Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub

Page created by Ray Reid
 
CONTINUE READING
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Bachelor Thesis

A Systematic Comparison of the US and EU
  Startup Ecosystems of Cultivated Meat

Chair of Entrepreneurship, Innovation and Technological
                    Transformation
                Prof. Dr. Dries Faems
                Maxim L. Mommerency

      Submission date (Vallendar, May 23rd, 2020)

Julia Ines Schimanietz           Gilda Emilia Lukacs
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Abstract                                                                               II

Abstract
One of the most pressing challenges facing modern society is the need to feed the growing
world’s population with increasingly limited resources. Cultivated meat has the potential
to mitigate precisely this challenge, while simultaneously minimizing negative
externalities such as environmental destruction. Hence, our research provides a detailed
analysis of the current developments in the cultivated meat industry. Specifically, we
provide an in-depth comparison of the United States and the European Union
entrepreneurial ecosystems of cultivated meat. The resulting empirical findings originate
from the geographic mapping of ecosystem indicators, comprising (a) cultivated meat
startups, (b) investors, and (c) research institutions, and from qualitative expert
interviews. The evaluation of the synthesized findings indicates that the US
entrepreneurial ecosystem is more mature than the EU ecosystem and thus exhibits
superior performance in most ecosystem domains. However, both ecosystems face the
same core challenges. These challenges comprise the need to achieve regulatory approval,
cost-parity, and open access knowledge-sharing. Consequently, we provide generalizable
best practices and tailored recommendations to overcome these challenges based on the
implications of the systematic analysis.

Keywords: Cultivated Meat, Cell-Based Meat, Cellular Agriculture, Ecosystem Mapping,
Entrepreneurial Ecosystem, Matchmaking
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Table of Contents                                                                                                                     III

Table of Contents
Abstract .............................................................................................................................II
Table of Contents ............................................................................................................ III
Table of Figures ............................................................................................................... V
Table of Tables ................................................................................................................ V
Table of Abbreviations .................................................................................................... V
1     Intro ............................................................................................................................ 1
2     Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems ........................................................ 3
    2.1. History of Entrepreneurial Ecosystem Theory ....................................................... 3
      2.1.1          Origin of the Entrepreneurial Ecosystem Concept ..................................... 4
    2.2       Definition of Key Concepts ............................................................................... 6
      2.2.1          The Entrepreneurial Ecosystem .................................................................. 7
    2.3       Conditions for Successful Entrepreneurial Ecosystems ..................................... 8
      2.3.1          Definition of EE Success ............................................................................ 8
      2.3.2          EE Frameworks in Comparison .................................................................. 9
    2.4       How to Measure the Success of an EE ............................................................. 10
    2.5       Implications for Policymakers ......................................................................... 11
    2.6       Role of Universities.......................................................................................... 13
3     Literature Review: Cultivated Meat ......................................................................... 16
    3.1       History and Key Terminology ......................................................................... 16
    3.2       Triple Bottom Line Evaluation ........................................................................ 19
4     Methodology ............................................................................................................ 23
    4.1       Purpose of Research Method ........................................................................... 23
    4.2       Design of Research Method ............................................................................. 23
5     Findings .................................................................................................................... 27
    5.1       Visualization of Ecosystem Clusters ................................................................ 27
      5.1.1          Global Perspective .................................................................................... 27
      5.1.2          Quantitative Breakdown ........................................................................... 28
      5.1.3          Visualization of Investment Landscape .................................................... 29
    5.2       Analysis of the Most Important Hubs .............................................................. 29
      5.2.1          Identified Hubs in the US Ecosystem ....................................................... 29
      5.2.2          Identified Hubs in the EU Ecosystem ....................................................... 33
    5.3       Spider Web Framework Analysis .................................................................... 37
      5.3.1          US Spider Web Analysis .......................................................................... 38
      5.3.2          EU Spider Web Analysis .......................................................................... 47
    5.4       Visualization of Qualitative Findings .............................................................. 55
6     Discussion ................................................................................................................ 56
    6.1       Summary of Findings ....................................................................................... 56
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Table of Contents                                                                                                                IV
    6.2      Practical Implications and Recommendations ................................................. 58
    6.3      Case Application: Germany ............................................................................. 62
    6.4      Theoretical Implications: NGOs as Matchmakers ........................................... 66
7     Conclusion................................................................................................................ 68
    7.1      Limitations of Research Approach ................................................................... 68
    7.2      Recommendations for Further Research .......................................................... 69
8     Final Remarks .......................................................................................................... 71
Bibliography ................................................................................................................... 72
Appendix ......................................................................................................................... 80
Delineation of Contributions .......................................................................................... 86
Declaration of Authorship .............................................................................................. 87
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Table of Figures                                                                     V

Table of Figures
Figure 1: The Triple Bottom Line Framework _______________________________ 19

Figure 2: Global Map of Entrepreneurial Ecosystem Indicators __________________ 27

Figure 3: Investor's Headquarters in the EU (left) vs. the US (right) ______________ 29

Figure 4: Visualization of the US Cultivated Meat Ecosystem ___________________ 30

Figure 5: Visualization of the EU Cultivated Meat Ecosystem ___________________ 33

Figure 6: Magnification of the EU Cultivated Meat Ecosystem __________________ 37

Figure 7: Modified Framework: Domains of the Entrepreneurship Ecosystem ______ 55

Figure 8: Visualization of Causalities ______________________________________ 62

Table of Tables
Table 1: Scoring System for EE Evaluation _________________________________ 25

Table 2: Scores of the Evaluated EEs for Cultivated Meat ______________________ 38

Table of Abbreviations
 CAS               Cellular Agriculture Society
 EE                Entrepreneurial Ecosystem
 EFSA              European Food Safety Authority
 FBS               Fetal Bovine Serum
 FDA               Food & Drug Administration
 FAO               Food and Agriculture Organization
 GMO               Genetically Modified Organism
 GHG               Greenhouse Gas
 HGF               High-Growth Firm
 RIS               Regional Innovation Systems
 GFI               The Good Food Institute
 TEA               Total Entrepreneurial Activity
 USDA              Unites States Department of Agriculture
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Intro                                                                                      1

1 Intro
        "[R]aising meat takes a great deal of land and water and has a substantial
        environmental impact. Put simply, there's no way to produce enough meat for
        9 billion people. However, we can't ask everyone to become vegetarians"
        - Bill Gates, 2013

One of the most critical questions of the 21st century is whether the world will be able to
feed 9 billion people by 2050 (Holt-Giménez, 2019; Gates, 2019). This daunting
challenge has two main contributors. Firstly, experts prognosticate a sharp population
increase to occur within the next thirty years (e.g., United Nations, 2019). Secondly,
researchers warned about a problematic, unsustainable shift in food consumption patterns.
Namely, that people are continuously increasing their demand for animal protein in the
form of meat (Gates, 2019).
As a result, the need for a substantial transformation of the meat industry has increased
over the past decade. Consequently, alternative protein companies emerged, aiming to
provide solutions to the problems of increasing resource constraints. Notably, cells
cultivated in bioreactors constitute the perhaps most promising alternative protein source.
Hence, so-called cultivated meat companies offer consumers genuine meat, but take
raising and slaughtering animals out of the food supply chain. Therefore, cultivated meat
can provide consumers with more convenience than a vegetarian or vegan diet, while
simultaneously enabling them to consume more sustainable products. Thus, we decided
that the investigation of the ecosystem conditions facing cultivated meat should be the
purpose of our research.
Noteworthily, the term Entrepreneurial Ecosystem (EE) and its underlying concepts date
back to the 1980s and 1990s. Until today, EEs continue to remain a 'hot topic' in
entrepreneurial and social sciences, with lots of new publications trying to grasp their
complex interrelations (e.g., Spigel & Harrison, 2017). However, researchers frequently
express disagreement about definitions and causations in this field. Hence, a lack of
consistency and consolidation of findings constitute the main limitation in this domain.
Further, entrepreneurial ecosystems do not only face contemporary challenges in theory
but also in practice. For instance, the cultivated meat ecosystem faces practical challenges
resulting from a global economy.
Despite the promising future potential of cultivated meat to disrupt the $2 trillion meat
market, cultivated meat startups can still not sell their products commercially, even
though the technology has been in existence for almost a decade (Bashi et al., 2019). As
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Intro                                                                                     2

a consequence, we identified the present inconsistencies in EE literature and the lack of
academic research regarding the development of cultivated meat ecosystems as an
essential research gap.
Our work's core objective is the detailed mapping and qualitative investigation of the
Europen Union (EU) and the United States (US) ecosystems of cultivated meat and the
subsequent application of our findings to the German EE. Specifically, we will provide
generalizable recommendations and best practices, as well as a case application to the
German cultivated meat ecosystem. Consequently, our research findings are relevant for
policymakers and industry practitioners, such as entrepreneurs, investors, life science
companies, and meat industry incumbents. Further, our contribution offers a relevant
implication for future academic literature on entrepreneurial ecosystems with regards to
matchmaking.
The main findings of our research include that the EU and the US ecosystems are the
most developed entrepreneurial ecosystems globally. However, the US has a few unique
advantages over the EU. The strengths of the US ecosystems constitute a resilient
entrepreneurial culture, facilitative support systems, as well as favorable market
conditions and networks. Meanwhile, the EU ecosystem does not outperform the US in
any domain. However, its comparative strengths are its culture, market conditions, and
nurturing foundation of human capital. Moreover, the main implication of our findings is
that regulatory approval, cost-parity with meat products, and the availability of open
access research constitute the key milestones that both cultivated meat ecosystems need
to achieve in the future.
In the following, we will begin with a review of existing academic literature on EE theory.
The goal of the literature review is to compare and contrast existing theories in order to
provide a structured overview of the research community's status quo. Subsequently, we
will summarize the current state of the cultivated meat industry, followed by the
presentations of findings of the EE mapping of the cultivated meat industry, which we
performed using Crunchbase and BatchGeo. Next, we will supplement the findings with
insights from semi-structured expert interviews. Finally, we will provide theoretical and
practical recommendations to help overcome the identified challenges.
Bachelor Thesis - WHU Innovation Ecosystem Hub
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                            3

2 Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems
The review of existing academic literature aims to provide a comprehensive overview of
patterns and contrasts inherent in existing theories. For this purpose, we will outline the
origin of the EE terminology and define its key concepts. Subsequently, the literature
review will focus on outlining conditions and measures for EE success before taking deep
dives into the role of policy and universities.

2.1. History of Entrepreneurial Ecosystem Theory

Biological vocabulary has found its way into business discourse, especially in
entrepreneurship. For example, the terminology of seed capital has become standard
entrepreneurial vocabulary. In the 1990s, another biological term was added to the
business jargon to conceptualize the geographical interconnectedness of different actors
and institutions, namely the entrepreneurial ecosystem. Regarding the historical
development of the term, the first publications legitimized the concept of ecosystems as
an operator in the broader business context, as opposed to the entrepreneurship context.
In contrast, most recent research efforts focused on the consolidation of findings and the
creation of generalizable terminology.
James Moore was one of the first researchers who used the metaphor of an ecosystem in
his publications in the 1980s and 1990s (Spigel & Harrison, 2017). According to Moore,
the concept bridges the interconnectedness of resources such as "capital, partners,
suppliers, and customers" (1993, p.75). Moreover, Moore's findings suggested that "a
company be viewed not as a member of a single industry but as part of a business
ecosystem that crosses a variety of industries" (Moore, 1993, p.76). Consequently, the
focus of research shifted from the individual entrepreneur and her startup towards the
local framework conditions surrounding her. This shift in focus is a distinctive property
of EE literature (Spigel & Harrison, 2017).
A more recent approach to the ecosystem metaphor was taken by Isenberg in 2011. He
used it to ameliorate the process of creating strategies for successful entrepreneurship.
Specifically, his Entrepreneurship Ecosystem Strategy proposes a framework made of six
pillars (Appendix A) and conceptualizes the causes of regional concentrations of
entrepreneurship. Since then, these pillars have inspired further modern research
approaches (e.g., Spigel & Harrison, 2017; Mason & Brown, 2014).
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             4

2.1.1   Origin of the Entrepreneurial Ecosystem Concept

To carry forward the biological metaphors, the newly established branch of EE literature
draws from a broad stem. These influences range from "economic geography [and]
economics" (Mason & Brown, 2014, p. 26) to "regional science, [...] industrial clusters,
[...] regional innovation systems (RIS)", (Spigel & Harrison, 2017, p. 153) to the market
failure approach (Stam, 2015). Hence, we will outline the main similarities the EE
literature shares with its lineage before highlighting its distinctive properties.

Firstly, one common trait appears to be the focus of the branches of literature on the same
phenomenon, namely on how exactly entrepreneurship is intertwined with its external
environment (Spigel & Harrison, 2017). In other words, a shared trait with, for example,
RIS and industrial cluster literature is the recognition that "there are forces beyond the
boundaries of an organization but within those of a region that can contribute to a firm's
overall competitiveness." (Stam & Spigel, 2016, p. 3). Similarly, systems theory
emphasizes a bottom-up explanation of the performance of regional economies and
moves away from the individualistic perception of the entrepreneur (Moore, 1993; Stam
& Spigel 2016).
Secondly, especially Porter's cluster theory has valuable implications for EEs. Namely
that "paradoxically, the enduring competitive advantages in a global economy lie
increasingly in local things" (1998, p. 77). Similarly, in EE theory, the regional
concentrations and competitive advantages of high-performing, new ventures can be
explained by advantages emerging from their local context, such as information spillovers
(Spigel & Harrison 2017).
Thirdly, RIS literature adds more detail to the explanation. Namely, the emphasis on
networks for resource generation, organization's roles in producing human capital, and
the importance of policy (Spigel & Harrison, 2017; Isenberg, 2011).
In summary, similar to its lineage, EE theory focuses on a bottom-up, contextual analysis
of economic performance. This focus adds the importance of resources, such as human
capital and policy, to the crucial factors contributing to high-performance
entrepreneurship.

In spite of many shared features with the literature it originated from, the EE approach
also comprises many distinctive properties. However, according to Isenberg (2011), EE
theory does not necessarily render its lineage complacent. Instead, EE theory serves as a
"complement, or even pre-condition to, cluster strategies, innovation systems,
knowledge-based economies, and national competitiveness policies" (p. 1).
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             5

The first addition to the concepts that the EE evolved from is the importance of
knowledge. For example, Spigel and Harrison (2017) added knowledge about
entrepreneurial processes to the importance of market and technical knowledge, which
was already present in RIS and cluster literature.
Second, EE theory distinguishes itself from previous concepts through industry
agnosticism. While cluster frameworks are usually preoccupied with the analysis of the
flow of resources within industry barriers, EE theory has a geographical focus in the most
literal sense. Specifically, it comprises all industries within a specific region (e.g.,
Isenberg, 2011; Stam & Spigel, 2016; Spigel & Harrison, 2017).
Third, in most of the previous management literature, such as the RIS or the market failure
approach, "the role of entrepreneurs remains a black box" (e.g., Stam & Spigel, 2016,
p.11). In contrast, the title of the EE concept is indicative of the importance of the
entrepreneur. However, the entrepreneur needs to be analyzed in a productive balance
with her surroundings.
Fourth, another distinguishing aspect of EE literature is the narrow understanding of
entrepreneurship. For example, Sussan and Acs (2017) used the terms "routine and high-
growth entrepreneurship" (p. 58). Similarly, Isenberg (2011) asserted that one should
distinguish between self-employment in the form of small and medium-sized enterprises
(SMEs)       (routine      entrepreneurship),   and    entrepreneurship      (high-growth
entrepreneurship). Furthermore, while the focus on entrepreneurs is a distinctive feature
of EE literature, Stam and Spigel (2016) have also emphasized the importance of other
stakeholders as essential feeders of the ecosystem.
Lastly, most recent EE theories adopt a process view of markets and entrepreneurship
(Spigel & Harrison, 2017). For instance, the market failure approach follows the ideal of
a static market equilibrium, while EE theory describes markets as an evolving process
(Stam & Spigel, 2016). We will discuss the resulting policy implications further in
subsection 2.5.

To conclude, the concept of entrepreneurial ecosystems is distinct from its origin due to
the importance of knowledge about entrepreneurial processes, industry agnosticism, the
narrow definition of the entrepreneur, and finally, a process view of markets and
entrepreneurship.
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                              6

2.2 Definition of Key Concepts

After the summary of the history and origin of the terminology, we will outline key
concepts that are relevant for the analysis of EE performance. Initially, we will link the
biological ecosystem to its business analog and clarify the entrepreneurship terminology.
Subsequently, we will propose a synthesis of the terms to finally provide a comprehensive
definition of an entrepreneurial ecosystem.

According to its textbook definition, an ecosystem in its most literal sense is a "system
that includes all living organisms (biotic factors) in an area as well as its physical
environment (abiotic factors) functioning together as a unit"1. Sussan and Acs (2017)
have provided a very comprehensive application of this concept by noting that in a
business context, the biotic factors describe agents including entrepreneurs or investors,
while institutions such as government bodies constitute abiotic factors. Thus, resources
such as venture capital (VC) or knowledge serve as nutrients of the ecosystem.
As discussed, the entrepreneur is the focus of the entrepreneurial ecosystem. More
specifically, entrepreneurship in the EE context exclusively refers to high-growth
entrepreneurship and excludes routine entrepreneurship (Sussan & Acs, 2017).
Accordingly, the entrepreneur is a "person who is continually pursuing economic value
through growth and, as a result, is always dissatisfied with the status quo" (Isenberg, 2011,
p. 2). Thus, risk is an intrinsic property of entrepreneurship. For instance, there exists a
time lag in the potential materialization of favorable results in the future, in contrast to
risky investments, which entrepreneurs have to make in the present (Isenberg, 2011;
Ansari et al., 2016). Further, resourcefulness is a characteristic of entrepreneurship.
According to Stangler and Bell-Masterson (2015), the "essence of entrepreneurial
strategy" (p. 3) lies in the entrepreneurs' achievement of excellent results under severely
constrained resources. Moreover, many researchers built their theories based on
Schumpeter's work on entrepreneurship (e.g., Sussan & Acs, 2017; Mason & Brown,
2014). The Schumpeterian entrepreneur is the impersonation of high-growth, high-risk
entrepreneurship (Sussan & Acs, 2017). Further, Kirzner (1999) has described
entrepreneurship as "essentially disruptive, destroying the pre-existing state of
equilibrium."

1   https://www.biologyonline.com/dictionary/ecosystem
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             7

2.2.1    The Entrepreneurial Ecosystem

The term entrepreneurial ecosystem builds the synthesis of the definitions of ecosystems
and entrepreneurship, as outlined above. It implies that ecosystems can explain high-
growth entrepreneurship. "[E]ntrepreneurship tends to be geographically concentrated in
specific regions, cities, neighborhoods, and even buildings" (Isenberg, 2011, p. 10). Thus,
the interconnectedness of entrepreneurial actors, organizations, and processes that
constitute the local environment plays a central role (Mason & Brown, 2014). Hence, the
analysis of such ecosystems should be conducted bottom-up, without undue focus on the
individual entrepreneur (Moore, 1993; Stam, 2015).
As discussed, another unique property of EE theory is its focus on high-growth
entrepreneurship. Mason and Brown (2014) have used the term blockbuster
entrepreneurs to describe individuals with the largest potential to produce extremely
high-growth firms (HGFs). Similarly, Stam et al. (2012) emphasized that ambitious
entrepreneurs should be the center of attention as "someone who engages in the
entrepreneurial process with the aim to create as much value as possible" (p. 26). For
instance, ambitious entrepreneurs attach extremely high value to extraordinary
performance and are constantly dissatisfied with the status quo (Isenberg 2011; Stam et
al., 2012). Therefore, high ambition, not business-ownership, should be the differentiating
factor of entrepreneurship (Isenberg, 2011). Further, most EE literature supplements the
concept of Schumpeterian entrepreneurs with the Kirznerian approach. Kirzner's
entrepreneur does not necessarily disrupt the existing equilibrium. Instead, she engages
in arbitrage because she is the first to notice that market conditions have changed (Sussan
and Acs, 2017). Thus, in contrast to Schumpeter, the Kirznerian entrepreneur's business
model can be, but need not be, based on disruptive innovation (Kirzner, 1999; Isenberg,
2011).
In summary, the purpose of an entrepreneurial ecosystem goes beyond the individualistic
enrichment of the entrepreneur. Ideally, HGF creation leads to a virtuous spiral of positive
externalities for society as a whole, and simultaneously attracts more entrepreneurial
activity (Isenberg, 2011; Stam, 2015).

Another noteworthy property of the EE approach is a process view on ecosystem
emergence. Researchers who have treated the process of EE development as a control
variable, have been criticized for their static approaches (e.g., Mason & Brown, 2014,
Stam & Spigel 2016). Thus the notion of a system perspective is inherent in the textbook
definition of an ecosystem. As such, systems entail a constant (co-) evolution instead of
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             8

a snapshot in time (Isenberg, 2011; Mason & Brown, 2014; Sussan & Acs, 2017). Further,
in biology, ecosystems can be referred to as closed systems, i.e., self-sustaining systems.
This self-sustainment is a success factor of entrepreneurial ecosystems. For example:
"Spillovers are positive feedback, and all engineers know that a system with positive
feedback sometimes hits a tipping point in which it becomes self-generating or self-
sustaining" (Isenberg, 2011, p. 9). Consequently, once EEs enter an upward spiral with
net positive resource inflows into the system, they eventually become resilient to severe
threats such as economic shocks (Spigel & Harrison, 2017).
While researchers have taken different approaches to this dynamic process, they agree
that causalities play a central role in ecosystem success (e.g., Isenberg, 2011; Stam &
Spigel, 2016). In fact, Stangler and Bell-Masterson (2015) noted that the
interconnectedness of elements in an EE is just as important as the elements by
themselves. Consequently, literature has shown that a dynamic process view needs to take
high interdependence into account.

To conclude, the delineation of key terminology has shown that a focus on ambitious
entrepreneurs, a dynamic process view of EE development, and the recognition of high
interdependence constitute distinctive characteristics of EE theory.

2.3     Conditions for Successful Entrepreneurial Ecosystems

2.3.1   Definition of EE Success

In this subchapter, we will specify what success means in the case of EEs and
subsequently outline the underlying conditions for success. As discussed, some scholars
regard innovation as the ultimate outcome of the EE model (Stam, 2015). In contrast,
others emphasize that entrepreneurship does not need to be innovative to be successful
(e.g., Kirzner, 1999; Isenberg, 2011). However, researchers agree that sustainability is
essential for entrepreneurial ecosystems to flourish. In general, the sustainability of EEs
describes a self-reinforcing process of continuous new venture creation, which challenges
the status quo in a virtuous cycle of positive externalities (Isenberg, 2011; Sussan and
Acs, 2017). Hence, high-growth successful venture creation ultimately leads to a
sustainable, resilient ecosystem.
Researchers and organizations have developed many frameworks to define the underlying
processes and elements that contribute to EE success. In the following, we will thus
outline emerging patterns and shared ideas.
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                               9

2.3.2   EE Frameworks in Comparison

Two prominent frameworks from Isenberg (2011) and the World Economic Forum
(WEF) (2013) describe the fundamental principles for cultivating EEs. Their frameworks
share the pillars of facilitative policy, markets, financial and human capital, culture, as
well as supports. Moreover, the WEF explicitly states the pillars of education and training
in its framework, which remain implicit in Isenberg's work (Appendix A). Building on
these works, Stam and Spigel introduced the Entrepreneurial Ecosystem Model
(Appendix B) to add causality to the pillars mentioned above (2016, p. 9). The model
separates input factors of EEs into framework and systemic conditions. Specifically,
framework conditions describe the leading contextual causes of value creation, which
comprise social, informal institutions, and physical enablers or inhibitors of human
interaction. Contrastingly, systemic conditions are more closely related to the heart of the
organization, such as leadership or finance. In their model, entrepreneurial activity, "the
process by which individuals create opportunities for innovation" (p. 2), is an intermediate
output, leading to innovation as the ultimate outcome via upward causation. Notably, the
authors mitigated the risk of oversimplifying the causalities by also acknowledging
downward and intra-layer causation.

Consistent with the previously outlined process view on the entrepreneurial ecosystem,
Spigel and Harrison (2017) have added a dynamic life cycle perspective to the EE model
through their Process Theory Framework. Hence, over its life cycle, an EE either
develops into a resilient ecosystem (i.e., success) or a weakened ecosystem (i.e., failure).
The authors characterize a thriving ecosystem through high levels of connectivity, the
creation and flow of entrepreneurial resources, and a net positive inflow of resources into
the ecosystem (Appendix C).
This model emphasizes the importance of the accessibility and recycling of resources, as
well as learning from failure. Moreover, "the flow [functionality] of resources in the
ecosystem is as relevant for its success as their presence [strength]." (Spigel & Harrison,
2017, p. 163). This statement implies that, for example, the existence of venture capitalists
is not sufficient; they must also be approachable. Furthermore, the recycling of resources
fosters EE growth (Isenberg, 2011; Mason & Brown, 2014; Stam, 2015). For instance,
successful entrepreneurs usually stay in their ecosystem after they exit a startup, and thus
become routine entrepreneurs or mentors. In EE literature, experts frequently describe
mentors as dealmakers, i.e., people who have the know-how and connections necessary
to support young companies (Isenberg, 2011; Mason & Brown, 2014). Lastly,
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                              10

entrepreneurial failure contributes to value creation in the form of knowledge recycling.
For instance, failure results in knowledge creation as well as the redistribution of financial
and human resources.

In summary, successful EEs comprise high connectivity between all elements, which
results in mutually beneficial spillovers and recycling of knowledge. Consequently, this
will yield a net positive inflow of new, accessible entrepreneurial resources.

2.4     How to Measure the Success of an EE

After the comparison of conducive conditions for EE success, we will summarize
different approaches to success measurement before reviewing the EE approach's policy
implications.

As discussed, EE success is defined as a process through which an ecosystem becomes
self-sustaining (Isenberg, 2011). Hence, where performance measurement is concerned,
there is no straightforward, measurable goal due to the multifaceted underlying
conditions. Consequently, challenges for success-measurement include tailoring
measurements to the relevant audience and the underlying motivation. For example,
performance indicators would differ based on underlying motivations, such as increasing
exit multiples versus increasing innovation (Stangler & Bell-Masterson, 2015).
Additionally, data is often not available at the desired level of analysis, and those who
measure EE performance need to find a balance between too much and too little
measurement (Stangler & Bell-Masterson, 2015; Mason & Brown, 2014).
The Global Entrepreneurship Index (GEI) is a rather traditional form of EE success
measurement and comprises the pillar of total entrepreneurial activity (TEA). However,
it does not separate high-growth entrepreneurship from self-employment and is thus
negatively correlated to economic growth and development (Acs et al., 2017). Further,
Spigel and Harrison (2017) refuted the circular argument of new firm formation as a
success measure and called for a more process-based measure for EE success.

A more promising indicator for successful EE formation seems to be the number of
unicorns in a region. For instance, Acs et al. (2017) have shown that this measure can
outpace sophisticated measures of self-employment, such as the TEA (Acs et al., 2017).
Hence, the authors identified the number of unicorns per 10 million inhabitants as a
suitable measure for EE performance (Acs et al., 2017). Similarly, Isenberg (2011)
proposed that "one new high potential venture entering the system every year, for about
every 50,000 to 150,000 people" (p. 9), should be used as a rule of thumb.
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             11

Lastly, several publications have emphasized the importance of benchmarking in the EE
context. Intuitively, benchmarking should be performed across locations and across time
within ecosystems, because ecosystems do not evolve in a vacuum (Isenberg, 2011;
Stangler & Bell-Masterson, 2015). For example, the Four Pillars of EE Vibrancy suggest
that benchmarking should focus on density, fluidity, connectivity, and diversity (Stangler
& Bell-Masterson, 2015).
First, density comprises measures that utilize the regional population as the denominator,
thus providing relative measures. Second, fluidity describes the ease of the combination
of existing resources to produce novel outcomes. Third, connectivity utilizes figures such
as the number of spinoffs or number of connections per dealmaker (Mason & Brown,
2014). Finally, diversity includes measures such as upward and downward income
mobility and the net value of immigration versus emigration. Therefore, these four pillars
propose an approach similar to the process view of Spigel and Harrison (2017). The Four
Pillars of EE Vibrancy also support Isenberg's (2011) assertions that none of the
interrelated factors of an EE should be regarded in isolation.

Consequently, dynamic, process-oriented measures that take into account the trajectory
across locations and over time are the best suitable measures of EE success.

2.5     Implications for Policymakers

In 2011, Isenberg described the entrepreneurial ecosystem strategy as the fastest way to
achieve economic growth and prosperity. Thus, it is essential to understand how policy
can facilitate positive externalities while mitigating adverse results. In fact, according to
academic literature, the following two pitfalls are the most common among policymakers.
First, every EE is unique. Therefore, policies that, for example, aim to imitate Silicon
Valley, set themselves up for failure (Isenberg, 2011; Mason & Brown, 2014; Stam &
Spigel, 2016). Instead, policy should take a tailored approach based on the individual
assets of the ecosystem. Second, entrepreneurship and non-entrepreneurship policy need
to be separated. According to Isenberg (2011), using the same policy for high-growth
startups and SMEs neglects the EE's complexity and inhibits growth.
Consequently, the above-mentioned need for individual EE policies is indicative of the
decreased importance of top-down governmental interventions. In fact, if policies are not
tailored to the individual EEs, they can hinder their development and thus impede
innovation (Stam & Spigel, 2016). Further, researchers have criticized policies that target
isolated elements of the complex system (e.g., Isenberg, 2011). Therefore, experts suggest
a shift from market-focused, top-down intervention towards bottom-up policymaking
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             12

(Mason & Brown, 2014). More simplified: "[T]here is a big difference between building
a highway system and telling people where to drive" (Isenberg, 2011, p. 4). In short,
governments should focus on bottom-up relational support instead of top-down
transactional support.

Over the past decade, the focus of policy has changed from increasing the startup rate
(quantity) towards improving the potential of entrepreneurs (quality) (Isenberg, 2011;
Spigel & Harrison, 2017). Thus, the literature review yielded three guiding principles of
policy implications. First, policymakers should assign a high priority to HGFs and
ambitious entrepreneurs (Isenberg, 2011; Stam & Spigel, 2016). While HGFs make up a
very small percentage of the total number of firms, their contribution to job creation and
economic growth is disproportionately large. Besides the direct effects, HGFs also create
desirable spillover effects contributing to the generation of knowledge, connectivity, and
ideas (Isenberg, 2011; Mason & Brown, 2014). Second, a good policy should make
market entry as easy as possible and, at the same time, allow for a natural selection
approach to resource allocation, i.e., making high potential ventures survive while letting
low potential ventures fail fast (Isenberg, 2011). Third, in order to achieve good results
quickly, policymakers should direct resources to specific, concentrated locations to create
environments for ambitious entrepreneurship (Isenberg 2010; Isenberg, 2011; Mason &
Brown, 2014).
Another logical consequence of bottom-up policies in an evolving ecosystem is a time
lag in the development of policies. Moreover, a bottom-up approach implies that the
government does not tell entrepreneurs where to innovate (Isenberg, 2011; Spigel &
Harrison, 2017). Thus, there is usually little regulation when disruptive innovation first
occurs, which encourages its development. However, once a disruptive innovation
becomes established, the degree of regulation increases until it reaches a tipping point,
from where it starts to inhibit innovation through over-regulation. Sussan and Acs (2017)
described this phenomenon as an inverted U-shape. However, previous research has
shown that the involvement of private sector advisors can mitigate the risk of over-
regulation (Isenberg 2011; Sussan and Acs, 2017).
Lastly, depending on the execution of EE policy, it can result in net positive or negative
externalities. On the one hand, EE policy can lead to negative externalities, such as
regional inequalities in the form of gentrification or increased cost of living. On the other
hand, good policies can lead to social value creation, which is a lot larger than the
individual value that entrepreneurs create for themselves (Stam & Spigel, 2016; Spigel &
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             13

Harrison, 2017). For instance, if success stories of HGFs are shared, they may inspire an
entire generation of new HGFs.
In this context, we defined the main challenge that policymakers face as the mandate
dilemma. It describes the phenomenon that the government has the mandate for holistic
market intervention in the EE, but not the competence. In contrast, the private sector has
the required competence, but no mandate (Isenberg, 2011). Consequently, it is advisable
to establish an independent third-party organization that is not owned by a specific
institution and represents the interests of all relevant stakeholder groups (Isenberg, 2011).
This self-liquidating organization should exist until the respective EE becomes self-
sustaining.

In summary, a nurturing policy should assume a facilitative role. Moreover, a conducive
policy for ambitious entrepreneurship should foster an environment where the natural
selection of the most promising companies can take its course. Furthermore, quality over
quantity of entrepreneurship should have high policy priority (Stam & Spigel, 2016).
Lastly, the private sector should be involved to remove unnecessary regulatory barriers.
Thus, the mandate dilemma can be resolved by introducing independent third-party
organizations that pool stakeholder interests.

2.6     Role of Universities

The continuous addition and exchange of diverse and skilled talent is an essential
contributor to a successful EE (Isenberg, 2010; World Economic Forum, 2013; Stam &
Spigel, 2016). Especially universities have been identified as catalysts (Guerrero et al.,
2016) for the successful emergence of EEs. Moreover, they can help to foster the
entrepreneurial culture and connectivity within EEs (Isenberg, 2010).

The appropriate unit of analysis for EEs is often a source of disagreement among
researchers, ranging from a global to a single building level (e.g., Acs et al., 2017).
Consequently, Acs et al. (2017) suggested focusing on knowledge instead of physical
frontiers for the characterization of ecosystems. For instance, researchers suggested that
universities constitute EEs by themselves, as they are connectors of education, research,
and knowledge-transfer. Researchers have also described universities as subsystems in a
larger context of country or city-level ecosystems (Guerrero et al., 2016; Hayter, 2016).
These "nested, loosely organized academic and non-academic intermediaries [...] work
collectively and strategically to promote and support academic entrepreneurship"
(Hayter, 2016, p. 652).
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                            14

Notably, university ecosystems comprise not only academic players such as students and
faculty but also entrepreneurs in residence, academic advisors, or partner organizations
(Hayter, 2016). Hence, this proximity facilitates knowledge and work transfer within this
network, which contributes to high rates of entrepreneurship and, thus, the success of
ecosystems (Guerrero et al., 2016; Hayter, 2016). The resulting creation of conducive
environments for entrepreneurship results in the evocation of a self-reinforcing virtuous
cycle, leading to the attraction of more entrepreneurial capital (Guerrero et al., 2016;
Hayter, 2016). Consequently, a variety of researchers have described universities as
promising sources of disruptive innovation (World Economic Forum, 2013; Guerrero et
al., 2016; Hayter, 2016; Acs et al., 2017; Jahanian, 2018).
As discussed, universities produce valuable entrepreneurial talent and thus contribute to
new venture formation (World Economic Forum, 2013). Moreover, universities'
innovative contexts encourage sustainable, entrepreneurial resource creation through a
unique combination of advanced research and training (Guerrero et al., 2016). Therefore,
incumbent companies often invest in university research to benefit from new ideas as well
as human capital resulting from the process (World Economic Forum, 2013). For
instance, US funding for university research and development (R&D) increased from $2.4
billion to $4.2 billion, between 2006 and 2016 (Jahanian, 2018).
However, universities do not only serve as talent matchmakers but also incubate
innovative ideas themselves (Hayter, 2016; Acs et al., 2017). Consequently, their efforts
often lead to the development of spin-off firms, patents, research publications, and
consulting services (Cohen et al., 2002). Further, universities can influence innovation
beyond the boundaries of their organizations: "[U]niversity leaders have a leading role to
play in helping the workforce adapt to the disruptive technologies, ensuring that the new
economy works for everyone" (Jahanian, 2018).
Moreover, universities share open source information more frequently than companies
and thus constitute essential information intermediaries in EEs. For instance, according
to Isenberg (2010), they contribute to knowledge-sharing through information platforms
and conferences.
Hence, knowledge-transfer does not only occur formally through education, but also
informally through "business plan competitions, networking events, 'TED talks' by
successful academic entrepreneurs, hack-a-thons, and entrepreneurship clubs" (Hayter,
2016, p. 649). In summary, universities facilitate network effects that contribute to strong
EEs though the "effective distribution of knowledge, lab[o]r, and capital" (Hayter, 2016;
Stam & Spigel, 2016, p. 9).
Literature Review: Entrepreneurial Ecosystems                                             15

In addition to open source innovation-sharing, universities usually comprise a fruitful
ground for innovation as they bring together perspectives of people from diverse cultural
backgrounds. For instance, history has shown that immigrants have especially high
entrepreneurial propensities and are twice as likely to start a company than the native
community (Stangler & Bell-Masterson, 2015; Guerrero et al., 2016). Consequently,
universities have started initiatives to attract and incentivize underrepresented minorities
to join their organizations. Thereby, universities encourage the exchange of diverse
opinions (Jahanian, 2018). Such initiatives are in line with the position of the WEF
(2013), who advocates for increased diversity in universities and the workplace.
As discussed before, a vibrant ecosystem attracts a net positive inflow of resources.
However, critics emphasize how the potential of immigrant talent in universities can only
add limited value to the local entrepreneurial ecosystem, if the talent emigrates post-
graduation due to a lack of facilitative conditions for entrepreneurship in the local
environment (Isenberg, 2011). Consequently, universities are valuable sources of
disruptive innovation, open access resources, and diverse skillsets. However, their ability
to serve as catalysts for the ecosystem can only be of use if the framework conditions in
the ecosystem are facilitative.
Literature Review: Cultivated Meat                                                       16

3 Literature Review: Cultivated Meat
After the review of key concepts and implications from EE literature, we will analyze the
state of the industry (SOI) of cultivated meat before we move on to the research method.
In the following, we will define the key terminology, outline the history of the technology,
and provide a triple bottom line overview of the potential impact of cultivated meat.

3.1     History and Key Terminology

Undoubtedly, humans need to consume protein for their bodies to function properly
(Brazier, 2018). More specifically, protein enables the regulation of cells, tissues, and
organs. While many different natural sources of protein exist, animal protein is the most
prevalently consumed protein source in our modern society. It is therefore not surprising
that the global meat market is worth over $1.7 trillion, feeding a world population of over
7.7 billion people (Bashi et al., 2019; United Nations, 2019). For instance, the six most
prominent incumbents in the US meat industry, such as Tyson Foods or Cargill, already
account for over $60 billion of the total meat market value (CB Insights, 2019a). In
comparison, the alternative protein market is worth $2.2 billion. Hence, it only constitutes
a marginal proportion of global protein consumption.
In order to keep up with the demand, the meat industry slaughters over 72 billion land
animals every year. The inclusion of fish in the equation increases this number to roughly
1.3 trillion animals annually (Zampa, 2018). However, due to continuous population
growth, the world's capacity to supply enough meat from traditional animal agriculture
will soon reach its limits (Hancox, 2018). Thus, the need for a product alternative of
similar nutritional components and taste has emerged, and consequently, meat substitutes
have entered the market (Appendix D). Subgroups of this protein category include (a)
plant, (b) fungus, (c) insect, and (d) cell-based meat alternatives (Godfray et al., 2019).
Within the (a) plant-based protein sector, companies such as Beyond Meat have recently
gained immense popularity. According to CB Insights (2019a), the valuation of Beyond
Meat multiplied to almost $5 billion since its initial public offering in May of 2019, when
the company value was still at $1.5 billion.
While most companies in the plant-based protein industry utilize plants such as soy as the
main ingredients of their products, the newest biotechnological innovations facilitate the
development of (b) fungus into meat-resembling alternatives made from so-called
mycoprotein (Quorn, n.d.; Godfray et al., 2019; Bashi et al., 2019).
Literature Review: Cultivated Meat                                                      17

Another approach to fill the gap between supply and demand within the protein industry
comprises the (c) processing of insects into various products such as insect flour, or meat
alternatives (Van Huis et al., 2013). While circa 80% of countries already consume insects
on a regular basis, consumer acceptance for this protein source remains hard to achieve
in the remaining countries (Van Huis et al., 2013).
The last alternative protein source and focus of the subsequent ecosystem mapping is (d)
cultivated meat. While cultivated meat consists of animal tissue identical to conventional
meat, its production does not require the raising and slaughtering of animals. Instead, it
comprises the extraction of a small number of cells from an animal through a biopsy under
anesthesia and the subsequent cultivation in a laboratory setting (Emery, 2018; Mosa
Meat, n.d.). Market leaders in the cultivated meat industry include Memphis Meats, Mosa
Meat, and BlueNalu.
Notably, meat has been the predominant source of protein consumed by developed
countries for several decades. Hence, consumers frequently use the terminologies of meat
and protein interchangeably. However, since the beginning of the 21 st century, the
perception of the meat industry has slowly transformed into the protein industry (Bashi
et al., 2019). For instance, according to a McKinsey & Company industry report, there
has been a sharp increase in the public's interest in animal protein alternatives. Further,
Bashi et al. (2019) have uncovered that the main drivers of changes in consumer behavior
are health and environmental concerns, as well as animal welfare.
To some, the connection between alternative proteins and reduced environmental impact
might not be straightforward. However, Professor Joseph Poore from Oxford University
conducted one of the most comprehensive studies on modern agriculture, which included
40,000 farms as well as 1,600 processors, packaging types, and retailers (Carrington,
2018). According to Carrington (2018), Poore concluded that "[a] vegan diet is probably
the single biggest way to reduce your impact on planet Earth, not just greenhouse gases,
but global acidification, eutrophication, land use, and water use."
Despite this, individuals such as Bill Gates (2013) are aware of the dilemma that we might
not be able to satisfy the increasing demand for meat, "[y]et we can't ask everyone to
become vegetarians." Hence, cultivated meat constitutes an alternative that satisfies the
same needs, while only using a fraction of the resources required in conventional meat
production. Consequently, Emery (2018) identified cultivated meat as a disruptive
technology with the potential to solve "one of the greatest challenges of the 21st century"
(p. 1). Namely, to feed the growing population's hunger for more meat with limited
resources.
Literature Review: Cultivated Meat                                                         18

While in this context, we will refer to the previously-mentioned protein source as
cultivated meat, industry experts also call it clean, in vitro, lab-grown, synthetic, or cell-
based meat (Lynch & Pierrehumbert, 2019).
The first-ever cultivated meat burger was revealed in 2013 by Mark Post, professor of
vascular physiology at Maastricht University. Mark Post also holds the position of CSO
of the Dutch company Mosa Meat, which has revolutionized the alternative protein
industry and inspired the rise of many more companies (Rodríguez Fernández, 2020).
Three years later, in early 2016, Memphis Meats introduced its first cultivated meatball.
Subsequently, in 2017 the world's first cultivated chicken and duck were showcased,
followed by Aleph farms who released their new-to-the-world cultivated steak in 2018
(Liberatore, 2016; CB Insights, 2019a; Rodríguez Fernández, 2020).
The technology behind such innovative products has been described by Mosa Meat (n.d.)
as follows: After the extraction of a few stem cells from the muscle of an animal (called
myosatellites hereafter), the myosatellites are placed in a medium containing nutrients
and naturally-occurring growth factors. These myosatellites then proliferate into trillions
of cells in a bioreactor. Finally, they merge to form larger muscle fibers, which can,
thereafter, be processed like conventional pieces of meat.
While this process is still costly and time-consuming, cultivated meat companies
continuously work hard to find scalable solutions for fast commercialization. However,
expensive ingredients, such as the fetal bovine serum (FBS), which constitutes a crucial
ingredient for some cell-cultivation technologies, have hindered the reduction of
production costs so far (CB Insights, 2019a).
Nevertheless, the promising potential of large-scale production of cultivated meat, to
replace factory farms and slaughterhouses, motivates researchers to continue searching
for solutions for the common obstacles (CB Insights, 2019a). Additionally, cultivated
meat is superior to its plant-based competitors in several domains, such as digestibility,
amino acid balance, and taste (Appendix E). Further, genetic engineering allows for
enhancements and adaptions of the nutritional benefits of cultivated meat, compared to
conventional meat (Bashi et al., 2019). Finally, compared to traditional meat, cultivated
meat can be produced more efficiently. For instance, it takes a farmer seven weeks to
raise 20,000 chickens, while cell-cultivation technologies allow the cultivation of a
million times as much chicken meat over the same time (Emery, 2018).
Literature Review: Cultivated Meat                                                       19

3.2     Triple Bottom Line Evaluation

After the delineation of the history of the cultivated meat industry, we will take a triple
bottom line approach to evaluate the overall impact of this nascent technology, as well as
its future potential. For this purpose, we conducted a spotlight analysis of the (a)
economic, (b) societal, and (c) environmental impact of cultivated meat, as depicted in
Figure 1 below.

Figure 1: The Triple Bottom Line Framework

Source: Own adaptation based on the concept of Elkington, 1994

Firstly, from an (a) economic standpoint, cultivated meat aims to compete with the global
conventional meat industry. Noteworthily, cultivated meat has not yet been
commercialized. Therefore, retail profits are not subject of analysis. Instead, the most
crucial factors are costs, efficiency, and time to market. For the future,
MarketsandMarkets (2019) predict that the cultivated meat market will be valued at $214
million by 2025, reaching $593 million by 2032. With this being only a small fraction of
the aforementioned $1.7 trillion valuation of the meat market, it is open for interpretation
whether this number is satisfactory under consideration of population growth and
resource scarcity (Bashi et al., 2019).
Moreover, cultivated meat has not yet achieved cost- and price-parity with conventional
meat or plant-based meat. For example, according to McKinsey & Company, the current
cost of producing cultivated meat, measured by $/kg of 100% protein, is $300 compared
to $2/kg of 100% soy protein (Bashi et al., 2019). However, according to historical data,
there is reason to believe that achieving price-parity is realistic in the near future. For
You can also read