Reflections on Northern Rock: The Bank Run that Heralded the Global Financial Crisis

Page created by Vanessa Barton
 
CONTINUE READING
Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 23, Number 1—Winter 2009 —Pages 101–119

Reflections on Northern Rock: The
Bank Run that Heralded the Global
Financial Crisis
Hyun Song Shin

I     n September 2007, television viewers and newspaper readers around the
      world saw pictures of what looked like an old-fashioned bank run—that is,
      depositors waiting in line outside the branch offices of a United Kingdom
bank called Northern Rock to withdraw their money. The previous U.K. bank run
before Northern Rock was in 1866 at Overend Gurney, a London bank that
overreached itself in the railway and docks boom of the 1860s. Bank runs were not
uncommon in the United States up through the 1930s, but they have been rare
since the start of deposit insurance backed by the Federal Deposit Insurance
Corporation. In contrast, deposit insurance in the United Kingdom was a partial
affair, funded by the banking industry itself and insuring only a part of the
deposits—at the time of the run, U.K. bank deposits were fully insured only up to
2,000 pounds, and then only 90 percent of the deposits up to an upper limit of
35,000 pounds. When faced with a run, the incentive to withdraw one’s deposits
from a U.K. bank was therefore very strong. For economists, the run on Northern
Rock at first seemed to offer a rare opportunity to study at close quarters all the
elements involved in their theoretical models of bank runs: the futility of public
statements of reassurance, the mutually reinforcing anxiety of depositors, as well as
the power of the media in galvanizing and channeling that anxiety through the
power of television images.
     However, the storyline of the Northern Rock bank run does not fit the
conventional narrative. On September 13, 2007, the BBC’s evening television news
broadcast first broke the news that Northern Rock had sought the Bank of England’s
support. The next morning, the Bank of England announced that it would provide
emergency liquidity support. It was only after that announcement—that is, after the

y Hyun Song Shin is the Hughes-Rogers Professor of Economics, Princeton University,
Princeton, New Jersey. His e-mail address is 具hsshin@princeton.edu典.
102   Journal of Economic Perspectives

central bank had announced its intervention to support the bank—that retail
depositors started queuing outside the branch offices.
      In fact, the financial damage to the bank had been done well before the run
by its retail depositors. Northern Rock was unusual among U.K. mortgage banks in
its heavy reliance on nonretail funding. By summer 2007, only 23 percent of its
liabilities were in the form of retail deposits. The rest of its funding came from a
combination of short-term borrowing in the capital markets and securitized notes
and other longer-term funding sources (as we discuss in more detail below). Of
course, the global credit crisis first erupted in summer 2007; in particular, on
August 9, 2007, the short-term funding market and interbank lending all but froze.
The triggering event on that day was the news that the French bank BNP Paribas
was closing three investment vehicles that invested in U.S. subprime mortgage
assets using short-term borrowed money. But many investment vehicles and finan-
cial institutions that tapped short-term financing had already begun experiencing
difficulties in renewing their short-term borrowing.
      Although Northern Rock had virtually no subprime lending, it was nevertheless
fishing from the same pool of short-term funding. The managers of Northern Rock
informed its regulators at the Financial Services Authority (FSA) as early as August 13,
2007, of Northern Rock’s funding problems. The Bank of England was informed on
August 14. From that time and for a full month until the fateful announcement on
September 14 that triggered the depositor run, the FSA and the Bank of England
sought to resolve the crisis behind the scenes, perhaps by arranging a takeover by
another U.K. bank. However, the unfolding credit crisis as well as the reluctance to
commit public money to facilitate a takeover stifled these efforts. Having failed to find
a buyer for Northern Rock, the public announcement by the Bank of England on
September 14, 2007, was recognition that Northern Rock’s predicament had reached
the point where only central bank support could avoid bank failure.
      The Northern Rock depositor run, although dramatic on television, was an
event in the aftermath of the liquidity crisis at Northern Rock, rather than the event
that triggered its liquidity crisis. In this sense, the Northern Rock episode was not
an old-fashioned bank run of the sort we see in movies like It’s a Wonderful Life or
Mary Poppins. Indeed, the irony of the images of Northern Rock’s retail customers
standing in line to withdraw deposits is that retail deposit funding is perhaps the
most stable form of funding available to a bank. Although retail deposits can be
withdrawn on demand, bankers have been heard to joke that a depositor is more
likely to get divorced than to switch banks.
      Thus, the real question raised by the Northern Rock episode is not so much
why retail depositors are so prone to loss of confidence that lead to bank runs, but
instead why the plentiful short-term funding that Northern Rock enjoyed before
August 2007 suddenly dried up. To turn the question around, the issue is why
sophisticated lenders who operate in the capital markets chose suddenly to deny
lending to a bank that had an apparently solid asset book and virtually no subprime
lending. Northern Rock was in the business of prime mortgage lending to U.K.
households. The asset quality of any mortgage bank is vulnerable to a sharp decline
Hyun Song Shin         103

in house prices and rising unemployment. However, 2007 was the Indian summer
of the housing boom in the U.K., and there were no outward signs of seriously
deteriorating loan quality. Thus, the sudden refusal of lenders to fund Northern
Rock needs an explanation. The answers to the puzzle reveal much about the
nature of banking in the age of securitization and capital markets.1
     In what follows, I will outline the Northern Rock episode, expose the relevant
facts for scrutiny, and explain how the Northern Rock case differs from the
textbook model of bank runs. I will argue that a better perspective on the crisis can
be gained by looking at the pressures on the creditors to Northern Rock. When a
financial crisis strikes, prudent risk management by lenders leads to a generalized
retrenchment as they attempt to meet the crisis by shedding their risky exposures.
Shedding risky exposures means that they lend less. However, from the point of
view of a borrower such as Northern Rock, prudent cutting of exposures by the
creditors is effectively a withdrawal of funding. The Northern Rock case raises a
number of important policy issues, not least how banking regulation should be
formulated in the age of securitization and complex capital markets.

Background

      Northern Rock was a “building society”—that is, a mutually owned savings and
mortgage bank— until its decision to go public and float its shares on the stock
market in 1997. As with other building societies in the United Kingdom, Northern
Rock traced its origin to the so-called cooperative movement of the nineteenth
century. It arose out of the merger of the Northern Counties Permanent Building
Society (established in 1850) and the Rock Building Society (established in 1865).
Even its name, “Northern Rock” conjured associations of dour solidity, which
seemed appropriate for a savings and mortgage bank.
      As with other U.K. building societies, Northern Rock started life as a regionally
based institution, serving its local clientele. Northern Rock was originally based in
the northeast of England, around the city of Newcastle upon Tyne.
      In spite of its modest origins, Northern Rock had larger ambitions. In the nine
years from June 1998 (the first year after demutualization) to June 2007 (on the eve of
its crisis), Northern Rock’s total assets grew from 17.4 billion pounds to 113.5 billion
pounds (approximately $200 billion). This growth in assets corresponds to a constant
equivalent annual rate of 23.2 percent, a very rapid rate of growth. By the eve of its

1
 For a chronology of the early stages of the financial crisis of 2007–2008, the interested reader might
begin with Bank of England (2008), Bank for International Settlements (2008, chap. 6), International
Monetary Fund (2008), Dudley (2007, 2008), Brunnermeier (this issue), and Greenlaw, Hatzius,
Kashyap, and Shin (2008). For an account of Northern Rock and the U.K. institutional background,
useful starting points are Dimsdale (2008), Mayes and Wood (2008), and Milne and Wood (2008). See
Yorulmazer (2008) for an empirical analysis of U.K. banks during the run on Northern Rock. For an
accessible and on-point journalistic discussion, see also “Northern Rock: Lessons of the Fall,” Economist,
October 18, 2007, at 具http://www.economist.com/displaystory.cfm?story_id⫽9988865典.
104    Journal of Economic Perspectives

crisis, Northern Rock was the fifth-largest bank in the United Kingdom by mortgage
assets. Northern Rock’s successes as a bank made it emblematic of the revitalization of
the northeast region following the decline of traditional industries, such as coal mining
and shipbuilding. Northern Rock funded a highly visible charitable trust and become
the main sponsor to the local football (soccer) team, Newcastle United. For all these
reasons, Northern Rock commanded fierce loyalty in its regional base.
      However, as Northern Rock expanded its mortgage assets, the size of its balance
sheet far outstripped its traditional funding base of branch-based retail deposits. Even
as total assets grew by a factor of 6.5 in this period, retail deposits only grew from 10.4
billion pounds to 24 billion pounds. Figure 1 charts the composition of Northern
Rock’s liabilities from June 1998 to June 2007. Retail funding had been 60 percent of
the bank’s liabilities in 1998, but had fallen to 23 percent of total liabilities on the eve
of the crisis in June 2007 (and would fall much farther after the run). Even in the case
of retail deposits, only a small proportion consisted of the traditional branch-based
deposits. The bulk of the retail deposits at the time of its run were non-branch-based
deposits such as postal and telephone accounts. Postal accounts require customers to
send in their withdrawal or deposit requests by post (by mail), and customers are
rewarded for their inconvenience with a slightly higher deposit interest rate. Tele-
phone accounts work in a similar way, but via telephone. These nonbranch retail
deposits enabled Northern Rock to expand their retail deposits beyond their narrow
regional base, but these deposits proved most vulnerable to withdrawal in the aftermath
of the run on Northern Rock.
      The gap in funding between the amount lent out and the amount depositors
put in was made up by securitized notes and other forms of nonretail funding, such
as interbank deposits and “covered bonds.” Given the importance of securitized
notes for the Northern Rock story, we postpone a discussion of securitized notes
until later. Covered bonds are long-term liabilities written against segregated
mortgage assets. As such, they are illiquid and long-term in nature, and so were not
directly implicated in the run. However, other short-run wholesale funding was
more closely implicated in the run on Northern Rock.
      Before examining the components of Northern Rock’s liabilities more closely,
it is worthy of note that Northern Rock was not unique among U.K. banks in its
growing use of nonretail funding. The Bank of England’s Financial Stability Report
(2008, figure 4) charts the trend in the use of nonretail funding among large U.K.
banks since 2000. The median U.K. bank’s nonretail funding started at 27.8 percent
in December 2000 but had almost doubled to 47.8 percent by December 2007.
Thus, what set Northern Rock apart from other U.K. banks was not that it used
nonretail funding, but the extent to which it relied on such funding.

The Securitization Process

    In many discussions of the Northern Rock episode, it has become the received
wisdom that the heavy use of securitized notes made Northern Rock’s business
Reflections on Northern Rock     105

Figure 1
Composition of Northern Rock’s Liabilities, June 1998 –June 2007

                 120
                                                                                Equity

                 100

                                                                                Other liabilities
                 80
Billion pounds

                 60
                                                                                Securitized notes
                 40

                 20
                                                                                Retail deposits
                  0
                   Ju

                       Ju 98

                       Ju 99

                       Ju 00

                       Ju 01

                       Ju 02

                       Ju 03

                       Ju 04

                       Ju 05

                       Ju 06
                       D 98

                       D 99

                       D 00

                       D 01

                       D 02

                       D 03

                       D 04

                       D 05

                       D 06
                         ec

                         ec

                         ec

                         ec

                         ec

                         ec

                         ec

                         ec

                         ec
                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-

                         n-
                           -

                           -

                           -

                           -

                           -

                           -

                           -

                           -

                           -
                            07
Source: Northern Rock, annual and interim reports, 1998 –2007.

model unusual, its balance sheet less traditional, and that securitization was some-
how responsible in Northern Rock’s downfall (for example, see Mayes and Wood,
2008; Milne and Wood, 2008; and others). However, I will argue that the role of
securitization is more subtle than this argument suggests.
     Northern Rock’s securitized notes were of medium to long-term maturity, with
average maturity of over one year. The bank assigned portions of its mortgage assets
to a trust—Granite Finance Trustees, which then entered into an agreement with
special purpose entities called “Funding” and “Funding 2.” In turn, these special
purpose entities entered into loan agreements with a separate note-issuing com-
pany, which issued the notes itself. Figure 2 is drawn from the offer documentation
for a particular bond offering—the Granite Master Issuer series 2005-2.
     The notes issued by Granite were floating rate “controlled amortization notes”
that paid out according to set redemption dates spread over several years. The
notes were ranked according to seniority, with Class A notes being more senior
(paying 4 basis points above LIBOR, the benchmark London Interbank Offered
Rate) and Class D notes being the most junior (paying 50 basis points above
LIBOR).
     Unlike the U.S. securitization process where the special purpose entities are
considered separate from the bank that makes the loans (that is, as off-balance-
sheet vehicles), the accounting rules that Northern Rock operated under meant
that the special purpose entities were consolidated on Northern Rock’s main
balance sheet. In this respect, the rapid growth of Northern Rock’s balance sheet
reflects the accounting regime, along with the flow of new loans originated.
106    Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 2
Structural Diagram of the Securitization Transaction for Northern Rock’s Granite
Master Issuer Series 2005-2

                                           Assignment
                                           of mortgage
                                             portfolio
               Northern Rock PLC                             Granite Finance Trustees Ltd
                   (Originator)                                   (Mortgage Trustee)
                                              Proceeds

                                                                    Funding 2 Ltd
              Class A Notes                                     (Special Purpose Entity)

              Class B Notes
                                          Note proceeds

              Class M Notes                                     Granite Master Issuer PLC
                                                                      (Note Issuer)
                                            Principal
              Class C Notes                and interest

              Class D Notes

Source: Supplement to Prospectus, May 23, 2005. At 具http://companyinfo.northernrock.co.uk/downloads/
securitisation/prospectus%20&%20us%20supplement%2005-2.pdf典.

    There is another contrast between Northern Rock and the U.S. and European
banks caught up in the subprime crisis. The latter banks sponsored off-balance-
sheet entities (such as “conduits” and “structured investment vehicles”) that held
subprime mortgage assets funded with very short-term liabilities such as asset-
backed commercial paper, which were at the heart of the subprime crisis. These
short-term liabilities needed to be rolled over several times each year, which made
banks highly vulnerable if credit markets became unwilling to fund new issues. In
contrast, the notes issued by Granite had relatively longer maturities.2 For example,
Northern Rock had 31.1 billion pounds of securitized notes outstanding at the end
of 2005. The total redemptions during 2006 of these notes were 7.12 billion
pounds. So, only a small fraction (23 percent) were redeemed over the course of

2
  A full list of all of Northern Rock’s securitization vehicles and amounts outstanding can be compiled
from annual reports, which are available at 具http://companyinfo.northernrock.co.uk/investorRelations/
corporateReports.asp典.
Hyun Song Shin        107

the following year. Such a repayment pattern is in sharp contrast to banks or
investment vehicles that relied on very short-term funding and therefore needed to
roll over their liabilities several times during the year.
     For this reason, the securitized notes issued by Northern Rock do not appear
culpable for the run—at least not in a direct way. The Northern Rock case was
therefore different from the outwardly similar downfalls for off-balance-sheet vehi-
cles sponsored by other European banks such as BNP Paribas (mentioned earlier)
or IKB, the German bank that suffered a liquidity crisis in August 2007, which were
rooted in a need to roll over short-term securities. We return to this issue later in
the paper.3

The Run on Northern Rock

      A snapshot of the run on Northern Rock can be seen by comparing the
composition of its liabilities before the run and after the run. The comparison is
given in Figure 3, taken from the 2007 annual report of Northern Rock. The
left-hand bar is the snapshot of the main components of Northern Rock’s liabilities
as of the end of June 2007— before the run—while the right-hand bar is the
snapshot at the end of the year, after its run and after the liquidity support from the
Bank of England.
      The most glaring difference is the liability to the Bank of England after its
liquidity support to Northern Rock, which stood at 28.5 billion pounds at the
end of 2007. Covered bonds (which, remember, are illiquid long-term liabilities
written against segregated mortgage assets) actually increased from 8.1 billion
pounds in June 2007 to 8.9 billion in December 2007. Securitized notes fall only
slightly from 45.7 billion to 43 billion pounds, which is consistent with the
earlier theme that these notes played relatively little direct role in the Northern
Rock run.
      The largest falls are in the categories of retail deposits and for “wholesale
liabilities.” “Wholesale funding”—nonretail funding that does not fall under either
covered bonds or securitized notes— declines from 26.7 billion pounds in June to
11.5 billion pounds in December 2007. Although a detailed breakdown of the
wholesale funding is not disclosed in the annual reports, they do contain some
clues on the maturity and sourcing of this category of funding.
      For example, the 2006 Northern Rock annual report (p. 41) states that
wholesale funding consists of a “balanced mixture of short and medium term

3
  In one instance, securitization did play a role in Northern Rock’s downfall. This has to do with the
Granite Master Issue 07-3. The notes were due to be issued in September 2007, but the crisis intervened
before the notes could be sold. None of the notes were placed with investors, and the whole issue of
notes—around 5 billion pounds face value—were taken back onto Northern Rock’s balance sheet (as
discussed in the Northern Rock 2007 annual report, p. 31). In this instance, the problem was that the
planned sale of notes did not proceed, depriving Northern Rock of cash, rather than a problem with the
rolling over of existing liabilities.
108    Journal of Economic Perspectives

Figure 3
Composition of Northern Rock’s Liabilities Before and After the Run
(millions of pounds)

               26,710
                                                 28,473

                                                             Loan from Bank of England
               24,350                            11,472
                                                             Wholesale
                                                 10,469      Retail
               8,105                             8,938       Covered bonds
                                                             Securitized notes

               45,698                            43,070

             June 2007                          Dec 2007
Source: Northern Rock annual report for 2007.

funding with increasing diversification of our global investor.” Medium-term fund-
ing refers to term funding of six months or longer, while short-term funding has a
maturity less than six months. The 2006 annual report (p. 41) is worth quoting
verbatim for an insight into the nature of this short-term funding:

   During the year, we raised £3.2 billion medium term wholesale funds from a
   variety of globally spread sources, with specific emphasis on the US, Europe,
   Asia and Australia. This included two transactions sold to domestic US inves-
   tors totalling US$3.5 billion. In January 2007, we raised a further US$2.0
   billion under our US MTN [medium term notes] programme. Key develop-
   ments during 2006 included the establishment of an Australian debt pro-
   gramme, raising A$1.2 billion from our inaugural issue. This transaction was
   the largest debut deal in that market for a single A rated financial institution
   targeted at both domestic Australian investors and the Far East.

      In this way, Northern Rock’s short-term wholesale funding shared many sim-
ilarities with the short-term funding raised by off-balance-sheet vehicles such as the
“conduits” and “structured investment vehicles” used by many other banks and
aimed at institutional investors. This type of funding was more short-term—less
than one year, frequently much shorter—and thus more vulnerable to the liquidity
crisis that hit the capital markets in August 2007. Indeed, the 2007 annual report
(p. 31) states that, although Northern Rock managed to raise a net 2.5 billion
pounds of wholesale funding in the first half of the year, the second half saw
Reflections on Northern Rock         109

Figure 4
Composition of Retail Deposits of Northern Rock Before and After Run
(million pounds)

               10,201

               4,105

                                                  4,351
               2,752                                                Postal accounts
                                                  1,371             Offshore and other accounts
                                                  1,712             Internet and telephone accounts
               5,573
                                                                    Branch accounts
                                                  3,035

             Dec 2006                            Dec 2007
Source: Northern Rock, annual report for 2007.

“substantial outflows of wholesale funds, as maturing loans and deposits were not
renewed. This resulted in a full year net outflow of £11.7 billion.” Thus, the key to
the initial “run” on Northern Rock was the nonrenewal of Northern Rock’s short-
and medium-term paper. This was the run that led to the demise of Northern
Rock—a run that happened out of sight of the television cameras.
     Northern Rock also shows that retail deposits are not all created equal. Figure
4 charts the change in the composition of retail deposits of Northern Rock from
December 2006 to December 2007. The total falls substantially, as one would
expect in the aftermath of a depositor run, with total retail funding falling from
24.4 billion to 10.5 billion.4 However, the conventional branch-based customer
deposits saw the smallest falls, falling from 5.6 billion to 3 billion pounds. In
contrast, postal account deposits, offshore deposits and telephone and Internet
deposits saw much more substantial falls. Although these retail deposits did run
once the troubles at Northern Rock were publicized, the evidence suggests that the
nonstandard retail deposits are the first to flee in a deposit run. Thus, the media
coverage of the Northern Rock bank run, showing images of depositors queuing at
the branch offices, was ironic. The branch deposits were actually the most stable of

4
  These numbers come from the main text of the Northern Rock annual report for 2007. Figure 4 of this
paper also comes from that report. Within the annual report, there is a small discrepency between the
22.4 billion total given in the text and that implied by the figure.
110    Journal of Economic Perspectives

all deposits, and branch deposits were far more stable than the wholesale funding
raised in the capital markets from sophisticated financial institutions.

Reassessing the Run on Northern Rock

     The Northern Rock bank run does not easily fit into the standard ways that
economists think about bank runs. One difference is that the classic models of bank
runs describe a pattern of coordination failure. For example, in Bryant (1980) and
Diamond and Dybvig (1983), an individual depositor runs for fear that others will run,
leaving no assets in place for those who do not run. However, in the first wave of the
credit crunch that came in August 2007, the withdrawal of credit hit the whole market,
not simply a subset of the institutions. If there was a run driven by a coordination
failure, then it was a run from all the institutions that relied on short-term funding of this
type. In this view, even though the global credit crunch had a disproportionate effect
on Northern Rock, it was not aimed at Northern Rock in particular.
     Another difference is that, in the coordination failure model of bank runs, the
creditors are individual consumers who rationally choose whether to run or not
based on their beliefs of what other depositors do. But the Northern Rock bank run
was not enacted by individuals, but rather by sophisticated institutional investors.
These investors often face constraints on their risk-taking either from risk manage-
ment rules they follow for internal business reasons, or from regulatory rules. When
measured risks are low, risk constraints on capital do not bind, and such investors
will be willing to lend. However, when a crisis strikes, risk constraints bind and
lenders cut back their exposures in response. But whatever the reason for the
prudent cutting of exposures by the creditors to Northern Rock, their actions will
look like a “run” from the point of view of Northern Rock itself. In this sense, the
run on Northern Rock may be better seen as the tightening of constraints on the
creditors of Northern Rock rather than as a coordination failure among them.
     Of course, we should not draw too hard and fast a distinction between the
coordination view of bank runs and the “leverage constraints” view of bank runs.
Coordination (or lack thereof) will clearly exacerbate the severity of any run when
a bank has many creditors. The point is rather that the run on Northern Rock
needs to appeal to more than just coordination failure. In practice, this means that
an explanation of the run on Northern Rock should make reference to marketwide
factors and not only to the characteristics of Northern Rock and its creditors viewed
in isolation. This is one more instance of the general maxim that in a modern
market-based financial system, banking and capital market conditions should not
be viewed in isolation.

Fluctuations in Leverage of the Financial System
     Every textbook teaches that a traditional bank holds short-term liabilities, in
the form of deposits, and uses them to finance longer-term, less-liquid assets, such
as loans. However, it is less often recognized that the financial system as a whole works
Hyun Song Shin     111

in the same way, holding a mixture of long-term, illiquid assets financed by
short-term liabilities. When a firm borrows money, it can buy more assets using this
borrowed money together with its initial capital—its equity. The leverage of the
firm is defined as a ratio of the total assets of the firm to its equity. Even for
nonfinancial firms, their leverage is influenced by marketwide asset market condi-
tions, as shown by Shleifer and Vishny (1992).
     However, for leveraged financial firms (who borrow in order to lend) market
conditions are pivotal in determining their leverage. Since equity is the buffer that
protects creditors against loss, the degree of debt that a financial firm can take on
depends on how volatile the asset values are. When financial conditions are benign
and measured risks are low, creditors are willing to lend more per each dollar of
equity held by the bank—that is, the creditors are willing to countenance higher
leverage. However, when measured risks rise and financial market conditions turn
hostile, then there is a sharp pullback in leverage, as creditors demand a higher
equity cushion to shield them from losses.
     In this way, fluctuations in the leverage of financial institutions keep step with
fluctuations in measured risks and overall market conditions. A sharp increase in
measured risks leads to a sharp pullback in leverage, which will create tensions
somewhere in the system. Even if some institutions can adjust down their balance
sheets flexibly in response to this scenario by reducing assets and paying down debt,
there will be some pinch points in the system that will be exposed by the de-
leveraging. Arguably, this is what happened to Northern Rock.
     While there is no agreed summary statistic on the extent of leverage in an
economy or how leverage fluctuates, plenty of evidence suggests that such fluctu-
ations are substantial. In a market-based financial system where credit is securitized
and traded in financial markets, one gauge of overall leverage and funding condi-
tions more generally is to look at the implicit maximum leverage possible in
collateralized borrowing transactions such as repurchase agreements— known as
“repos.”
     In a repurchase agreement, the borrower sells a security today for a price below
the current market price on the understanding that it will buy back the security in
the future at a pre-agreed price. The difference between the current market price
of the security and the price at which it is sold is called the “haircut” in the repo.
The “haircut” fluctuates with funding conditions in the market, and these fluctu-
ations largely determine the leverage of a financial institution. The reason is that
the haircut determines the maximum permissible leverage achieved by the bor-
rower. For example, if the haircut is 2 percent, the borrower can borrow $98 for
every $100 worth of securities. Imagine that the borrower uses leverage to the
maximum extent possible: that is, the borrower pledges the $98 of securities for an
amount equal to that amount, less 2 percent; and then pledges the additional funds
raised as security for an additional round of loans, and so on. Since short-term
profit is magnified by leverage, it is reasonable to assume that the borrower
leverages up close to the maximum. The arithmetic of the borrowing multiplier is
that if the haircut is 2 percent, then the maximum permissible leverage—ratio of
112        Journal of Economic Perspectives

Table 1
Haircuts for Repos during March 2008

Security                                                  Typical haircuts            March 2008 haircuts

Treasuries                                                    ⬍ 0.5%                      0.25% ⬃ 3%
Corporate bonds                                                5%                             10%
AAA asset-backed securities                                    3%                             15%
AAA residential mortgage-backed securities                     2%                             20%
AAA jumbo prime mortgages                                      5%                             30%

Source: Bloomberg.
Note: In a repurchase agreement, the borrower sells a security today for a price below the current market
price on the understanding that it will buy back the security in the future at a pre-agreed price. The
difference between the current market price of the security and the price at which it is sold is called the
“haircut” in the repo.

assets to equity—is 50 (the reciprocal of the haircut ratio). In other words, to hold
$100 worth of securities, the borrower must come up with $2 of equity.
      Suppose that a borrower leverages up to the maximum permitted level and has
a highly leveraged balance sheet with a leverage of 50. If at this time a shock to the
financial system raises the market haircut to 4 percent, then the permitted leverage
halves to 25, from 50. In fact, times of financial stress are associated with sharply
higher haircuts. Table 1 show the haircuts that were being applied during the peak
of the market disruptions in March 2008 compared to the haircuts prevailing
during normal times. For instance, a borrower holding AAA-rated residential
mortgage-backed securities would have seen a ten-fold increase in haircuts, mean-
ing that its leverage must fall from 50 to just 5.
      Clearly, an increase in haircuts entails very substantial reductions in leverage,
which creates hard choices. Imagine a borrower who sees the extent of its possible
leverage fall by half. Either the borrower must raise new equity, so that its equity
doubles from its previous level, or the borrower must sell half its assets, or some
combination of both. Either raising new equity or cutting assets will entail painful
adjustments. Raising new equity is notoriously difficult in distressed market condi-
tions— but selling assets in a depressed market is not much better. For financial
institutions that have assets which are very short-term and liquid—such as short-
term collateralized lending—a common approach to this situation is to make the
necessary adjustment by reducing lending (which in effect is reducing assets) and
by repaying debt.
      Of course, Northern Rock was a mortgage bank, not a securities firm that uses
repo financing as its main borrowing method. However, the discussion of repos and
how the haircuts fluctuate in response to market conditions can explain why
leverage and credit conditions fluctuate substantially for the economy as a whole;
the discussion now turns to why those factors had a particularly large effect on
Northern Rock.
Reflections on Northern Rock       113

Figure 5
Northern Rock’s Leverage, June 1998 –December 2007

                 90
                                                                      Leverage on common equity
                 80

                 70
                                                                      Leverage on shareholder equity
Leverage ratio

                 60

                 50

                 40                                                   Leverage on total equity

                 30

                 20

                 10
                  Ju

                  J u -98

                  J u -99

                  Ju -00

                  Ju -01

                  J u -02

                  Ju -03

                  Ju -04

                  J u -0 5

                  Ju -06
                  D -98

                  D -99

                  D -00

                  D -01

                  D -02

                  D -03

                  D -04

                  D -05

                  D -06

                  D -07
                     ec

                     ec

                     ec

                     ec

                     ec
                     ec

                     ec

                     ec

                     ec

                     ec
                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n

                     n
                        -0
                           7
Source: Northern Rock, annual and interim reports, 1998 –2007.
Note: The leverage ratio is the ratio of total assets to equity.

Vulnerability and Leverage at Northern Rock
      Northern Rock was a very highly leveraged institution, which tended to make
it especially vulnerable to a reduction in overall funding conditions for the financial
system as a whole. To appreciate this point, it is important to draw some important
distinctions regarding how leverage might be measured in practice. As stated
already, leverage is defined in principle as the ratio of total assets to equity. But
much turns on choosing the correct notion of equity.
      Figure 5 plots the leverage of Northern Rock from June 1998 to December
2007, using three different measures of equity. Common equity is the purest form
of equity—it is the stake held by the owners of the bank with voting power and
hence who control the bank. “Shareholder equity” is defined as common equity
plus preferred shares. Preferred shares do not have voting power but are senior to
shares of the common equity holders in case the bank is liquidated, and they are
paid a fixed dividend payment in perpetuity. In effect, preferred shares are like a
perpetual bond. Finally, “total equity” is shareholder equity plus subordinated debt,
a class of debt that is senior to the common and preferred equity, but which is
junior to other types of debt taken on by the bank, including deposits.
      In the early years of Northern Rock’s operation as a public limited company,
no distinction existed between total equity, shareholder equity, and common
equity. All equity was just common equity. However, beginning in 2005, the total
equity series included for the first time 736.5 million pounds worth of subordinated
debt as well as 299.3 million pounds worth of reserve notes (Northern Rock 2005
annual report, p. 51). Both of these items had been issued earlier (in 2001), but
they were included in the equity series in the annual report for the first time in
114   Journal of Economic Perspectives

2005. Treating these subordinated debt items as “equity” explains why the bottom
line in the figure shows a drop in leverage in June 2005. However, when the
subordinated debt items are excluded and equity is construed just as shareholder
equity, Northern Rock’s leverage continued to increase in 2005. In 2006, Northern
Rock issued 396.4 million pounds worth of “preference shares,” which it counted as
shareholder equity (Northern Rock 2006 annual report, p. 59). This issuance of
new preference shares accounts for the jump down in the leverage series with
respect to shareholder equity in June 2006.
     Subordinated debt can serve the useful purpose of being a buffer against loss
for depositors and the senior creditors. For this reason, under the Basel interna-
tional guidelines for bank regulation, subordinated debt is viewed as being part of
bank capital (as “tier 2” capital). Preference shares can also act as a buffer against
loss for depositors.
     However, in the context of repo haircuts and how the overall leverage of the
financial system is determined, a key idea is that the borrower should have a
sufficient ownership stake in the assets that it controls so that the lender can be
assured that the borrower does not engage in moral hazard or otherwise endanger
the lender’s stake in the assets. The key is that the haircut is the equity stake held
by the controlling party. Control is key, and only common equity can grant control.
In Adrian and Shin (2008a), my coauthor and I provide a formal discussion of
fluctuating leverage from this perspective.
     In contrast, both subordinated debt and preferred shares are debt-like claims
on the bank that do not grant control. The reason why the conventional regulatory
rules treat these claims as being bank capital is that both are junior to deposits.
Since the philosophy behind the Basel rules is that banks should hold buffers to
protect depositors, even such debt-like claims are treated as “capital.”
     However, when calculating the degree of leverage permitted by market con-
ditions, the correct analogy is to think of the counterpart to the haircut in a repo
contract. Equity (that is, capital) should be viewed as the stake held by the party that
has control of the bank’s operation. In other words, for the purpose of calculating
the market-permitted leverage, it is common equity that counts.
     When leverage is interpreted strictly as the ratio of total assets to common
equity, then Northern Rock’s leverage continued to climb throughout its history as
a public company, rising from 22.8 in June 1998, just after its floatation, to 58.2 in
June 2007, on the eve of its liquidity crisis. This level of leverage is very high, even
by the standards of the U.S. investment banks at this time (around 25 to 30). Of
course, Northern Rock’s leverage jumped even higher in December 2007 after its
run, following the depletion of its common equity from losses suffered in the
second half of 2007. Its leverage on common equity at the end of 2007 was 86.3.
     When a bank is so highly leveraged, even a small increase in the implicit
haircut on its borrowing will entail a withdrawal of funding from that bank. Thus,
although most of the discussion above has focused on the constraints facing the
leveraged creditors to Northern Rock, many of the points will apply also to
nonleveraged creditors to Northern Rock—such as money market mutual funds, or
Hyun Song Shin         115

insurance companies. In a contracting problem with moral hazard, the minimum
incentive-compatible stake in the assets that the borrower must hold will fluctuate
widely as the underlying risk in the portfolio shifts (Adrian and Shin, 2008a).
      When a borrower is as highly leveraged as Northern Rock, small fluctuations in
its implied haircut can cause large shifts in available funding. In other words, if
Northern Rock could borrow with a haircut of 2 percent, but then found itself
needing to borrow at much higher haircut, the required reduction in leverage for
Northern Rock would have been extreme. From the standpoint of Northern Rock,
this reduction in the leverage permitted by the market manifested itself when many
outside creditors declined to roll over existing short-term loans. In this sense, the
“run” on Northern Rock was just a matter of when the next pullback in funding
conditions would arrive. When the tide eventually turned, institutions with extreme
leverage and balance sheet mismatches were left on the beach. Northern Rock was
not the only one to find itself beached, but it lacked the liquidity support of a larger
sponsor—apart from the Bank of England.
      In effect, Northern Rock was faced with a giant margin call, where lenders
demanded higher haircuts. The usual way to meet a margin call is to sell some assets
to raise the cash. But the assets of Northern Rock were illiquid long-term mort-
gages, so that it could not meet those margin calls. The inability to meet this margin
call led to Northern Rock’s demise.5

Economic Role of Short-Term Debt

     The Northern Rock episode offers an opportunity to revisit some of the
economic principles behind the use of short-term debt to finance long-term
assets—which is of course essentially the classic model of how banks work. When
the financial system as a whole finances long-term, illiquid assets by short-term
liabilities, not every institution can be perfectly hedged in terms of its maturity
profile. Northern Rock could be seen as such a “pinch point” in the financial
system, where tensions would finally be manifested.
     There are well-known arguments for the desirability of short-term debt in
disciplining managers. For example, Calomiris and Kahn (1991) argue that de-
mand deposits for banking arose naturally as way for the bank’s owners and
managers to commit not to engage in actions that dissipate the value of the assets,
under pain of triggering a depositor run. Diamond and Rajan (2001) have devel-
oped this argument further, and have argued that the coordination problem
inherent in a depositor run serves as a collective commitment device on the part of
the depositors not to renegotiate in the face of opportunistic actions by the

5
  The possibility of distress and the key role played by leverage was discussed by Shleifer and Vishny
(1997) and was taken up by Gromb and Vayanos (2002). Brunnermeier and Pedersen (forthcoming)
have coined the term “margin spiral” to describe the increase in margin calls that amplifies distress in
financial markets.
116   Journal of Economic Perspectives

managers. When the bank has the right quantity of deposits outstanding, any
attempt by the banker to extort a rent from depositors will be met by a run, which
drives the banker’s rents to zero. Foreseeing this, the banker will not attempt to
extort rents. In a world of certainty, the bank maximizes the amount of credit it can
offer by financing with a rigid and fragile all-deposit capital structure.
      However, according to Calomiris and Kahn (1991) and Diamond and Rajan
(2001), the relationship between the bank and the depositors reflects only the
financial conditions of the bank itself. When the relationship between the bank and
its depositors is viewed in isolation from the rest of the financial system, short-term
debt has desirable incentive effects, and the fragility of the balance sheet has an
economic rationale. However, one lesson from Northern Rock (subsequently to be
repeated in the demise of Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers) is that sometimes
creditors are subject to external constraints, and may have to take actions that are
the consequence of factors outside the immediate principal–agent relationship
with the bank.
      Take the following example (explored in Morris and Shin, 2008). Bank 1 has
borrowed from Bank 2. Bank 2 has other assets (that is, loans it has made to other
parties), as well as its loans to Bank 1. Suppose that Bank 2 suffers credit losses on
these other loans, but that the creditworthiness of Bank 1 remains unchanged. The
loss suffered by Bank 2 depletes its equity capital. In the face of such a shock, a
prudent course of action by Bank 2 is to reduce its overall exposure, so that its asset
book is trimmed to a size that can be carried comfortably with the smaller equity
capital.
      From the point of view of Bank 2, the imperative is to reduce its overall
lending, including its lending to Bank 1. By reducing its lending, Bank 2 achieves
its micro-prudential objective of reducing its risk exposure. However, from Bank 1’s
perspective, the reduction of lending by Bank 2 is a withdrawal of funding. If
financial markets are deep and liquid, Bank 1 will find alternative sources of
funding at roughly the same price—after all, nothing in Bank 1’s risk characteristics
has changed, so it should be able to borrow just as easily as it did before. But now
imagine a situation where a combination of events arises: i) the reduction in Bank
2’s lending is severe; ii) overall credit markets have seized up in such a way that no
one has access to funding, including Bank 1; and iii) Bank 1’s assets are so illiquid
that they can only be sold at fire-sale prices. Under these circumstances, the
prudent shedding of exposures from the point of view of Bank 2 will feel like a run
from the point of view of Bank 1. Arguably, this type of run is one element of what
happened to Northern Rock.
      When evaluated from a system perspective, a maturity mismatch of short-term
liabilities and long-term assets on the balance sheet of a financial institution is
double-edged: From the point of view of incentive effects, a fragile balance sheet is
desirable. However, spillover effects from outside the principal–agent relationship
of banks and their depositors can generate countervailing inefficiencies. The
demise of Northern Rock provides a lesson in the possible downside costs of
maturity mismatch.
Reflections on Northern Rock   117

Implications for Financial Regulation

     Traditionally, capital requirements have been the cornerstone of the regula-
tion of banks. The rationale for capital requirements lies in maintaining the
solvency of the regulated institution. By ensuring solvency, the interests of credi-
tors— especially retail depositors— can be protected. Large-scale creditors who
have the ability to monitor a bank can protect their interests through the enforce-
ment of covenants and other checks on the actions of the bank’s managers.
However, in the case of a traditional deposit-funded bank, the creditors are the
small retail depositors, who face a coordination problem in achieving the moni-
toring and other checks that large creditors are able to put in place. The purpose
of bank regulation has been seen as the protection of the interests of these
small-scale depositors by putting into place through regulation those restrictions on
the manager’s actions that would arise in relationships between a debtor and an
active creditor who can take actions to safeguard his or her interests.
     This traditional rationale for capital regulation leads naturally to the conclu-
sion that the key determinant of the size of the regulatory capital buffer should be
the riskiness of the bank’s assets. The Basel Committee on Banking Supervision
brings together representatives of financial supervisors from 10 member countries
to discuss best practices with regard to banking supervision. Although its recom-
mendations have no legal force, they do carry considerable weight with banking
authorities around the world. The original Basel capital accord of 1988 introduced
coarse “risk buckets” into which assets could be classified. The more recent “Basel
II rules,” which were implemented in most Basel Committee member countries in
2007 (with the United States following in 2008), have taken the idea much further
by refining the gradations of the riskiness of the assets and thus fine-tuning the
capital requirements to the risks of the assets held by the bank. However, the fall of
Northern Rock was only a foretaste of the ensuing turmoil in the global financial
system. The global financial crisis of 2007– 08 poses a challenge to the traditional
view of bank regulation. Northern Rock was only the first to fail among many other
financial institutions that relied on access to a continuous stream of short-term
liquidity to roll over expiring short-term debts. When that short-term liquidity did
not materialize, it felt like a run from the point of view of these institutions. Bear
Stearns and Lehman Brothers were two more high-profile failures of this type.
     Two specific categories of policy proposals, which my coauthor and I discuss in
further detail in Morris and Shin (2008), deserve closer attention. First, regulators
might consider some type of liquidity regulation. The rationale is that a bank can
survive a run if 1) it has sufficient liquid assets and cash or 2) it has sufficiently
stable (that is, illiquid) liabilities such as long-term debt. This kind of a liquidity
requirement may not be too onerous if the requirement is adhered to widely in the
financial system. The idea is that when liquidity buffers are distributed throughout
the financial system, the set of multiple buffers will act to reduce spillover—just as
the absence of liquidity buffers has tended to amplify shocks that reverberate inside
the system.
118   Journal of Economic Perspectives

      The second category of proposals would impose some limit on the raw leverage
ratio, rather than risk-weighted assets. The argument for a raw leverage constraint
is that it can act as a constraint “on the way up,” when banks are increasing their
leverage on the back of permissive funding conditions. By preventing the build-up
of leverage during good times, the leverage constraint dampens the effects of
contracting leverage in bad times. The leverage constraint works both at the level
of the debtor as well as that of the creditor. For example, in the earlier example of
Bank 1 and Bank 2, from the point of view of Bank 1 (the debtor), a leverage
constraint will prevent Bank 1 from building up excessive leverage, thereby making
Bank 1 less susceptible to a cut-off of future short-term loans. From the point of
view of Bank 2 (the creditor), the leverage constraint binds on the way up such that
there is slack in the balance sheet capacity of Bank 2 when the tide eventually turns,
so lending from Bank 2 to Bank 1 will suffer a smaller shock. Thus, for both lender
and borrower, the leverage constraint binds during boom times so that the imper-
ative to reduce leverage is less strong in the bust. Indeed, the bust may be averted
altogether, as the initial boom is dampened. The most commonly encountered
criticism against a raw leverage constraint is that it does not take the riskiness of the
assets into account. However, a leverage constraint is not intended to replace
Basel-style capital requirements, but rather to supplement them, on the grounds
that a leverage constraint has desirable properties that cannot be replicated by
risk-based capital ratios alone.
      Both liquidity regulation and leverage caps have much in common with several
recent proposals for the reform of financial regulation—as in Kashyap, Rajan, and
Stein (2008)—that emphasize de facto cyclical variations in required capital, or
insurance that would be taken out by banks. These complementary approaches
address the general shortage of capital during a downturn as well as fluctuations in
funding conditions and the possibility of sudden runs on the financial system.
      The Northern Rock episode raises profound questions for economists and
policymakers. Only a few years ago, Northern Rock was seeing a rapid growth of its
assets, on the back of benign credit conditions, that had propelled it to being
perhaps the most innovative and celebrated bank in the United Kingdom. How-
ever, the high implied leverage that Northern Rock had built up during the boom
times was vulnerable to a reversal when the tide turned. Bank regulators should be
mulling the potential role of liquidity requirements and leverage ratios as supple-
ments for the conventional capital-based banking requirements. Economists should
further deepen their understanding of the potential benefits and costs of financial
intermediation that uses short-term liabilities to finance long-term assets.
Hyun Song Shin          119

References

   Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin. 2008a.              The Economist. 2007. “Northern Rock: Lessons
“Financial Intermediary Leverage and Value at           of the Fall.” October 18. http://www.economist.
Risk.” Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff           com/displaystory.cfm?story_id⫽9988865.
Report No. 338. Available at SSRN: http://                 Greenlaw, David, Jan Hatzius, Anil K.
papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_               Kashyap, and Hyun Song Shin. 2008. “Leveraged
id⫽1189342.                                             Losses: Lessons from the Mortgage Market Melt-
   Adrian, Tobias, and Hyun Song Shin. 2008b.           down.” U.S. Monetary Policy Forum Report No.
“Liquidity and Leverage.” Journal of Financial          2. http://research.chicagogsb.edu/igm/events/
Intermediation, 17(3): 315–29.                          docs/MPFReport-final.pdf.
   Bank of England. 2008. Financial Stability Report.      Gromb, Denis, and Dimitri Vayanos. 2002.
April 2008, Issue 23. Available at: http://www-         “Equilibrium and Welfare in Markets with Finan-
.bankofengland.co.uk/publications/.                     cially Constrained Arbitrageurs.” Journal of
   Bank for International Settlements. 2008.            Financial Economics, 66(3): 361– 407.
78th Annual Report. Basel, Switzerland.                    International Monetary Fund. 2008. Global
   Brunnermeier, Markus, and Lasse Pedersen.            Financial Stability Report, April, Washington, D.C.
Forthcoming. “Market Liquidity and Funding                 Kashyap, Anil, Raghuram Rajan, and Jeremy
Liquidity.” Review of Financial Studies.                Stein. 2008. “Rethinking Capital Regulation.”
   Bryant, John. 1980. “A Model of Reserves,            Prepared for the Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas
Bank Runs and Deposit Insurance.” Journal of            City Symposium at Jackson Hole, 2008.
Banking and Finance, 4(4): 335– 44.                        Mayes, David, and Geoffrey Wood. 2008.
   Calomiris, Charles, and Charles Kahn. 1991.          “Lessons from the Northern Rock Episode.”
“The Role of Demandable Debt in Structuring             Unpublished paper, University of Auckland and
Optimal Banking Arrangements.” American Eco-            Cass Business School.
nomic Review, 81(3): 497–513.                              Milne, Alistair, and Geoffrey Wood. 2008.
   Diamond Douglas, and Philip Dybvig. 1983.            “Shattered on the Rock? British Financial Stabil-
“Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance, and Liquidity.”          ity from 1866 to 2007.” Unpublished paper, Cass
Journal of Political Economy, 91(3): 401–19.            Business School.
   Diamond Douglas, and Raghuram Rajan.                    Morris, Stephen, and Hyun Song Shin. 2008.
2001. “Liquidity Risk, Liquidity Creation, and          “Financial Regulation in a System Context.”
Financial Fragility: A Theory of Banking.” Jour-        Paper prepared for the Brookings Papers con-
nal of Political Economy, 109(2): 287–327.              ference, Fall 2008.
   Dimsdale, Nicholas. 2008. “The International            Northern Rock plc. Various years. Annual
Banking Crisis and British Experience” Unpub-           report. Available at: http://companyinfo.
lished paper, Oxford University.                        northernrock.co.uk/investorRelations/corporate
   Dudley, William C. 2007. “May You Live in            Reports.asp.
Interesting Times.” Remarks at the Federal Re-             Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. 1992.
serve Bank of Philadelphia, October 17. http://         “Liquidation Values and Debt Capacity: A Mar-
www.newyorkfed.org/newsevents/speeches/                 ket Equilibrium Approach.” Journal of Finance,
2007/dud071017.html.                                    47(4): 1343– 66.
   Dudley, William C. 2008. “May You Live in               Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert Vishny. 1997.
Interesting Times: The Sequel.” Remarks at the          “The Limits of Arbitrage.” Journal of Finance,
Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago’s 44th Annual           52(1): 35–55.
Conference on Bank Structure and Competi-                  Yorulmazer, Tanju. 2008. “Liquidity, Bank
tion, Chicago, Illinois, May 15. http://www.            Runs and Bailouts: Spillover Effects during the
newyorkfed.org/newsevents/speeches/2008/                Northern Rock Episode.” Unpublished paper,
dud080515.html.                                         Federal Reserve Bank of New York.
This article has been cited by:

 1. Julien Idier, Gildas Lamé, Jean-Stéphane Mésonnier. 2014. How useful is the Marginal Expected
    Shortfall for the measurement of systemic exposure? A practical assessment. Journal of Banking &
    Finance 47, 134-146. [CrossRef]
 2. David Vera, Kazuki Onji, Prasanna Gai. 2014. Are all financial crises created equal? Wholesale funding
    and two financial crises. Applied Economics 46:27, 3284-3299. [CrossRef]
 3. John K. Ashton, Andros Gregoriou. 2014. The Influence of Banking Centralization on Depositors:
    Regional Heterogeneities in the Transmission of Monetary Policy. Regional Studies 48, 1467-1482.
    [CrossRef]
 4. David-Jan Jansen, Robert H. J. Mosch, Carin A. B. van der Cruijsen. 2014. When Does the General
    Public Lose Trust in Banks?. Journal of Financial Services Research . [CrossRef]
 5. Ren-Raw Chen, N.K. Chidambaran, Michael B. Imerman, Ben J. Sopranzetti. 2014. Liquidity,
    leverage, and Lehman: A structural analysis of financial institutions in crisis. Journal of Banking &
    Finance 45, 117-139. [CrossRef]
 6. Andreas A. Jobst. 2014. Measuring systemic risk-adjusted liquidity (SRL)—A model approach.
    Journal of Banking & Finance 45, 270-287. [CrossRef]
 7. Geethanjali Selvaretnam. 2014. Optimal Reserves and Short-Term Interest Rates in a Model of Bank
    Runs. Scottish Journal of Political Economy n/a-n/a. [CrossRef]
 8. Meilan Yan, Maximilian J. B. Hall, Paul Turner. 2014. ESTIMATING LIQUIDITY RISK USING
    THE EXPOSURE-BASED CASH-FLOW-AT-RISK APPROACH: AN APPLICATION TO
    THE UK BANKING SECTOR. International Journal of Finance & Economics 19:10.1002/ijfe.v19.3,
    225-238. [CrossRef]
 9. G. Liang, E. Lutkebohmert, Y. Xiao. 2014. A Multiperiod Bank Run Model for Liquidity Risk.
    Review of Finance 18:2, 803-842. [CrossRef]
10. Alison Lui. 2014. Greed, recklessness and/or dishonesty? An investigation into the culture of five UK
    banks between 2004 and 2009. Journal of Banking Regulation . [CrossRef]
11. Bang Nam Jeon, María Pía OliveroAn overview: Global banking and financial markets in crisis 3-11.
    [CrossRef]
12. Jungsoo Park, Hyun-Han Shin, Jeong Ho SuhBank creditor structure and bank risk during liquidity
    crises: A survey with policy implications 433-447. [CrossRef]
13. ARNOUD W.A. BOOT. 2014. Financial Sector in Flux. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 46:s1,
    129-135. [CrossRef]
14. Achim Hauck, Uwe Vollmer. 2013. Emergency liquidity provision to public banks: Rules versus
    discretion. European Journal of Political Economy 32, 193-204. [CrossRef]
15. Michael R. King. 2013. The Basel III Net Stable Funding Ratio and bank net interest margins. Journal
    of Banking & Finance 37:11, 4144-4156. [CrossRef]
16. MICHAEL GOEDDE-MENKE, THOMAS LANGER, ANDREAS PFINGSTEN. 2013. Impact
    of the Financial Crisis on Bank Run Risk – Danger of the Days after. Journal of Banking & Finance
    . [CrossRef]
17. Guillaume Vuillemey. 2013. Solvency vs. Liquidity. A Decomposition of European Banks' Credit Risk
    over the Business Cycle. International Economics . [CrossRef]
18. Chunyang Wang. 2013. Bailouts and bank runs: Theory and evidence from TARP. European Economic
    Review 64, 169-180. [CrossRef]
19. Thomas Hoebel 197-222. [CrossRef]
You can also read