiating process, up to the first failure to come to an agreement in June
      2005 under the presidency of Luxembourg, the British made no attempt to
      reopen the CAP issue (Mayhew 2005). The fervent plea of Tony Blair in
      favour of a future-oriented budget16 was not reflected in the behaviour of the
      British delegation at the negotiation table up to this point. The attacks on
465   CAP spending during the British presidency served the double purpose of
      defending the British rebate against powerful opponents and of taking stock
      for the next financial perspective.
         The compromise hammered out by the European Council17 in the night of
      16– 17 December 2005 was very close to the initial positions of the net contri-
470   buting states:

      . The own resources ceiling remained unchanged at 1.24 per cent of GNI.
      . Overall spending in terms of appropriations for commitments was set at a
        level of 862.4 billion E (in constant 2004 prices) for the entire period
475     from 2007 to 2013, representing 1.045 per cent of EU GNI. These figures
        translate beyond any doubt into a political victory for the net contributing
        states. In terms of spending commitments, always lower than commitments
        for appropriation, this comes close to their initial demand of 1 per cent.
      . The funds included under the Lisbon heading (1a) ‘Competitiveness for
480     growth and employment’) were to be increased from 8.250 million E in
        2007 to 12.600 million E in 2013, which represents 7.5 per cent annual Q2
        real growth compared to 2006, well below the growth rate proposed by the
        Commission.
      . Inside this budget subheading, composed of five broad objectives –
485     research and technological development, European networks, education
        and training, promoting competitiveness in a fully integrated single
        market, and the social policy agenda – the European Council favoured a
        clear priority for research funding that ‘should therefore be increased
        such that by 2013 the resources available are around 75 per cent higher
490     in real terms than in 2006’.18
      . With regard to the pursuit of the Lisbon goals using instruments of the EU’s
        cohesion policy, the European Council followed the basic concept of the
        Commission. It agreed that 60 per cent of the money to be spent under
        the ‘convergence objective’ and 75 per cent of the sums spent under
495     the ‘regional competitiveness and employment objective’ should be spent
542   Journal of European Public Policy
        according to criteria designed to ensure that the goals of the Lisbon agenda
        would be met by the programmes and projects funded through the structural
        funds and the cohesion fund. These criteria, however, only apply to the EU
        15, and not to the new member states. This means that roughly 60 per cent of
500     the resources available for cohesion policy in the EU 15 are to be spent
        according to Lisbon-related spending criteria that have to be defined by the
        Council based on a proposal from the Commission. As roughly 50 per
        cent of the resources dedicated to the EU’s cohesion policy will be going
        to the EU 15, this means in turn that at least 30 per cent of the entire sum
505     of cohesion policy resources (adding up to 307.7 billion E) will be distributed
        using the Lisbon-related criteria for allocating scarce resources.
      The overall picture conveyed by the European Council’s decisions is that of slow
      progress on expenditure. Just as many observers assumed before the end-game
510
      inside the European Council, R&D expenditures suffered the deepest cuts com-
      pared to the initial proposal of the Commission.
         Of course, there is a certain emphasis on the Lisbon-related budget heading
      and especially on R&D spending. However, these high growth rates start from a
      low absolute level of spending. A thorough reorientation of priorities, as called
515
      for by the Sapir Report, would have led to quite different spending patterns
      (Begg and Heinemann 2006: 1).

      THE PARLIAMENT: A POWERLESS VETO PLAYER?
520   The EP was a veto player in the negotiation process on the multi-annual finan-
      cial framework. Its consent was necessary as it had to sign an IIA with the
      Council and the Commission in order to give a binding force to the political
      compromises on the multi-annual budget hammered out by the European
      Council. How did the EP use its veto power?
525      In order to strengthen its position, the Parliament set up a temporary com-
      mittee – for the first time since the financial perspective came into existence –
      and adopted – equally for the first time – a comprehensive negotiation position
      in advance of the European Council’s final agreement on the budget.
         The EP broadly supported the approach taken by the Commission in its
530   initial proposal from February 2004. It welcomed the substantial increases in
      spending under the Lisbon heading, and in the two other fields singled out
      by the Commission as deserving additional funds in order to match the EU’s
      political priorities, namely Justice and Home Affairs and External Relations
      of the EU. Nevertheless, it proposed to reduce the Lisbon heading in the Com-
535   mission’s proposal in order to shift 4 billion E Lisbon-related funds (mainly
      heading (1a)) to heading (3): Citizenship (1.3 billion E) and to heading (4)
      The EU as a global partner (2.7 billion E).20 It also advocated a gradual intro-
      duction of compulsory national co-financing of the CAP by the EU 15 member
      states which would have reduced the financial burden for the Community’s
540   budget. However, the EP’s own proposal was close to the Commission’s with
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   543
      regard to overall spending and the breakdown between the individual headings
      of the budget (see Table 3).
         Following the European Council’s decision to inflict heavy cuts on the
      amount of money available for the political priorities stated by the Commission
545   and the Parliament, the EP deplored ‘the unacceptable reduction in commit-
      ments in respect of competitiveness, growth and employment, despite the
      emphasis given by all the EU institutions to the Lisbon strategy and the cuts
      in relation to citizenship, freedom, security and justice and external actions’21
      and rejected the European Council’s agreement.
550      Despite its strong rhetoric, the EP was only marginally able to influence the
      final outcome. It raised the overall budget by 2 billion E to a level of 864 billion
      E, an increase of just 0.23 per cent compared to the European Council agree-
      ment of 17 December 2005. This small increase went mainly to the competi-
      tiveness or Lisbon heading.
555      The fact that the amount and distribution of the multi-annual budget, as
      agreed upon in the European Council, remained, by and large, unchanged
      does not really come as a surprise in the light of past developments (see Table 4).
         Why is the influence of the EP on the final outcome of the negotiations so
      negligible? Usually, the EP is keen to use the leverage given to it by its veto
560   right on the IIA to improve its procedural rights in the yearly budget battle
      with the Council (Becker 2005). Institutional self-interest prevails over policy
      interests. The EP might also find it difficult, internally, to balance the policy
      priorities of its members and its committees. Nevertheless, it had different
      policy and budgetary priorities from the Council (see Table 3).
565      The main reason for its lack of influence is to be found in the sequence of
      moves in this collective game. After the Commission’s initial proposal,
      decision-making shifts to the Council. When the European Council, after
      protracted and highly conflict-laden negotiations on thorny distributional
      issues, finally reaches agreement, it is extremely hard for the EP to reopen
570   this package. The EP comes seriously into play only when negotiating the
      IIA with the Council and the Commission. During the 2005 round of nego-
      tiations, where the European Council only reached an agreement at the
      second attempt after the first failure of June 2005, the EP’s room for
      manoeuvre was extremely limited, all the more so as the time factor was
575   running against its interests. The closer the start of a new period of the finan-
      cial perspective without final agreement between the institutions, the greater
      the political pressures will be. This is a result of the complexity of the nego-
      tiations, where agreement between the institutions on the financial perspec-
      tive is closely linked to the arena of decision-making on the legislative
580   package, as it opens the way for adoption of the individual spending
      programmes. This explains the highly binding nature of the political compro-
      mise struck between the member states at European Council level (Becker
      2005: 183). The EP could only take a hard line at the risk of a breakaway
      of the Members of the European Parliament (MEPs) from poorer member
585   states which depend on the timely flow of regional aid.
630

              625

                              620

                                             615

                                                             610

                                                                            605

                                                                                            600

                                                                                                            595

                                                                                                                            590

                                                                                                                                               544
                                                                                                                                               Journal of European Public Policy
Table 3 : Financial perspective 2004 – 13: initial proposals and final results

                                                                                                                  Difference
                                             European         European           European                         IIA – COM       Difference
                                            Commission       Parliament           Council   Interinstitutional     proposal       IIA– COM
                                             (10 Feb.          (8 June           (17 Dec.       Agreement         (in million      proposal
                                              2004)             2005)             2005)        (May 2006)            euro)            (%)

1 Sustainable growth                         458,015         459,035        379,739               382,139         275,876          216,6
(1a) Competitiveness for growth and          121,685         120,563         72,120                74,098         247,587          239,1
   employment
(1b) Cohesion for growth and                 336,330         338,472        307,619               308,041         228,289            28,4
   employment
2 Preservation and management of             400,275         396,248        371,245               371,344         228,931            27,2
   natural resources
of which: Agriculture – market support       301,074         293,105        293,105               293,105          27,969            22,6
   measures and direct aid payments
3 Citizenship, freedom, security and          20,945          19,437             10,270            10,770         210,175          248,6
   justice
4 The EU as global partner                    87,890          70,697             50,010            49,463         238,427          243,7
5 Administration                              57,670          28,62019           50,300            49,800          27,870          213,6
6 Compensation (Bulgaria, Romania)               240             800                800               800             560          233,3
Total commitment appropriations            1,025,035         974,837        862,364               864,316          160,719         215,7
in % of GNI                                        1.26            1.18           1.05                  1.05

Sources: Cf. notes 7, 10, 17 and 20 (own computation).
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   545
      Table 4 Political agreement of the European Council and Interinstitutional
      Agreement compared (in billion E/ECUs)

                                          European       Interinstitutional     Difference
                                           Council          Agreement                %
635
      Delors II package (1993– 99)         530.5               528.9               21.6
      Agenda 2000 (2000– 06)               702.8               704.2                1.5
      Agenda 2007 (2007– 13)               862.4               864.3                2.0

      Sources: Cf. Table 1.
640

      THEORETICAL LESSONS FROM THE AGENDA 2007 AND
      FUTURE PROSPECTS
645   In the past, changes in overall levels of the budget and in spending priorities
      were possible when budgetary decision-making was linked to major integration
      projects, and when net contributors to the budget were willing to accept side-
      payments in order to advance their interests in non-budgetary policy fields
      (single market in 1988, monetary union in 1992). The experience of the nego-
650   tiations on the financial framework 2007– 13 shows, ex negativo, the strength of
      the side-payment argument. In this case, there was no major integrative hurdle
      to be overcome and, accordingly, the net contributors were less willing to
      accommodate the interests of poorer member states. This finding is in line
      with an intergovernmentalist or ‘exchange’ explanation of budgetary
655   negotiations.
         Another lesson is that changes in individual member states’ preferences, and
      especially the changing configuration of interests in the European Council, have
      huge repercussions on both the climate and the result of the negotiations.
      Germany was less willing than ever to foot the bill for a growing budget
660   (Maurer et al. 2004), owing to the consequences of reunification for the national
      budget and owing to her failure, during four years (2002– 05), to comply with
      the deficit criteria of the Stability and Growth Pact.
         Overall, the balance of power between net contributors and net recipients
      among the member states has shifted profoundly. Until 1988 only Germany
665   and the UK were net contributors to the budget, but already by the mid-
      1990s, with the accession of Austria, Finland and Sweden, the majority of
      member states were net contributors. Of course, this situation changed again
      with the accession of ten new member states, most of them net recipients.
      However, the existence of a powerful and influential coalition of net contribu-
670   tors profoundly changed the configuration of member states’ interests under-
      lying this round of budget negotiations. Hence, a rationalist, interest-based
      and intergovernmentalist approach is very powerful in accounting for the
      final outcome of the negotiations, at least in terms of overall budget size.
         With regard to spending priorities, the negotiations leading to the financial fra-
675   mework 2007–13 have clearly shown that ‘competitiveness’, being a somewhat
546    Journal of European Public Policy
      diffuse goal, does not have a strong lobby inside the EU’s decision-making
      process. As the group of potential ‘Lisbon budget’ winners is quite large and
      diffuse and as the potential losers of a shift in priorities are more concentrated
      and politically more vociferous, the Commission was not able to build a powerful
680   coalition of societal actors and interest groups to push for a change in spending
      priorities. The unpredictability of the distributive impact of Lisbon-related expen-
      ditures – for example, in the case of research expenditure, where research teams
      have to apply competitively for EU funding – is another aspect of the expla-
      nation. Member states, following a logic of net flows from the budget, were
685   more reluctant to increase this budget heading at the expense of others, where con-
      sequences in terms of net flows were more predictable.
         The Commission’s main success in framing the budgetary debates in terms of
      the competitiveness goal of the Lisbon agenda was to gain better control over
      member state cohesion policy. But this detail in a complex overall picture
690   does not strongly support neofunctionalist claims.
         With regard to the funding of the global role of the Union, the lack of a
      powerful lobby inside the EU might explain the huge difference between the
      initial proposal of the Commission (heading (4): ‘The EU as a global
      partner’) and the final result (see Table 3). Vested interests inside the EU
695   prevail over potential beneficiaries in third countries.
         Another lesson is the importance of path dependencies as emphasized by his-
      torical institutionalists: cases in point are the British rebate and extra funds for
      cohesion policy for individual countries and regions without any economic
      rationale. Special arrangements like those in favour of thinly populated
700   regions in wealthy countries such as Sweden, Finland and Austria are the politi-
      cal price for reaching an agreement under unanimity conditions.
         Discontent with the current structure of the budget found its expression in a
      revision clause in the European Council’s conclusion of December 2005 which
      was actively supported by Sweden, Great Britain and the EP. In 2008– 09, there
705   will be a ‘full, wide ranging review covering all aspects of EU spending, including
      the CAP’22 based on a Commission report. The Commission started a broad
      consultation process in September 2007 to launch this debate in order to
      prepare the negotiations on the next financial framework 2014– 20.23 Are
      there any reasons to believe that the upcoming round of negotiations might be
710   more successful than the last in shifting spending priorities towards a Lisbon-
      oriented budget, given an even higher number of veto players (because of the
      accession of Bulgaria and Romania) and unchanged decision-making rules?
         Two potential sources of change may be identified: a possible change in the
      policy environment and a change in member state preferences. The tremendous
715   and potentially long-lasting increase in agricultural commodity prices on the
      world market clearly changes the policy environment for the agenda 2014 nego-
      tiations, and could open a window of opportunity for reducing agricultural sub-
      sidies. The odds of CAP reform might be improved by the fact that France’s
      economic benefits from this policy will be more and more reduced after the
720   phasing-in of the new member states into the CAP framework of direct
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?   547
      payments. Thus, French willingness to exchange a downsizing of CAP
      expenditures against a further reduction of the British rebate might grow.
      And a sensible improvement in the situation regarding national budgets
      might relax constraints on the revenue side of the European budget.
725      Only these combined changes in the policy environment and in member state
      preferences are likely to provide the necessary (albeit not sufficient) conditions
      for closing the huge gap between Lisbon rhetoric and the structure of the
      EU’s budget.

730   Biographical note: Joachim Schild is Professor of Political Science / Compara-
      tive Government at the University of Trier, Germany.

      Address for correspondence: Joachim Schild, University of Trier, FB-III: Pol-
      itical Science, Universitätsring 15, D-54286 Trier, Germany. Tel. þ49 (0) 651
735   201 2123. Fax: þ49 (0) 651 201 3917. email: schild@uni-trier.de

      ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
      I would like to thank Peter Becker and three anonymous referees for their
740
      helpful comments on an earlier draft of this article, Philipp Hessel, Judith
      Gouverneur and Philipp Niemann for their help in collecting and presenting
      the data used, and Joanna Ardizzone for her proof reading.

745
      NOTES
       1 European Union. Financial Report 2004, Luxembourg: Office for Official Publi-
         cations of the European Communities, 2005, pp. 148– 9.
       2 Real past R&D expenditures, commitments for appropriations in the 7th frame-
         work programme for research and technological development running from 2007
750      to 2013, based on the final compromise on the financial perspective from May
         2006.
       3 The figures for the global budget used to calculate this share do not include the
         budget of the European Development Fund.
       4 Cf. Commission of the European Communities: Q&A on Interinstitutional Agree-
         ment on Budgetary Discipline and Sound Financial Management 2007 –2013
755      MEMO/06/204, Brussels, 17 May 2006.
       5 Cf. European Commission. New proposals for growth and jobs under the next
         Financial Framework 2007 – 2013, IP/05/389, Brussels, 6 April 2005.
       6 Sources: European Union. Financial Report 2004, Brussels 2005 for R&D real
         spending up to 2004; figures for 2005 and 2006: European Commission: Q3
         General budget of the European Union for the financial year 2006. The figures,
760      Brussels/Luxembourg, January 2006; figures for 2007 –13: Commission of the
         European Communities: Amended proposal for a decision of the European Parlia-
         ment and the Council concerning the 7th framework programme of the European
         Community for research, technological development and demonstration activities
         (2007 –2013), Brussels, 28 June 2006 (COM(2006) 364final), p. 66.
       7 Interinstitutional Agreement between the European Parliament, the Council and
765      the Commission on budgetary discipline and sound financial management, Official
548     Journal of European Public Policy
           Journal of the European Union, 2006/C 139, 14 June 2006, Annex I (own compu-
           tation).
       8   Brussels European Council, 24 and 25 October 2002, Presidency Conclusions,
           14702/02, POLGEN 67, Brussels, 26 November 2002.
       9   This joint letter is to be found at: www.bmdf.co.uk/blairlettereubudget.pdf
770   10   European Commission, Building our common future, policy challenges and bud-
           getary means of the enlarged union 2007 – 2013, COM (2004) 101 final/2,
           Brussels, 26 February 2004.
      11   Cf. European Parliament: Report on the Interinstitutional Agreement on budgetary
           discipline and sound financial management, Committee on Budgets, Rapporteur:
           Reimer Böge, A6-0150/2006, Brussels, 27 April 2006, p. 37.
775   12   Cf. European Commission: New proposals for growth and jobs under the next
           Financial Framework 2007– 2013, Brussels, 6 April 2005 (IP/05/389).
      13   European Commission, Building our common future, op. cit., p. 16.
      14   I would like to thank an anonymous referee for his helpful comment on this point.
      15   See the progress report of the Irish Presidency: Council of the European Union.
           Report from the Presidency to the European Council, Financial Framework for
780        2007– 2013: Analytical Report, Brussels, 7 June 2004 (CADREFIN 11), pp.
           6– 7; for an overview of the initial positions of the member states in these nego-
           tiations, see Maurer et al. (2004).
      16   UK Presidency of the EU 2005. Speech to the European Parliament, 23 June 2005.
           The speech of Prime Minister Tony Blair is to be found at http://www.fco.gov.uk/
           Files/kfile/UKEUPresidency2005_Sp_PM_EuropeanParliament_230605,0.pdf#
785        search¼per cent22europeanper cent20parliamentper cent20tonyper cent20blairper
           cent20juneper cent2023per cent202005per cent22
      17   Council of the European Union. Note from the Presidency to the European
           Council on the Financial Perspective 2007– 13, 15915/0, CADREFIN 268, B-
           russels, 19 December 2005.
      18   Ibid., p. 5.
790   19   The Commission, following an activity-based budgeting approach, assigned admin-
           istrative costs to policy fields. For the sake of a better comparison, the total amount
           of administrative costs is displayed here (as in the IIA). The administrative expen-
           ditures in the EP’s proposal reflect the activity-based approach of the Commission,
           criticized by Parliament for its lack of transparency.
      20   Cf. European Parliament Resolution on policy challenges and budgetary means of
795        the enlarged Union 2007 –2013, P6_TA(2005)0224, point 49.
      21   European Parliament resolution on the European Council’s position on the Finan-
           cial Perspective and the renewal of the Interinstitutional Agreement 2007 – 2013,
           P6_TA(2006)0010, Brussels, 18 January 2006, point 4.
      22   Cf. note 17.
      23   Cf. Communication from the Commission: Reforming the budget, changing
800        Europe. A public consultation paper in view of the 2008/2009 budget review,
           Brussels, 12 September 2007 SEC(2007) 1188 final.

805
      REFERENCES
      Allen, D. (2005) ‘Cohesion and Structural Funds: competing pressures for reform?’, in
         H. Wallace, W. Wallace and M.A. Pollack (eds), Policy-Making in the European
         Union, 5th edn, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 213– 41.
      Becker, P. (2005) ‘Das Europäische Parlament in den EU-Finanzverhandlungen’, in
         A. Maurer and D. Nickel (eds), Das Europäische Parlament. Supranationalität, Reprä-
810      sentation, Legitimation, Baden-Baden: Nomos, pp. 179– 99.
J. Schild: How to Shift the EU’s Spending Priorities?      549
      Becker, P. (2006) ‘Fortschreibung des Status Quo – Die EU und ihr neuer Finanzrah-
         men Agenda 2007’, Integration 29(2): 106– 21.
      Begg, I. (2005) ‘Funding the European Union. Making sense of the EU budget. What is
         it for? What should it be for?’, The Federal Trust, March 2005.
      Begg, I. and Heinemann, F. (2006) ‘New budget, old dilemmas’, Centre for European
815      Reform, Briefing note, February 2006.
      Enderlein, H., Lindner, J., Calvo-Gonzalez, O. and Ritter, R. (2005) ‘The EU budget.
         How much scope for institutional reform?’, ECB Occasional Paper, No. 27, Frank-
         furt a.M.: European Central Bank.
      European Commission (2002) ‘European Union. Public finance’, Luxembourg: Office
         for Official Publications of the European Communities.
820   Gerbet, P. (1999) La construction de l’Europe, Paris: Imprimerie nationale.
      Hooghe, L. (1996) ‘Building a Europe with the regions: the changing role of the
         European Commission’, in L. Hooghe (ed.), Cohesion Policy and European Inte-
         gration. Building Multi-level Governance, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp.
         89 –126.
      Kingdon, J.W. (1984) Agendas, Alternatives and Public Policies, Boston: Little Brown.
825   Laffan, B. (1997) The Finances of the European Union, London: Macmillan.
      Laffan, B. (2000) ‘The big budgetary bargains: from negotiation to authority’, Journal of
         European Public Policy 7(5), Special Issue: 725 – 43.
      Laffan, B. and Lindner, J. (2005) ‘The budget. Who get’s what, when and how?’, in H.
         Wallace, W. Wallace and M.A. Pollack (eds), Policy-Making in the European Union,
         5th edn, Oxford: Oxford University Press, pp. 191 –212.
830   Lijphart, A. (1999) Patterns of Democracy. Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-
         six Countries, New Haven, CT and London: Yale University Press.
      Lindner, J. (2006) Conflict and Change in EU Budgetary Politics, London and New York:
         Routledge.
      Maurer, A., Schroff, W. and Ehl, M. (2004) Solidarität und Finanzgerechtigkeit in der
         EU-25. Die Positionen europäischer und deutscher Akteure zur Finanziellen Vor-
835      ausschau 2007 –2013, Stiftung Wissenschaft und Politik, Diskussionspapier,
         Berlin,        March      2004,       in:    http://www.swp-berlin.org/common/
         get_document.php?id¼805
      Mayhew, A. (2005) The British Position in the Negotiation of the Financial Framework,
         Working Paper FG1 2005/7, Stiftung Wissenschaft und Politik, Berlin 7.7.2005,
         in: http://www.swp-berlin.org/common/get_document.php?id¼1343.
840   Moravcsik, A. (1998) The Choice for Europe. Social Purpose and State Power from Messina
         to Maastricht, Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press.
      Sapir, A. et al. (2003) An Agenda for a Growing Europe. Making the EU Economic System
         Deliver. Report of an Independent High-level Study Group established on the
         initiative of the President of the European Commission, Brussels.
      Scharpf, F.W. (1988) ‘The joint decision trap. Lessons from German federalism and
845      European integration’, Public Administration 66(3): 239 –78.
      Steenblock, R. and Hartwig, I. (2004) ‘Die Agenda 2007: Solidarität, Nachhaltigkeit
         und Innovation’, Integration 27(1 –2): 85 –94.
      Tsebelis, G. (2002) Veto Players. How Political Institutions Work, Princeton, NJ:
         Princeton University Press.
850
                                                         Final version received 08/01/08

855
You can also read