Occupational Hazards for Drivers in Colombia's Illegal Ride-hailing Economy

Page created by Terrence Cross
 
CONTINUE READING
Occupational Hazards for Drivers in Colombia's Illegal Ride-hailing Economy
Occupational Hazards for Drivers in
Colombia’s Illegal Ride-hailing Economy
Employment on the edge of criminality and informality

MASTER INTERNATIONAL RELATIONS THESIS

Twan Leo Jan Hol
Master Thesis
MA International Relations (2018/2019)
Leiden University
Supervisor:            Dr. H.A.S. Solheim
Wordcount:             16.474 (max. 13.500-16.500)
02-07-2020
Table of contents
INTRODUCTION: THE RISKS OF RIDE-HAILING IN BOGOTÁ ............................................................................... 3
1. MITIGATION OF RISK IN THE RIDE-HAILING SECTOR: A THEORETIC APPROACH ............................................ 6
   1.1 RIDE-HAILING AS A COMBINATION OF OLD IDEAS AND NEW TECHNOLOGY ...................................................................... 6
   1.2 CHOICE-MAKING: A THIN LINE BETWEEN ACCEPTED RISKS AND AVAILABLE ALTERNATIVES .................................................. 9
   1.2.1 VARYING PRACTICES OF DETERRENCE................................................................................................................. 11
   1.3 OCCUPATIONAL RISKS IN ILLEGAL SECTORS............................................................................................................. 12
2. THE RAPID EXPANSION OF RIDE-HAILING IN LATIN AMERICA (2013-PRESENT)........................................... 17
   2.1 LATIN AMERICA AS A FERTILE GROUND FOR RIDE-HAILING COMPANIES ........................................................................ 17
   2.2 RIDE-HAILING AND REGULATION, FROM RELIEF TO THREAT ....................................................................................... 19
   2.3 UBER AS A SHACKLE IN THE COLOMBIAN CHAIN OF INFORMALITY ............................................................................... 22
3. RIDE-HAILING IN BOGOTA: AN ANALYTICAL APPROACH ............................................................................... 26
   3.1 PERCEPTION OF RISKS BY DRIVERS ........................................................................................................................ 26
   3.2 AVOIDANCE TECHNIQUES AND PASSENGER INTERACTION IN PRACTICE ......................................................................... 29
   3.3 FUTURE FOR RIDE-HAILING IN COLOMBIA .............................................................................................................. 31
CONCLUSION .................................................................................................................................................. 35
BIBLIOGRAPHY ............................................................................................................................................... 38
LIST OF INTERVIEWEES ................................................................................................................................... 45

Cover photo: Gold, 2016.

                                                                                                                                                               2
Introduction: The risks of ride-hailing in Bogotá
Ride-hailing multinational Uber withdrew their operations from Colombia on the 31st of January 2020
after turbulent years of rapid growth and a fierce public debate (Eltiempo.com, 2020). While some
applauded the exit of the ‘disruptive’ platform, others, depending on the platform as a way to generate
income, mourned the retreat of the platform, that was preceded by a strong campaign against the new
practice of ride-hailing (Revista Semana, 2019; NotiPress, 2020; Morales, 2020).
         The rise of innovative online marketplaces and technologies during the past decade has
transformed various sectors of the economy globally. Meanwhile, small, innovative start-ups have
grown to become multinationals. The global ride-hailing platform Uber, expanded rapidly by matching
demand and supply for transport in private passenger cars through its platform that can be accessed
through any smartphone with an internet connection (Oviedo, Granada, & Perez-Jaramillo, 2020; Uber
Estimator, 2020). It’s plain business model made expansion easy and generated a stream of protests
among agents that call it disruptive for traditional transport systems, leading to confrontations
between taxi- and ride-hailing drivers (Moed, 2018b; Revista Semana, 2019; Pulzo, 2017).
         In many parts of Latin America and the world, regulation or prohibition of ride-hailing has been
put into place after pressure from protests, including roadblocks and violence against suspected ride-
hailing drivers, reportedly by taxi drivers (CBS News, 2015; Charbell, 2019; Colprensa, 2020; Conn,
2018; Ruvolo, 2015). Taxi drivers, supported by academic research, argue that Uber’s arrival to
Colombia, has decreased their income due to unfair competition, as taxi drivers have financial
obligations that are non-existent in the platform industry (Berger, Chen, & Frey, 2018; Revista Semana,
2019).
         While indicating a concern for the lack of protection for workers in new forms of employment
created by digitalization, Behrendt et al. underwrite the effects of the existence of these new forms of
employment, such as the undermining of fair competition for enterprises. They argue that the
problems and circumstances of these workers overlap with the larger challenge of informality (2019,
pp. 19, 15). Likewise, one of the motives for lawmakers to combat informal economies derives from
the idea that illegal or informal activities damage businesses that adhere to law, creating price
distortions and causing non-optimal investments for these businesses (Zelekha, 2011, p. 194)
         While other countries have attempted to control the ride-hailing sector through regulation,
the government of Colombian president Iván Duque started a campaign against illegality in the
transporting sector in 2018, in an attempt to desist the drivers of ride-hailing platforms (Ministerio de
Transporte, 2018a; Ministerio de Transporte, 2018b). In the span of approximately two years, the
Bogota police registered more than 20.000 penalizations to drivers of illegal platforms, while the
number of drivers using the two biggest ride-hailing platforms, Uber and Beat, was estimated to be
respectively 88.000 and 50.000 around the country (Castilla, 2019; Secretaría Distrital de Movilidad,

                                                                                                       3
2018). The fine is set at the worth of a minimum wage (828.100 Colombian Pesos), next to a suspension
of the drivers’ license for six months (dinero.com, 2019; Castilla, 2019; El Mundo, 2019).
        It appears that these efforts, in combination with the reported aggressions from taxi drivers,
have made driving for ride-hailing platforms a rather risky occupation in Colombia, leaving the question
as to why and how workers continue driving for ride-hailing platforms. A relevant question, as the goal
of the Colombian government is to desist the illegal drivers. An investigation into their motives and
decision-making process may provide insights into how and why drivers end up working for illegal
ridesharing platforms and may provide an opportunity to map underlying structures and factors
leading to their decision. These insights might be applicable to more sectors within the informal, illegal
and platform economy by lawmakers.
        Academics, such as Viscusi and Tremblay & Pare, have aimed to explain the decision-making
process of workers in illegal activities by comparing it to the decision-making process of workers in
hazardous environments, building on the economic model of crime (1986; 2003). Here, the decision
making process is seen as an equation of, on the one hand, profits from crime and on the other hand
the perceived risk of an activity (Becker, 1968; Allen, 2005). Following on this, avoidance techniques,
or restrictive deterrence, appear in research as tactics that criminals or workers in hazardous
environments apply to mitigate risk, enabling workers to continue their activities (Jacobs, 1996, p. 83).
        This thesis will research the perceived occupational hazards of ride-hailing platforms’ drivers.
It is expected that the research will fill the existent gap in the literature regarding the weak
understanding of occupational hazards for informal workers and to contribute to the growing
academic interest among international organizations and scholars into the working conditions of
workers in new forms of employment (Loewenson, 2002, p. 329; Behrendt, 2019; ILO I. L., 2018).
        The research question that forms the starting point of this thesis is formulated as follows:

        ,,How do ride-hailing platform drivers in Bogotá apply risk-avoidance techniques in their
        decision-making process regarding (non) desistance from their activities?”

The research of this thesis is executed through semi-structured interviews with 9 ride-hailing drivers,
in order to be able to gather qualitative information on the matter. These drivers have been selected
in the field, by ordering a ride through the platform of Uber (6) and Beat (3) in Bogota. Insights deriving
from the interviews have been complemented by observations in the field to be able to construct an
anthropological analysis. Next to research in the field, the method consists of a discourse analysis
regarding risks and desistance of drivers in Bogota and Colombia.
        The semi-structured interviews have been conducted in an informal setting and have been
structured to address, first, the risks that the drivers perceive, followed by strategies the drivers apply
to mitigate these risks and lastly by touching upon the importance of their occupation, taking into

                                                                                                         4
account their socio-economic circumstances. The informal semi-structured character of the interviews
allows for collecting other relevant information on the daily practices of the work in order to place the
avoidance techniques into their right context and collecting information that has not been anticipated
before. The discourse analysis is used to triangulate insights deriving from the interviews and
observations in the field.
        First, a chapter will be dedicated to theory regarding the research subject. The first part
evaluates the concept of ride-hailing, followed by a section that sets forth the economic model of
crime, while the last section provides a taxonomy of occupational risks. The second chapter is aimed
at providing a regional context. It addresses the rise of ride-hailing platforms in Latin America, different
regional approaches to regulation of the phenomenon and concludes with a brief overview of sectors
and platforms that share similarities with the ride-hailing industry in Bogota. The analysis is structured
in a way that it first addresses the socio-economic environment of respondents and its impact on their
motives for (non)desistance, followed by an analysis of the observed application of avoidance
techniques. Lastly, a discourse analysis provides insight into desistance of drivers in the absence of
Uber in Colombia. As usual, this work is concluded by a discussion and conclusion.

                                                                                                          5
1. Mitigation of risk in the ride-hailing sector: a theoretic approach
In this chapter, a theoretical framework is built in order to provide the remainder of the thesis with
relevant concepts, theories and earlier academic work related to the research question of this thesis.
Furthermore, this chapter gives an opportunity to establish which theoretic perspective to follow and
which terminology of important concepts is used in the remainder of this thesis, next to stating the
state of the art within the academic field.
        The chapter is divided into three sections. First of all, the concept of ride-hailing will be
discussed within the larger picture of the platform economy, addressing the emerging body of
academic literature that has been written regarding these concepts. Consequently, the economic
model of crime and theories surrounding deterrence from crime and avoidance will be explained. The
third section consists of a short taxonomy of occupational hazards and its occurrence in different
academic fields. This chapter will be concluded by addressing some insights deriving from the theory
and by formulating some hypothesis regarding the research question and literature.

1.1 Ride-hailing as a combination of old ideas and new technology
In 1975 Martin Wohl made the case for taxicabs as the most efficient form of public transport,
establishing that the taxi industry, despite of heavy limitations and regulations concerning fares,
licensing and operations, was the only branch of public transport that could operate without public
funding, while creating vast employment opportunities for lower skilled workers. Wohl envisioned that
the future of solutions to public transport problems would lie in offering transport outside of designed
routes and schedules, providing transport by cabs that could be hailed on demand in every street
segment in cities and suburbs at any time. A reality that was put into practice over 30 years later by
online platforms that match labour and demand within a geographical location in the form of ride. This
practice is also known as ride-hailing or ride-sharing (Wohl, 1975, pp. 150, 151; Contreras & Paz, 2018,
p. 65; Feeney, 2015).
        Ride-hailing is a label for work on demand applications that deliver transportation (Behrendt,
2019, p. 18; Chen, 2018, p. 2691. 2692). In a more practical definition, the Associated Press Stylebook
defines ride-hailing services as services that “let people use smartphone apps to book and pay for a
car service or, in some cases, a taxi” (APStylebook, 2018). What, according to Rayle et al., sets ride-
hailing apart from similar and, in some cases, older forms of transport, such as app-based taxi hailing
and app-enabled carpooling, is the combination of GPS-enabled smartphone technology and the
absence of traditional taxi-regulations (2016, p. 169). However, what exactly entails ride-hailing and
how it should be conceptualized, is still subject of discussion, especially with regard to terminology.
While some scholars use the term ride-sharing and place the concept within the framework of the
sharing economy, others resist this term, stating it is merely a term invented by the companies out of
marketing concerns, which misleads the public perception, as the practice of ride-hailing does not

                                                                                                      6
necessarily require two passengers or more and often includes just one passenger, while ride-sharing,
a term that was initially used in academic papers, implies that vehicles used for a trip are in theory
shared by two or more passengers (Henao & Marshall, 2019, p. 2175). Other terms that have been
used to refer to ride-hailing (companies) include Transportation Network Companies (TNCs), ride-
hailing, ridesourcing, ride-booking, ridematching, on-demand-rides, and app-based rides.
        According the Henao and Marshall, not all these terms are to be used interchangeably. The
term TNC is mostly used by lawmakers to refer to the companies, while ridesourcing is a merely
academic term (Henao & Marshall, 2019, p. 2175; Dias, et al., 2017, p. 1308). The debate concerning
the terminology of the phenomenon has not been limited to the domain of scholars. Correspondingly,
journalists and The Associated Press Stylebook have engaged in the discussion and prescribe that the
accurate term for the practice should either be ride-hailing or ride-booking services, meanwhile
discouraging the use of the word ride-sharing, which implies a general consensus on the non-use of
the latter (Warzel, 2015). To join this consensus and incorporate the term that has recently been more
prominently used in news outlets and academic works, this thesis will qualify the in this section
described practice as “ride-hailing” for the remainder of this work.
        Ride-hailing, however, is not a lonely wolf in itself within the academic field. De Stefano
categorizes ride-hailing as a sub-category of platform work, a generic term for multiple services that
make use of an online platform (De Stefano, 2016, pp. 2, 3). Numerous differences can be identified
between the existent platforms, based on its purpose and, for example, the way in which people work.
The two main categories can be defined on the basis of the kind of labour they provide. The first
category is made up of online labour platforms that provide crowdwork. Crowdwork mostly consists
of work that can be done online and from distance, such as the moderation, translation and
transcription of online content and sometimes involves transferring work that traditionally has been
done offline, but is done now online. The second category consist of work on demand platforms. Here,
work demand and supply are arranged through online applications, while the labour is delivered
physically, mostly in a geographically predetermined area. Ride-hailing apps are examples of such a
labour platform, while work on demand platforms include apps that provide different kinds of labour,
such as meal delivery (De Stefano, 2016, pp. 2,3; ILO, 2018, p. 1). As Scholz argues throughout his book
‘Uberworked and underpaid’, ride-hailing workers often face uncertain costumer demand and low
earnings, while it is often seen as an opportunity to earn money for people with limited access to
formal labour markets. The rise of these forms of labour in economies with a large share of illegality in
the economy, is often linked to bigger problems of informality that exist within society (Scholz, 2017;
Behrendt, 2019, p. 21). While Ticona & Mateescu agree with Scholz that platform work in some sectors,
such as transport, cause the informalization of labour, they disagree that platform work in any sector

                                                                                                       7
entails this effect. In sectors where already a large part of the workforce is employed informally, it
could even have the opposite effect, it is argued (Ticona & Mateescu, 2018, pp. 2691-2693).
        The principal exploratory academic works and researches on ride-hailing services have mainly
focused on the traits of ride-hailing services in respect to the service of taxicabs or demographic data
regarding its users, finding that users of ride-hailing apps are, in comparison to taxi-users, higher
educated, younger males that come from house-holds without car ownership. It is theorized that this
is mainly due to the fact that young individuals are more aware about technological developments and
more open to use new technologies and services in comparison to their older peers, while they also
have the ability to make use of them. At the same time, Dias et al. expect ageing populations to be
increasingly prone to use these new services as their ability to drive deteriorates (Rayle, et al., 2016,
p. 172; Dias, et al., 2017, pp. 1310, 1315). Furthermore, Rayle et al. suggest that, while sharing a large
part of its user base, the services of taxis and ride-hailing apps do not overlap as much as popular
media make it seem. Indeed, competition between the two kind of services exists, but, according to
these scholars, a large part of the user base of ride-hailing apps would not have made the same ride
by taxi, which suggests that ride-hailing and taxi services do not completely serve the same market
demand (2016, 176, 177).
        Dias et al. have, like Henao & Marshall, investigated the way in which the availability of ride-
hailing services has, if it all, substituted already existing means of transport and the way it has
influenced car-ownership among urban citizens (Dias, et al., 2017; Henao & Marshall, 2019). In both
studies it is found that people without car ownership may substitute public transport, walking or biking
by using ride-hailing apps. Dias et al. implicate that ride-hailing therefore might be contra-productive
in avoiding congestion in densely populated areas. Henao & Marshall, on the other hand, theorize that
the implications of these finding are to be put into a long-term context: non-car owners may have
decided not to own a car partly due to the availability of ride-hailing services (2019, p. 2192). Rayle et
al. have investigated the rationale of users of ride-hailing services to use those services, finding that
convenience (ease of payment, waiting time and travel time) is one of the most common reasons to
use ride-hailing platforms, followed by practical issues, such as people not wanting to look for a parking
lot or not wanting to drink and drive. While it can be established that there is a clear picture of why
users (passengers) engage into ride-hailing-services, the motivation and reasons of drivers to engage
in the practice have been mostly ignored as a subject of study in recent literature. Unsurprisingly, the
effects of ride-hailing on drivers’ behaviour as a future topic of discussion has been put forward (2016,
177).
        Meanwhile, the amount of academic work on the implications of ride-hailing services on
various aspects of daily life, other than public transportation, has increased. Berger theorizes that ride-
hailing services like Uber may transform medical emergency transportation, as far as they have not

                                                                                                         8
done so yet, as people may make use of, often faster and cheaper, ride-hailing services instead of an
ambulance in situations of medical emergency (Berger E. , 2017, pp. 15-17). Another important aspect
of the academic body regarding ride-hailing services and the broader issue of platform economy
addresses labour regulatory challenges when it comes to the nature of the contract between people
delivering the ride-hailing services and the platforms connecting them with costumers (Zou, 2017).

1.2 Choice-making: a thin line between accepted risks and available alternatives
One of the most used concepts in relation to policies that aim to prevent individuals in society to
commit a crime or partake in illegal activities is deterrence. The traditional view on deterrence has
been one that links deterrence closely to punishment. In this theory, punishment is aimed at criminals,
or perpetrators of illegal acts, to deter them from repeating a certain crime or illegal act, as well as
preventing others to commit similar acts (Law & Martin, 2009). Gary Becker is one of the founders of
the rational-choice theory of crime or economic model of crime and has further developed the ideas
surrounding the concept of deterrence (1968). Becker focused on an economic analysis of the levels
of punishment and allocation of government resources into policies to combat illegal behaviour. He
interprets the optimal decision that criminals make to partake in illegal activities as being a
consideration that minimizes the risk of losing capital during illegal activities. Those losses could, for
example, be seen in the form of the risk of material damage, the possibility to be apprehended and
the related cost of conviction, including carrying out the related punishment (Becker, 1968, p. 207).
This model would indicate that higher punishment increases crime risks and thus would make crime
less attractive, leading to a lower crime rate, while the higher the expected payoff, the bigger the
probability of participation in crime (Rauhut & Junker, 2009, pp. 1,2; Harbaugh, Mocan, & Visser, 2013,
pp. 389, 390).
        According to Allen, however, the economic model of crime and the decision-making of
potential criminals include, apart from an economic view, more factors, such as ‘human capital skills,
the availability of legitimate activity, preferences for risk, the potential sanction and the probability of
detection’, while he also mentions the social content of crime that forms part of this model. He
theorizes that people living in a culture that encourages crime might be more likely to engage into
crime, whereas in other societies there might be a higher social cost attached for people to engage in
crime or being openly linked to certain forms of illegal activity (Allen, 2005, pp. 494, 495). Also, Viscusi
recognizes the availability of a legitimate job alternative as a factor within the economic decision-
making process of potential criminals (1986, p. 319):
        “The primary matter of concern to the potential criminal is not the crime risk per se but whether
        the frontier of criminal rewards-crime risks offers a crime option that is superior to his
        legitimate job alternative.” (Viscusi, 1986, p. 319)

                                                                                                          9
Sometimes this legitimate job alternative might not be existent. Research embedded in the economic
model of crime suggests that circumstances as high unemployment rates, poverty and problems in the
labour market prompts illegal activity and crime, as the illegal activity delivers more reward than the
legal, unemployed, alternative (Garcia, Rodriguez, & Parra, 2011, p. 113). Thus, one could argue that a
legal alternative income could be a deterring factor for people to commit illegal acts.
        Mocan & Unel have further developed the economic model of crime in relation to legal labour
market opportunities, taking into account income inequality and changes in wage versus crime rates.
While the empirical difficulty to establish causal relations between (the height or absence of) wages
and crime participation, because of the questionable exogeneity and the existence of other lesser
apparent factors that might partly determine a perpetrators likelihood to participate in illegal
activities, has impaired evidence of the correlation between wages and criminal activity, Mocan & Unel
have conducted research that connects the impact of unskilled workers’ wages on crime, based on the
economic model of crime (2017, pp. 3-6). Their research suggests that the impact of wages, thus
variations on and availability of wages in legal labour markets, have a greater impact on criminal
activity than recognized before. Their results imply that variations and legal alternatives to work should
be of public policy concern when it comes to crime control and desistance of illegal activities and
provide a foundation for future research on this topic (Mocan & Unel, 2017, p. 43).
        Still, the above-mentioned findings give room for theories that reverse the causal relation
between crime and legal market opportunities. As argued by Albrecht, Navarro and Vroman,
disqualifications for participation in the legal labour market, as a consequence of labour market
policies, oblige workers, with for instance physical disabilities or a criminal record, to take part in the
informal or illegal sector. Leaving individuals with no other choice than executing activities outside of
the formal sector (Albrecht, Navarro, & Vroman, 2009, p. 1106; Thoene, 2015, p. 21).
        A poor future perspective in the labour market could thus be the consequence of, as well as
the cause for, undertaking criminal activities. The theory put forward in this work is that for some
individuals, the decision to participate in illegal activities is only to a certain extent a matter of choice,
as they are excluded from most of the legal labour market. One of the determining factors that can
lead to an individual to be excluded from legal alternatives is an individual’s level of human capital,
based on the relative productivity of a worker (Mondragon Velez & Peña Vargas, 2008, p. 4) As a
consequence, Albrecht, Navarro & Vroman theorize, higher skilled workers are found in the formal
sector and unskilled workers are mostly present in the informal or illegal economy (2009, p. 1106).
        Extending the importance of providing legal labour alternatives outside of the domain of crime
control, Thoene theorizes that the mechanisms that exclude workers from formal employment have
more implications than solely depriving these people of decent income and insurance against life risks.
Ignoring the skills and capacities of parts of societies, mostly the more deprived sectors, undermines

                                                                                                           10
the formation of democratic political structures. Those structures are used to advance citizenship
rights and economic opportunities in a more inclusive way for society (2015, p. 13).
        Labour markets are, thus, one of the principal components to create an inclusive and
participatory society in which people enjoy more inclusive rights, aimed at socio-economic equality. In
order to be able to contribute to a reduction in poverty, labour markets should be providing not only
more formal jobs, but also of better quality, so that social rights are guaranteed and the jobs will be a
suitable alternative for unregulated jobs (Thoene, 2015, p. 14).

1.2.1 Varying practices of deterrence
Within the same framework of the economic model of crime, scholars have theorized on the possible
ways that criminals deter from illegal activities. They take into account the same equation which makes
up the assessment and possible decision to deter from crime, with on one side the perceived chance
of being apprehended multiplied by the perceived scale of punishment and on the other end the
expected gains deriving from illegal activities. The outcome of this equation, however, is not limited to
two outcomes (deter or not deter), but may develop gradually (Jacobs, 1996, pp. 361, 362; Paternoster,
1987, p. 174).
        Before we explore these different forms of deterrence, first of all, we need to understand why
offenders might come to different outcomes when making up this equation. One of the explanations
can be found in the work of Paternoster and Piquero (1995). According to them, (potential) offenders
create a perception on the probability of being apprehended. This use of perception implies that
criminals value risks differently. In theory, there exist two distinctive ways of perceiving apprehension
and punishment risks. One is called general deterrence, which is caused through circulating reports or
other accounts of people being apprehended for a certain illegal activity. The other one is called
specific deterrence, depicting the perceived probability of being apprehended and the consequences
thereof by means of one’s own experience (Paternoster & Piquero, 1995, pp. 251, 252).
        According to Jacobs, the shortcoming of this division is, amongst others, the fact that for this
theory to hold, a punishment must have had taken place in order for deterrence to take place. Related
to this, Jacobs argues that there are mechanisms in place in which the opposite holds. Subjects that
succeed repeatedly in their efforts to execute illegal activities may lower their perceived chances of
apprehension and of those who hear about these ‘successes’ and might even increase them (Jacobs,
1996, p. 362).
        As stated before, some offenders may decide to not completely deter, nor continue their
activities as they have done before, acting in accordance to a principle called restrictive deterrence.
While multiple definitions of this concept are in use, Jacobs’ qualification may be most useful. He
divides restrictive deterrence into two categories, of which one, probabilistic deterrence, has already
been mentioned in 1975 by Gibbs. He stated that some violators may restrict their illegal activities in

                                                                                                      11
the belief that repeating them will eventually lead to apprehension, which implies that the perpetrator
perceives their activity as risky (Gibbs, 1975, p. 33; Jacobs, 1996, p. 372).
        This is just one side of restrictive deterrence Jacobs suggests. While probabilistic restrictive
deterrence, is, thus, based on reducing the frequency of a violation, particularistic deterrence entails
“a reduction in offense frequencies based on tactical skills used by offenders to make their crimes less
detectable and reducing their chances for apprehension” (Jacobs, 1996, p. 376).
        When it comes to these tactics, Jacobs further makes distinctions in reactive (RRD) and
anticipatory restrictive deterrence (ARD) (1996, p. 377; Moeller, Copes, & Hochstetler, 2016, p. 83).
The former meaning that perpetrators develop strategies or techniques to identify officials or people
they suspect to be officials and how to avoid apprehension in the case they come into contact with
them. Anticipatory tactics are aimed at avoiding contact with agents, by making decisions regarding
the area wherein and the hours in which they commit illegal acts. Another example of ARP is trying to
blend into the public by obeying to traffic laws, thus not catching the attention of officers. The above
mentioned tactics are also known as ‘avoidance techniques’ (Jacobs, 1996, p. 83; Moeller, Copes, &
Hochstetler, 2016, pp. 86-87).

1.3 Occupational risks in illegal sectors
In the previous section, theories and concepts have been discussed in order to understand the
considerations and mechanisms surrounding deterrence and the ways in which deterrence takes place,
based on the equation of risks versus gains. So far, theories regarding sources of risk attributed to the
execution of illegal activities, have remained mostly unaddressed. This thesis will explain these risks
from the perspective of occupational hazards.
        According to the taxonomy of occupational hazard by Cabeças, an occupational hazard, also
labelled ‘occupational risk’, needs to involve two elements; first, a hazard or risk factor needs to be
present. In this sense, a hazard is understood by a ‘source or situation with a potential for harm in
terms of death, ill health or injury, or a combination of these’ (Cabeças, 2015, p. 703). Thus, a hazard
does not necessarily take place, but merely presents the probability of an incident happening.
Secondly, a relation between the hazard and the occupation of the subject or group of subjects who
are at risk needs to be established. According to Cabeças, this is not necessarily a causal relation.
Regarding, for example, the classification for occupational hazards related to diseases, he identifies
three different categories, differentiated by the nature of the relation between an occupation and
hazards. The first category consist of so-called occupational diseases, which have a direct and
recognized causal relation to the occupation of an individual. Secondly, work-related diseases, are
diseases which do not have one single cause and which origin may involve other risks outside of the
occupational domain. Lastly, diseases affecting working populations, are diseases that are not caused

                                                                                                      12
within the occupational domain, but diseases which symptoms are aggravated by hazards present
within the working environment of individuals (Cabeças, 2015, p. 703).
        As put forward, however, occupational hazards are not limited to diseases only. For example,
other possible hazards, as apparent in the taxonomy of Cabeças, consist of the potential for a work-
related accident to happen, leading to an occupational injury, and ‘emerging occupational hazards’, a
heterogenous group of newly discovered hazards that may affect not only people, but property as well.
The European Agency for Safety and Health at Work, requires emerging hazards, next to being newly
discovered, to be increasing in probability of occurrence (Cabeças, 2015, p. 704).
        As pointed out, occupational hazards have traditionally been interpreted as mostly a physical
phenomenon, in the form of work-related illnesses, accidents and deaths (Webster Dictionary, 2019;
Giuffrida, 2002, p. 235). More recently, occupational hazards as a concept has been taken out of solely
the field of occupational health and into other fields, amongst which are environmental studies and
economics. This, subsequently, broadened the view of what can be regarded an occupational hazard.
Any personal damage that could be inflicted into someone which originates from someone´s
profession could be considered an occupational risk or hazard. This results in including within the
concept of occupational hazards instances of, for example, mental health issues and sexual harassment
in working environments, next to traditional medical conditions (Giuffrida, 2002, pp. 235-237).
        As the range of different occupational hazards identified by theory and research is not limited,
but merely emerging, based on the nature of what can be considered risks, so is the concept
occupational hazards not limited to solely occupations in the formal branches of the economy. The
sex industry is one of the more unconventional industries that have been under the attention of
scholars in the field of occupational health. Popoola and Izugbara, for example, investigated the
occupational hazards of sex workers in Nigeria, where such work is illegal (Izugbara, 2005; Popoola,
2013). Their investigations provided relevant insights and grounds for future research regarding
occupational hazards in illegal activities, by finding that, unlike concerns arising from governments, the
public and earlier academic work, not diseases (STD’s) were perceived as the biggest occupational
hazard by the sex workers themselves, but police harassment, stigmatization and police/client violence
were found to be the main hazard related to their occupation (Popoola, 2013, p. 145; Izugbara, 2005).
        Popoola theorizes that this discrepancy might occur, because the latter incidents cause direct
effects on their income and ability to continue their work. The findings imply that while government
bodies are ought to put into place legislation to diminish occupational hazards and increase
occupational health, legislation and policing might have an opposite effect. Therefore, it is argued that
occupational hazards could be addressed by legislation aimed at the economic empowerment of
people working in these branches of economy. This could be done by addressing broader structures in
society and combatting the circumstances, such as poverty and under-education, that initially led

                                                                                                       13
individuals to engage into illegal activities as the last-resort to be able to generate a viable source of
income (UNAIDS, 2006; Popoola, 2013, p. 147).
        Regarding illegal work, Viscusi identified parallels between crime risks, i.e. the risk that
criminals get apprehended or experience any other kind of physical or economic damage while carrying
out illegal activities, and occupational risks (Viscusi, 1986, pp. 317, 318). In this interpretation,
executing illegal economic activity (crime) is seen as an occupation, hence its attributed risks are
occupational. Tremblay and Pare have gone further to elaborate this theoretical line, discussing an
occupational hazard-model of crime risk for heavy criminal offenders, using the death rate among
criminals as an indicator. According to this model, offenders experience a higher mortality rate because
of a higher exposure to conflicts. This exposure to conflicts is explained by stating that offenders form
a prominent target, especially for other offenders, as they fight over the same scarce resources.
Furthermore, they are targeted as incapacitation objectives by victims of their crimes and law
enforcement officers (Tremblay & Pare, 2003, pp. 299-308).
        An interesting finding, highlighted by Tremblay and Pare, is that offenders attempted to
control their risks by adopting victimization and apprehension avoidance techniques. This suggestion
is supported by the observation that young offenders, as their perception of risk is lower, increasingly
engage into more risky activities, with higher returns and higher victimization hazards. Their death rate
does, however, decrease over time, suggesting they apply techniques to avoid these crime-related
occupational hazards as they get more experienced and aware of hazard attributed to their activities.
The techniques applied by offenders in order to limit occupational hazards have been discussed in the
previous section within the concept of restrictive deterrence (Tremblay & Pare, 2003, pp. 299, 307,
308). How people respond to hazards they face carrying out their activities may, however, differ
depending on one’s characteristics and conditions. People that already suffer from a disease may, for
example, respond different to a certain hazard then their colleagues, when they consider the
consequences of a hazard to be larger for them (Cabeças, 2015, p. 704). Other groups of workers might
be incapable of coping with the hazards faced in their occupation and cope with this situation through
endurance, accepting the hazards as normal consequences of their work, or apply other ineffective
strategies as a response to perceived hazards (Popoola, 2013, p. 146).
        In the same line Giuffrida et al. argue that poor working conditions in a current occupation and
potential alternative jobs, in combination with the lack of social security and insurance, makes that
workers may tolerate working conditions with a higher potential for occupational hazards to occur.
The reason being, that those (illegal) workers experience the condition in which losing their job would
mean losing their main, often only, source of income, while a safer working environment that could
substitute their current occupation is not within their reach (2002, p. 236; Popoola, 2013, p. 140). As a

                                                                                                       14
result, according to Giuffrida et al., occupational risks are likely bigger in small enterprises and
economies with a low level of labour unions rights (2002, pp. 235-237).

Conclusion
This chapter has provided the theoretical foundation of this thesis. When it comes to ride-hailing, it is
established that the first ideas regarding the concept were found in literature concerning taxicabs
(Wohl, 1975). It is shown however, that ride-hailing serves a largely different public and its use includes
implications that go beyond public transportation (Berger E. , 2017; Rayle, et al., 2016). In contrary to
its users, little is known when it comes to the demography of its drivers and their motivations to work
in the newly emerged ride-hailing industry, while it is argued that the problems surrounding their
labour are closely linked to those of people working in the informal economy (Behrendt, 2019).
        The economic model of crime, developed by Becker, suggests that criminals weigh out profits
of crime versus its risks in order to decide whether to continue their activities (1968). These risks are
addressed through the perspective of occupational hazards, as it is shown that the body of literature
regarding occupational health has grown to include less conventional occupations and more hazards
that are not solely physical (Giuffrida, 2002; Cabeças, 2015). As criminal’s intent to decrease risks of
apprehension, policing is regarded as an occupational health within illegal occupations (Popoola, 2013;
Jacobs, 1996). Like workers in hazardous circumstances, criminals can partly deter, both concerning
the frequency of their actions, but also in the way they operate (Gibbs, 1975). Literature in both
occupational health and crime deterrence show, that when individuals cannot find a viable alternative
they may continue their activities and sometimes apply ineffective techniques to improve their
circumstances (Cabeças, 2015; Popoola, 2013). Furthermore individuals may perceive hazards on the
basis of their own experience or on the basis of others’ experience, while the way they process these
hazards can differ based on ones characteristics and circumstances, such as health or pre-existing
diseases (Cabeças, 2015; Popoola, 2013).
        Based on the above we can expect that law enforcement will have a smaller effect on the
occupational hazard perception within the decision-making process of the ride-hailing workers than
might be expected. This, because a formal or legal alternative is, in theory, considered to be an
important factor for both criminals and workers in hazardous occupations. At the same time, policing
will probably be one of the most visible, direct, occupational hazards for ride-hailing workers, which is
thus expected to be a hazard that requires avoidance techniques to overcome (Rauhut & Junker, 2009;
Becker, 1968; Giuffrida, 2002; Popoola, 2013).
        In short, whether ride-hailing workers will put into place techniques to avoid the risks
attributed to their activities will depend on the way they perceive risks, the way in which these risks
have been put in place and the socio-economic status of these workers. Their decision is influenced by
possible viable alternatives that are at hand based on, amongst others, personal capital and

                                                                                                        15
possibilities in the labour market. Therefore, in the next chapter, not only the rise of ride-hailing
platforms in Latin America will be addressed, but also the way in which governments have formed
regulations regarding ride-hailing and the state of the Colombian labour market will be analysed.

                                                                                                    16
2. The rapid expansion of ride-hailing in Latin America (2013-present)
In the current chapter, the subject of this thesis will be contextualized. To achieve this end, the
development of ride-hailing platforms in Latin America and Colombia will be viewed through a
historical and economic perspective, taking into account (inter)national and regional situations. As
established, ride-hailing is a relatively new phenomenon. Therefore, where necessary, the scope of
this chapter is extended to Latin America. Not only to fill gaps of information that is not available solely
on Bogotá nor Colombia, but also to give a broader perspective on the nature of the phenomenon and
the responses it has received. Regarding the historical scope of this chapter, the investigation will be
limited by taking the phenomenon of ride-hailing in Latin America into account from the year it was
first introduced in the region.
          The first part of this chapter will deal with a chronological account of the introduction,
geographical development and emergence of new(er) ride-hailing platforms in Colombia and Latin
America. Consequently, the reception of the phenomenon by lawmakers and other stakeholders in
society is discussed. As stressed in the theoretical chapter, economic alternatives are an important
factor within the economic model of crime and desistance. Therefore, it is relevant to, ultimately,
contextualize the economic circumstances in which the ride-hailing industry is positioned in Colombia.
Thus, the last part of this chapter will consist of a brief contextualization of the Colombian labour
market and industries that are active in Colombia and share certain dynamics with the ride-hailing
sector.
          To sustain this chapter, next to academic literature, (government) reports and news articles
will be used.

2.1 Latin America as a fertile ground for ride-hailing companies
The phenomenon of ride-hailing reached Latin America in 2013 when Uber first launched in Mexico,
followed by Colombia in the same year. In 2014, Uber already expanded to Brazil, Peru and Chile, while
opening up multiple different other markets in the years to follow (Moed, 2018b; Lustig, 2018).
According to Oviedo, Granada & Perez-Jaramillo, Latin America has grown to be one of the core regions
of operation for Uber. As of 2020, Uber was active in 173 cities across South America and the
Caribbean, with an estimated 25 million monthly users in 15 countries (2020, pp. 1732, 1734; Salazar
Castellanos, 2019). According to Uber Estimator, a website that tracks the countries and cities where
Uber is active and gives an estimation of the local fares, the only countries in Latin or South America
where Uber is not currently active are Venezuela, Nicaragua, Belize, Cuba and the three Guyanas
(2020).
          Uber managed to get a tight grip on Latin America. This was not only because of the relative
proximity to Uber’s headquarters in the Unites States, which allowed for a more effective support
structure and efficient upscaling strategy, there might also be a cultural rationale. It is said that Latin

                                                                                                         17
American consumers and American consumers share similar technological consumer preferences,
while at the same time the high rate of access to smartphones plays a role (Amaral Haddad, et al.,
2019, pp. 1-3; Moed, 2018b). Whether or not these theories hold, the fact that 2 out of the 5 countries
that hold the most cities in which Uber offers its service are located in Latin America, shows the degree
to which Uber has been able to geographically expand in the region compared to other world regions.
In fact, Brazil (no. 2, 131 cities) and Mexico (nr. 3, 56 cities) allow only Uber’s home country, the United
States, a place before them on the ranking- and they rank even higher than a country like India (Uber
Estimator, 2020). The latter could be explained by the fact that in some regions of the world, domestic
ride-hailing platforms entered their respective markets before Uber could expand their operations to
these regions. In this way, Uber operates in more cities in Mexico than India, where the domestic
platform Ola has been able to obtain a significantly larger market share than in the US, Europe or Latin
America, making Uber a less dominant player (Moed, 2018b; Salazar Castellanos, 2019).
        In Latin America, however, Uber has not been the only player within the ride-hailing industry
offering their service (Lustig, 2018). In Colombia, for example, Uber, while remaining the market
leader, has been forced to share their market for over five years as new platforms emerged. In 2015,
Cabify and Picap, a Colombian application for ride-hailing with motorcycles, entered the market. In
2018, Indriver, Fory and Beat started operations, while more recently, the Chinese platform Didi
entered the Colombian ride-hailing market in 2019 (Patiño, El debate por la legalidad de Picap, la 'app'
de mototaxismo, 2019; Leal Acosta, 2019). A director of Beat has stated that the growth rate of the
amount of rides through his platform has been between 30% and 40% per month during the first half
of 2019, while according to the CEO of Didi, the Chinese platform reached 16.000 subscriptions of new
drivers in the first week after it started to operate in Colombia (Leal Acosta, 2019). While the absence
of public statistics makes it difficult to verify these statements, it seems evident that new players in
the Colombian ride-hailing sector have complacently been able to obtain a market share within the
Colombian ride-hailing industry.
        While academic articles that research the successful expansion of ride-hailing in Latin America
are non-existent, Oviedo, Granada & Perez-Jaramillo do identify two main grounds for the success of
the different ride-hailing platforms in the region. The first one being rooted in the perceived
comparative advantage of platforms over traditional taxi services by the population. Not only the fact
that the platforms deliver on time services that can be requested through a mobile phone are among
these advantages. The fact that the app provides its users with the opportunity to rate drivers and
users, as well as providing feedback for the improvement of its systems, are considered to be an
advantage compared to traditional modes of public transport. At the same time, the conditions of the
vehicles that are used by its drivers are often considered to be better than those of traditional taxis
(2020, pp. 1732-1733).

                                                                                                         18
Taking into account the large dependency the urban population in Latin America has developed on
different forms of public transport, it is not surprising that this population has been keen to try new or
improved forms of public transport (Lustig, 2018). Therefore, the conclusion of different media, which
states that ride-hailing has thrived in the region through a popular demand for safe public transport
alternatives to traditional public transport, seems plausible (Lustig, 2018; Moed, 2018b).
        An open and liberal market for public transportation in Latin America, with many small private
actors and limited regulation, could be one of the reasons that cause these systems to decay. Leading,
in turn, to a severely damaged public image. The Peruvian game ‘Crazy Combi’, a game that ridicules
the alleged reckless driving behaviour of drivers of combi buses, one of the most used modes of public
transport in the Peruvian capital Lima, illustrates this image (Harden, 2019; Moed, 2018b; Tegel, 2018).
Another example is the infamous ‘millionaire rides’, a number of infamous incidents in Colombia, in
which taxi passengers, after hailing a taxi on the street, are robbed from their money and valuables by
thieves, while often the taxi-driver is involved. In some cases, the victims are driven to an ATM to
empty their bank account, or coerced into handing over digital passwords. This practice gained
international attention in 2013, when an American DEA agent was killed in a millionaire ride, causing
severe damage to the reputation of the Bogota taxi industry and generating a response by then-
president Juan Manuel Santos (Moed, 2018b; Harden, 2019; Muse, 2013).
        The success of ride-hailing, however, is not to be entirely attributed to the state and image of
the taxi industry and other traditional modes of transport in the region. As put forward by Oviedo,
Granada & Perez-Jaramillo, another cause for the success of ride-hailing platforms in Latin America, is
to be sought in the economic environment of the region, combined to the adaptability of the platforms’
business design, giving not only Uber, other local and international ride-hailing platforms as well, room
to thrive. In addition to being helped by a fertile economic environment in the region which is
favourable to entrepreneurs and start-ups, the platforms, aided by data-driven innovations, have been
able to adapt its ways of operation to meet local requirements for operation (2020, p. 1733).
        At the same time, the high unemployment rates in the region, aggravated by an economic
downturn in 2018, made that there is a large, unemployed workforce available, willing to supply the
increasing demand of ride-hailing rides (Rapoza, 2019; Moed, 2018b; Defossez, 2017, p. 2).

2.2 Ride-hailing and regulation, from relief to threat
As demonstrated, Uber and other ride-hailing companies are active on nearly the entire region of Latin
America. Still, the vast majority of its one million daily users in the region make use of the platforms
illegally. For example, of all the countries in which it is active, Uber has only been legalized in Mexico
and Brazil, leading to different degrees of success (Haldevang, 2015; Benkoe, 2018; Moed, 2018b).
        While countries in Latin America have attracted vast amounts of investments from ride-hailing
platforms, governments on different scales have been increasingly careworn about the position of the

                                                                                                       19
platforms and their disruptiveness regarding existing mobility systems. Indeed, the expansion of Uber’s
businesses in Latin America has not been without its proper setbacks and difficulties. Since its arrival
to Latin America, protests have arisen, leading in nearly all countries to violent attacks of ride-hailing
drivers by taxi drivers, such as in Mexico, Colombia, Argentina and Brazil (Pulzo, 2017; Ruvolo, 2015;
Conn, 2018; CBS News, 2015). These attacks have mostly been executed by actors from the traditional
taxi industry and have even taken place in locations where the service is (partly) legalized (Oviedo,
Granada, & Perez-Jaramillo, 2020, p. 1733; Moed, 2018b). Different stakeholders in society pressured
local and national governments to revise and define the legal conditions of the platforms and the legal
protection of their workers in court. According to criticasters, there should be a better understanding
of the economic, social and environmental effects of the platforms’ operation before allowing them to
operate. Those alleged effects are, amongst others, the level of congestion in urban areas, an
alteration of the travel behaviour and mode choice pattern of passengers next to possible negative
effects on the financial sustainability of existing mobility systems. Additionally, as we have seen in the
previous chapter, effects on the size, composition and use of the local car fleet are named as possible
consequences of the arrival of ride-hailing platforms’ services (Oviedo, Granada, & Perez-Jaramillo,
2020, p. 1733).
        Thus, while the ride-hailing platform has not been legalized or formalized in many countries,
there are few countries in which Uber did not manage to enter at all. As mentioned before, Nicaragua
is one of the countries were Uber is not active, however, Uber did intend to enter the market of the
Central American country. According to reports, Uber undertook several attempts in 2017 and 2019,
however, those attempts were met with a gulf of violent protests, again driven by taxi drivers
(Nicaragua Investiga, 2020; Tijerino, 2019). Still, various similar ride-hailing services are being offered
in Nicaragua. These platforms claim to obey the law by controlling and registering their drivers. The
government, together with representatives from the taxi industry, stressed that all use of digital ride-
hailing platforms is prohibited, arguing that they are unsafe for users and cause unemployment (River,
2019; Nicaragua Investiga, 2020).
        In 2015, the government of Mexico City became the first authority in Latin America to legalize
the service of Uber and other ride-hailing services like Cabify (Semana, 2015). The legalization included
three main measures undertaken. First of all, a new legal form of public transport was created, labelled
as “Servicios de transporte privado solicitados a través de plataformas tecnológicas” (‘private transport
services requested through technological platforms’). A tax of 1,5% has been implemented on the
revenue of those services. These taxes are deposited in a fund that is established to be able to make
investments in the Mexican road network and investments in the Mexican taxi industry. A second
measure is that cars can only be considered under the new category of public transport if they meet
certain requirements, including a minimum new purchase price and the presence of an airbag, safety

                                                                                                        20
You can also read