Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV

Page created by Mildred Shaw
 
CONTINUE READING
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
Headwind or Tailwind – Taxation Issues
           of Wind Parks
 A thesis submitted to the Bucerius/WHU Master of Law and Business Program
 in partial fulfillment of the requirements for the award of the Master of Law and
 Business (“MLB”) Degree

                           Lynn Waffenschmidt
                                 August 7, 2012

                      13,920 words (excluding footnotes)
                    Supervisor 1: Prof. Dr. Birgit Weitemeyer
                        Supervisor 2: Florian Lechner
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
Table of Contents

1 Introduction to the Topic ..................................................................................................... 1
2 The Liability for Wind Parks to Pay Taxes in Germany ....................................................... 8
        2.1 Jurisdiction to Tax in General .................................................................................. 8
        2.2 The German “Inland” in the Course of Time ............................................................ 8
        2.3 Consequences for Offshore Wind Parks ................................................................ 11
        2.4 Selected Issues ..................................................................................................... 15
                   2.4.1 The Wind Park “RIFFGAT” and the German-Dutch Border Issue ............ 15
                   2.4.2 Floating Wind Turbines ........................................................................... 20
                            2.4.2.1 The Technological Development ................................................ 20
                            2.4.2.2 Taxing Floating Wind Turbines ................................................... 23
3 Trade Tax Issues...............................................................................................................26
        3.1 Levy of Trade Tax ................................................................................................. 27
                   3.1.1 When Does a Trade Tax Liability Arise? ................................................. 27
                   3.1.2 How Much Trade Tax Is to Be Paid? ....................................................... 31
                   3.1.3 Which Municipality Is Entitled to the Trade Tax Revenues? .................... 32
        3.2 Allocation of Trade Tax.......................................................................................... 35
                   3.2.1 Which Municipality Is Entitled to How Much of the Trade Tax
                         Revenues? ............................................................................................ 35
                   3.2.2 Which Allocation Formula Should Be Used? ........................................... 39
                              3.2.2.1 Do Wind Parks Call for an Exception of the Regular Rule
                                      of §29 GewStG? ..................................................................... 39
                            3.2.2.2 Which Possibilities for Alternative Rules Exist? .......................... 43
4 Conclusion ........................................................................................................................45
References ...........................................................................................................................48
Appendices ..........................................................................................................................54
        Appendix A: Offshore wind parks in the North and Baltic Sea...................................... 54
        Appendix B: Emsmündung and course of borders as depicted in the Ems-Dollart-
                    Treaty of 1960......................................................................................... 56
        Appendix C: List of floating wind turbine projects ........................................................ 57
        Appendix D: Overview of interview partners ................................................................ 59
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
Table of Figures

Fig. 1:   Water depth and distance to coast of European offshore wind parks, sorted by
          country...................................................................................................................... 3
Fig. 2:   Drivers of revenue and cost of offshore wind parks.................................................. 4
Fig. 3:   Cumulative installed capacity of offshore wind turbines in selected European
          countries ................................................................................................................... 5
Fig. 4:   Total offshore wind capacity installed, under construction, consented, planned
          as of 30 June 2011, in MW ....................................................................................... 6
Fig. 5:   The zones of the sea according to the UNCLOS...................................................... 9
Fig. 6:   Germany’s and the Netherland’s perception of their borders in the Ems-
          Dollart-Area ............................................................................................................ 16
Fig. 7:   The location of the wind park “RIFFGAT” ................................................................17
Fig. 8:   Distance and depth of online, consented and under construction offshore wind
          farms ...................................................................................................................... 20
Fig. 9:   Floating support structure types ..............................................................................21
Fig. 10: Sample calculation of a business’ amount of trade tax due .....................................32
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
Table of Abbreviations

AO        Abgabenordnung (General Tax Code)
BFH       Bundesfinanzhof (Federal Finance Court)
BFM       Bundesfinanzministerium (Federal Ministry of Finance )
BGBl.     Bundesgesetzblatt (Federal Gazette)
BMU       Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit (Federal
          Ministry for the Environment, Nature Conservation and Nuclear Safety)
BR-Dr     Bundesratsdrucksache (Federal Council Print Matter)
BSH       Bundesamt für Schifffahrt und Hydrographie (Federal Office for Navigation
          and Hydrography)
BT-Dr     Bundestagsdrucksache (Bundestag Print Matter)
BWE       Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V. (Federal Association Wind Energy )
CO2e      CO2 Equivalent
DEWI      Deutsches Windenergie-Institut (German Wind Energy Institute)
EEG       Erneuerbare-Energien-Gesetz (Renewable Energies Law)
EEZ       Exclusive Economic Zone
EStG      Einkommensteuergesetz (Income Tax Code)
EWEA      European Wind Energy Association
FG        Finanzgericht (Finance Court)
GewStG    Gewerbesteuergesetz (Trade Tax Code)
GG        Grundgesetz (Basic Law)
GHG       Greenhouse Gas
IWES      Fraunhofer Institut für Windenergie und Energiesystemtechnik (Fraunhofer
          Institute for Wind Energy and Energy System Technology)
JStG      Jahressteuergesetz (Annual Tax Reform)
KfW       Kreditanstalt für Wiederaufbau (Credit Institute for Reconstruction)
KStG      Körperschaftssteuergesetz (Corporate Tax Code)
nm        nautical mile (= 1,852m)
PwC       PricewaterhouseCoopers AG Wirtschaftsprüfungsgesellschaft
Rn.       Randnummer (Recital)
Rz.       Randziffer (Recital)
SeeAnlV   Seeanlagenverordnung (Offshore Installations Ordinance)
UNCLOS    United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea
UNFCCC    United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change
VDMA      Verband Deutscher Maschinen und Anlagenbau e.V. (German Engineering
          Federation)
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
1 Introduction to the Topic

         It is not only the polar bear that is in danger of losing his habitat. The climate change

we are currently witnessing is affecting everyone on this planet: Heavy storms destroy the

homes of thousands of Americans, prolonged drought periods leave rural Indians and

Pakistani fighting against death from starvation of both livestock and men, the rising sea-

level threatens to swallow up New Zealand and other archipelagos.

         The Kyoto Protocol, adopted in 1997, so far has been the largest joint political effort

to fight climate change and mitigate its consequences. One of the biggest levers to reach the

goal of the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC), the

“stabilization of greenhouse gas concentrations in the atmosphere at a level that would

prevent dangerous anthropogenic interference with the climate system”1, is the transition

from using fossil fuels to renewable energy sources.

         As a pioneer in fighting climate change, Germany already made big steps towards its

goal for renewable energies to reach a share of 35% in electricity supply by 20202: In 2011,

the share rose to approximately 20%, compared to 17% in 20103. According to the

Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V. (BWE) and the Deutsches Windenergie-Institut (DEWI),

thanks to renewables, Germany could save 120m t CO2e in 2010; one third of this reduction

could be attributed to wind energy4. However, there is still a lot of potential to be tackled: If

wind energy alone would reach a share of 25% in electricity supply by 2025, as is planned by

the German federal government, GHG emissions could be reduced by 20% compared to

20105.

1
  Article 2 of United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change, The Convention on Climate Change, 1992, retrieved
  from http://unfccc.int/essential_background/convention/background/items/1349.php (23 June 2012).
2
  Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit, Questions and answers about transforming our energy
  system, 2011, retrieved from http://www.bmu.de/english/transformation_of_the_energy_system/faq/doc/47589.php (23 June
  2012).
3
  Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit, Erneuerbare Energien wichtiger Pfeiler für die
  Energieversorgung, press release no. 170/11, 29 December 2011, Berlin, retrieved from http://www.erneuerbare-
  energien.de/pressemitteilungen/aktuelle_pressemitteilungen/pm/48231.php (23 June 2012).
4
  Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V. (Ed.), BWE Branchenreport: Windindustrie in Deutschland 2012, 2nd ed., Berlin 2012, p.
  29.
5
  Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V. (Ed.), BWE Branchenreport 2012 (fn. 4), p. 29.
                                                                                                                          1
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
So far, wind energy only covers 7.7% of Germany’s electricity demand, but still, up

from 6.2% in 20106, with an output of 47 TWh in 20117. Last year, wind turbines with a

capacity of over 2,000 MW were installed on- and offshore, leading to a total of 22,200 wind

turbines with a capacity of nearly 29,000 MW in Germany8. With this installed base, Germany

ranks third behind the USA, who displaced Germany in 2008, and China, who displaced the

USA in 20109.

         The worldwide development of wind energy is even more dynamic than in Germany

alone: With an additional 41,000 MW in 2011, there now is an installed capacity of

approximately 215,000 MW as of end 2011, a plus of 21% compared to 201010.

         Offshore wind energy however is still dwarfed by the onshore development. Only

4,000 MW of the aforementioned 215,000 MW can be attributed to offshore wind turbines

worldwide and 200 MW11 of the 2,051 MW additional capacity installed in Germany in 201112.

Although the first offshore wind park has already been built in 1991, near Vindeby, Denmark,

until now only comparably few wind parks have since been installed – 62 worldwide –,

approximately half of which far-shore13, half near-shore14.

         The trend though points towards wind parks being constructed further away from the

coast. Germany once more is a pioneer in this regard: the average German wind park is

installed 51 km away from the coast, in a water depth of approximately 28 m compared to a

worldwide average of 13.2 km and 14.5 m respectively15:

6
    Fraunhofer Institut für Windenergie und Energiesystemtechnik (IWES), Windenergie 2011, 2011, retrieved from
    http://windmonitor.iwes.fraunhofer.de/bilder/upload/Windreport_2011_de.pdf (18 June 2012), p. 9.
7
    IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 7.
8
    IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 7.
9
    IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 34.
10
   Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V. (Ed.), BWE Branchenreport 2012 (fn. 4), p. 11.
11
   The 200 MW (rounded) come from the offshore wind parks alpha ventus (60 MW), Baltic 1 (48.3 MW) and Bard Offshore (90
    MW). Cf. Windenergie Agentur WAB, Branchenbericht 2011: Offshore-Windenergiemarkt in Deutschland, 2011, retrieved
    from http://www.windenergie-agentur.de/deutsch/PDFs/WAB-Branchenbericht2011.pdf (18 June 2012), p. 3.
12
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), pp. 7, 35.
13
   Using the criterion of the EEG, „far-shore“ means further away from the coast than three nautical miles: cf. IWES,
    Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 35.
14
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 35.
15
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), pp. 42–43.
                                                                                                                       2
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
16
         Fig. 1: Water depth and distance to coast of European offshore wind parks, sorted by country

         The subordinate role of offshore wind has several causes: Offshore wind turbines are

exposed to rougher external conditions; wind and waves put high pressure on the whole

installation and furthermore make the materials corrode more easily than those of their

counterparts onshore. The resulting different technical requirements increase costs.

Production is more expensive as well, since economies of scale have not been reached yet

due to the slower development of the technology. Transport costs are higher due to the

larger distances and the aggravated accessibility of offshore wind parks. Maintenance is also

affected by the aggravated accessibility: waves and storms make it harder and more

expensive to get to the turbines and can result in longer standstills in case of a dysfunction.

Furthermore, the grid connection is harder to achieve than on shore, longer and more

resistant cables are needed.

         In contrast, there are also advantages of offshore wind turbines over onshore ones:

Depending on the actual location, wind yield can as much as double17, to 4,000 full load

hours18. Additionally, wind yields are steadier on the high sea. There are also more locations

available at present than on shore and offshore wind parks do not disturb tourists’ or

resident’s ears and eyes alike, if they are far out.

16
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 43.
17
   Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V., BWE Branchenreport: Windindustrie in Deutschland 2011, 2011, retrieved from
   http://www.wind-energy-
   market.com/fileadmin/Bilder_und_Logos/Marktuebersicht/Windindustrie_in_Deutschland_DE_Branchenreport.pdf (18 June
   2012), p. 18.
18
   E.ON, E.ON Offshore Wind Energy Factbook, 2011, retrieved from
   www.eon.com/de/downloads/EON_Offshore_Wind_Factbook_en_December_2011.pdf (11 April 2012), p. 11.
                                                                                                                       3
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
19
         Fig. 2: Drivers of revenue and cost of offshore wind parks

         For these reasons, offshore wind energy is firmly rooted in the German federal

government’s energy concept. In September 2010, the government passed a new guideline,

wherein the goal of renewable energies gaining a share of 35% of energy supply by 2020,

50% by 2030, 65% by 2040 and 80% by 2050 is established20. Due to the catastrophe in

Fukushima in March 2011, the role of nuclear plants in the aforementioned energy concept

was revised and in June 2011 an “energy package” was passed with the aim of accelerating

the implementation of the measures previously decided upon.

         The goal stated in the Strategie der Bundesregierung zur Windenergienutzung auf

See21 of 2002 was reinforced in 2010’s energy concept: the installed capacity of offshore

wind turbines is supposed to reach 25,000 MW by 203022. Considering that 2011’s capacity

was only 200 MW, this means the installation of approximately 1,000 MW every year, which

could generate a yearly added value of €3bn in the German economy, according to the

VDMA23.

         But for Germany as an export nation, it is not only the German market that counts.

According to the BWE, wind turbine producers achieve two thirds of their revenues through

19
   Graph by author. Photo retrieved from www.virginiaenergy.org (23 June 2012).
20
   Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit, Transforming our energy system (fn. 2).
21
   In English: “The Federal Government’s Strategy for the Utilization of Offshore Wind Energy”.
22
   Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit et al., Strategie der Bundesregierung zur Windnutzung auf
   See im Rahmen der Nachhaltigkeitsstrategie der Bundesregierung, 2002, retrieved from http://www.erneuerbare-
   energien.de/files/pdfs/allgemein/application/pdf/windenergie_strategie_br_020100.pdf (22 June 2012), p. 7;
   Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit, Das Energiekonzept der Bundesregierung 2010 und die
   Energiewende 2011, 2011, retrieved from
   http://www.bmu.de/files/pdfs/allgemein/application/pdf/energiekonzept_bundesregierung.pdf (23 June 2012), p. 8.
23
   Verband Deutscher Maschinen und Anlagenbau e.V., VDMA-Positionspapier: Offshore-Windenergie, 2011, retrieved from
   http://www.vdma.org/wps/wcm/connect/c21ba2004dd25050bcb8fcd1f693e3d9/2011_04_01_Offshore+Windenergie.pdf?MOD
   =AJPERES&CACHEID=c21ba2004dd25050bcb8fcd1f693e3d9 (18 June 2012), p. 2.
                                                                                                                          4
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
their export business24. In Europe, Great Britain is leading the offshore market with 1,660

MW installed capacity25 by end 2011 and is expected to keep this position:
                                                                                                               26
         Fig. 3: Cumulative installed capacity of offshore wind turbines in selected European countries

         The German wind energy industry can only use its potential if there are the right

political and economic framework conditions. Currently, the most severe problems for the

offshore wind industry in Germany are the following: The process of obtaining an official

permit to build an offshore wind park takes far too long. There are considerable problems of

obtaining funding. According to KPMG, average investment costs for one MW amounts to

€3.7m27. Due to the financial crisis, incertitude resulting from only few project experiences, as

well as a not overly attractive feed-in compensation, it is hard to find investors. Additionally,

the slow grid expansion is still a problem. After all, it is Northern Germany where there is

most wind yield and Southern Germany where most electricity is needed. According to the

BWE, “[a]lone in 2010, 150 GWh of electricity were lost in the German wind industry,

because turbines had to be switched off due to a grid overload.”28 Further problems are the

availability of the infrastructure for building more offshore wind parks, such as special

vessels, as well as a shortage of skilled labour.

24
   Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V., BWE Branchenreport 2011 (fn. 17), p. 11.
25
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 40.
26
   PricewaterhouseCoopers AG Wirtschaftsprüfungsgesellschaft (PwC), Volle Kraft aus Hochseewind, 2012, retrieved from
    http://wab.biz/atest/images/stories/PDF/studien/Volle_Kraft_aus_Hochseewind_PwC_WAB.pdf (18 June 2012), p. 42.
27
   KPMG AG Wirtschaftsprüfungsgesellschaft, Offshore-Wind – Potenziale für die deutsche Schiffbauindustrie, 2011, retrieved
    from http://www.kpmg.de/docs/offshore_wind_copyright_230511.pdf (18 June 2012), p. 30.
28
   Bundesverband WindEnergie e.V. (Ed.), BWE Branchenreport 2012 (fn. 4), p. 11. Translated from German by author.
                                                                                                                              5
Headwind or Tailwind - Taxation Issues of Wind Parks - GBV
The German government is already dealing with some of these challenges. Two of

the most important achievements are the special program of the KfW that sponsors the first

ten offshore wind parks with €5bn worth of loans at the market interest rate29 as well as the

EEG amendment improving the conditions of feed-in compensation30.

         These initiatives lay the foundation of Germany becoming a leading force in the

offshore wind industry. Germany already is the country that authorized the highest capacity

in offshore wind parks: 8,800 MW on an area of 1,160 km2 31:

         Fig. 4: Total offshore wind capacity installed, under construction, consented, planned as of 30 June
             32
2011, in MW
              Belgium      1,857                                                    Online
             Denmark           2,472                                                Under construction
              Finland             4,293                                             Consented
              Estonia     1,000                                                     Planned
               France                  6,000
             Germany                                                     31,246
              Greece               4,889
               Ireland           3,780
                 Italy         2,700
               Latvia    200
                Malta 95
          Netherlands                  5,992
              Norway                               11,394
               Poland     900
             Portugal    478
                Spain                   6,804
              Sweden                       8,279
                  UK                                                                                     48,596

         Until December 2011, a total of 30 wind parks were authorized by the BSH, 25 in the

German North Sea, five in the German Baltic Sea33. This development is in line with the

federal government’s goals stated above and an important part of the financial development

of the German offshore wind industry. PwC estimates that the offshore wind industry’s

revenues across the whole value chain could reach €22.4bn by 2021, up from €5.9bn in

29
   Bundesministerium für Umwelt, Naturschutz und Reaktorsicherheit, Das Energiekonzept der Bundesregierung 2010 und die
    Energiewende 2011, 2011, retrieved from
    http://www.bmu.de/files/pdfs/allgemein/application/pdf/energiekonzept_bundesregierung.pdf (23 June 2012), p. 8.
30
   Gesetz zur Neuregelung des Rechtsrahmens für die Förderung der Stromerzeugung aus erneuerbaren Energien vom 28. Juli
    2011, (BGBl. 2011 I, 1634).
31
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 37.
32
   Data from European Wind Energy Association, Wind in our Sails: The coming of Europe's offshore wind energy industry,
    2011, retrieved from
    http://www.ewea.org/fileadmin/ewea_documents/documents/publications/reports/23420_Offshore_report_web.pdf (18 June
    2012), p. 16. Illustration by author.
33
   IWES, Windenergie 2011 (fn. 6), p. 37. See also Appendix A.
                                                                                                                     6
2010, its number of employees from currently 6,000 to 33,00034. This of course also has a

huge impact on the tax revenues: The same study projects trade tax revenues of €240m in

2021 for Germany, up from €64m in 2010 and €190m in 201635.

            For the reason of the above elaborated importance of wind energy for the fight

against climate change as well as for the German economy, this thesis deals with selected

topics in the taxation of wind parks. In the second chapter following this introduction to the

topic, I will explain when Germany is authorized to levy taxes in general on both on- and

offshore wind parks and elaborate on the changing definition of the German “Inland”. After a

historic discourse, I will scrutinize the definition and role of the continental shelf and dedicate

a sub-chapter to the German-Dutch border dispute that arose anew due to the instalment of

the wind park “RIFFGAT” that is supposedly on both German and Dutch territory –

depending on the respective country’s definition of the national border. Based on the

previous analyses the chapter ends with a sub-chapter solely about the special case of

taxing floating wind turbines that are far out in the sea and not necessarily very firmly

grounded on the seabed in order to answer the question of how existing German law is to be

applied to this future technology.

            The third chapter deals with trade tax as one example of the taxes Germany levies on

wind parks. I will examine both the question of which preconditions have to be satisfied so

that trade tax becomes due and the question of distributing the trade tax between the

municipality where the operating company has its registered seat and the municipality where

the park is operated.

            In order to answer these questions, I will review literature, discuss with several

experts to include the perspectives of a lawyer, an operating company, the German

municipalities and financial authorities, as well as interpret the applicable German laws.

34
     PwC, Hochseewind (fn. 26), pp. 5, 13.
35
     PwC, Hochseewind (fn. 26), p. 14.
                                                                                                 7
2 The Liability for Wind Parks to Pay Taxes in Germany

          2.1 Jurisdiction to Tax in General

          In order to be liable to pay taxes to the German state you either have to be a resident

in Germany, which means for a company to have its registered seat within the German

national territory or its effective management taking place there (§10 AO), or you earn

income in Germany that falls under the category of source income as defined in §49 EStG –

for a corporation especially important in this regard are earnings attributable to a German

permanent establishment (§49 (1) No. 2 EStG, §12 AO).

          If the first possibility applies, the German tax authorities have the right to claim taxes

on the taxpayer’s world-wide income; the corporation then has an unlimited tax liability (§1

(1) KStG; §1 (1)-(3) EStG). If the second possibility applies, only the part of the taxpayer’s

income that was actually earned in Germany can be taxed by the German authorities; the

taxpayer has a limited tax liability36 (§2 KStG; §1 (4) EStG).

          To determine on what exactly the German tax authorities can claim taxes, the

question now is, where exactly does German national territory start and where does it end?

          2.2 The German “Inland” in the Course of Time

          A liability to pay taxes only arises on German national territory37. All borders onshore

are very clear, so the issue of defining that territory moves to the borders offshore. The sea is

governed by the United Nations Convention on the Law of the Sea (UNCLOS), the

“fundamental order of the sea […] [that] divides the sea into different zones and assigns

various sovereign rights and duties to the coastal states”38.

36
   This may cause a certain part of the income to be taxed several times, for example if someone is a tax resident in more than
   one country or if someone’s world-wide income is taxed in his home country and at the same time income he earned as a
   non-resident in another country is taxed by that country as source income. Double taxation treaties deal with this problem of
   legal double taxation. Since this issue is not the focus of the paper at hand, it will not be discussed in more detail here.
37
   The national territory definition used for determining a tax liability may differ from the general definition of national territory.
   This is due to the functionality of the term “national territory” in tax law (Waldhoff/Engler, Die Küste im deutschen
   Ertragssteuerrecht – am Beispiel der Besteuerung von Offshore-Energieerzeugung, in: Finanz-Rundschau 6/2012, 254–262,
   p. 255).
38
   Markus/Maurer, Windenergie und Gewerbesteuer: Zur Lückenhaftigkeit des Rechts der Offshore-Windenergie-Besteuerung,
   in: Neue Zeitschrift für Verwaltungsrecht – Extra 2012, Vol. 31(10), 1–10, p. 2.
                                                                                                                                      8
The UNCLOS defines five different zones (see Fig. 5), of which I chose the three that

are most important for wind parks in Germany as I will further explain in the next subchapter:

the territorial sea (Art. 2 ff. UNCLOS), the exclusive economic zone (Art. 55 ff. UNCLOS) and

the continental shelf (Art. 76 ff. UNCLOS).
                                                                          39,40
          Fig. 5: The zones of the sea according to the UNCLOS

          According to Art. 2 (1) UNCLOS, an “adjacent belt of sea” of a coastal state, the

territorial sea, belongs to the national territory of the same as does its land territory and

internal waters. Thus, the state’s sovereignty does not stop at the coast, but up to 12 nautical

miles41 from the baselines42 in the sea (cf. Art. 3 UNCLOS) and covers the air space, the

seabed as well as the subsoil (cf. Art. 2 (2) UNCLOS). Germany has proclaimed such a zone

of approximately 12 nautical miles in the North and the Baltic Sea in 199443.

39
   http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/File:Zonmar-en.svg (1 March 2012).
40
   Even though not depicted in Fig. 5, “all parts of the sea that are not included in the exclusive economic zone, in the territorial
   sea or in the internal waters of a State, or in the archipelagic waters of an archipelagic State” (Art. 86 UNCLOS) are defined
   as the high seas.
41
   According to Graf Vitzthum, this can be traced to the original zone of 3 nautical miles, which is a canon’s range of fire. After
   the Second World War however, coastal states expanded this zone on their own authority. Art. 3 UNCLOS institutionalizes
   this customary international law. (Graf Vitzthum, Staatsgebiet, in: Isensee/Kirchhof (Eds.), Handbuch des Staatsrechts der
   Bundesrepublik Deutschland, Band II: Verfassungsstaat, 3rd ed., Heidelberg 2004, §18 Rn. 30)
42
   The so-called „normal baseline“ (Art. 5 UNCLOS) is defined as the “low-water line along the coast as marked on large-scale
   charts officially recognized by the coastal State” (ibid.). In case it is impractical to measure the base line in the
   aforementioned way, due to the physical shape of the coast for example, the “straight baseline” (Art. 7 UNCLOS) is used that
   takes “lighthouses or similar installations which are permanently above the sea level” (ibid.) as points of orientation.
43
   Cf. Bekanntmachung der Proklamation der Bundesregierung über die Ausweitung des deutschen Küstenmeers vom 11.
   November 1994, (BGBl. 1994 I, 3428).
                                                                                                                                   9
Any area in excess of the territorial sea is under international law not part of a state’s

national territory. However, pursuant to the Geneva Convention on the Continental Shelf of

1958, the coastal states have a certain, functionally limited, sovereignty, namely the

“sovereign rights for the purpose of exploring it [i.e., the continental shelf] and exploiting its

natural resources”44. Germany utilised this right in 1964 by publishing its Proklamation der

Bundesregierung über die Erforschung und Ausbeutung des deutschen Festlandsockels on

20 January 196445. A law on the Preliminary Regulation of the Rights to the Continental

Shelf46 followed in the same year and was changed ten years later, in 197447.

          The UNCLOS builds on the Geneva convention of 1958 and, in principle, involves the

same thought of a coastal state’s “functionally sovereign territory”48 in excess of the territorial

waters, does however further refine what was previously called “continental shelf”49.

          The exclusive economic zone (EEZ) is defined as “an area beyond and adjacent to

the territorial sea” (Art. 55 UNCLOS) where the coastal state has “sovereign rights for the

purpose of exploring and exploiting, conserving and managing the natural resources,

whether living or non-living, of the waters superjacent to the seabed and of the seabed and

its subsoil, and with regard to other activities for the economic exploitation and exploration of

the zone, such as the production of energy from the water, currents and winds” (Art. 56 (1)

(a) UNCLOS). Germany has established such an EEZ in both the North and the Baltic Sea

with its proclamation of 25 November 199450. The EEZ is, however, not part of the German

44
   Art. 2 (1) of International Law Commission, Convention on the Continental Shelf. 29 April 1958, United Nations, Treaty Series,
   Vol. 499, p. 311, retrieved from http://www.unhcr.org/refworld/docid/3ddb8e6a4.html (24 June 2012).
45
   Proklamation der Bundesregierung über die Erforschung und Ausbeutung des deutschen Festlandsockels vom 20. Januar
   1964, (BGBl. 1964 II, 104).
46
   Gesetz zur vorläufigen Regelung der Rechte am Festlandsockel vom 24. Juli 1964, (BGBl. 1964 I, 497). Translated from
   German by author.
47
   Gesetz zur Änderung des Gesetzes zur vorläufigen Regelung der Rechte am Festlandsockel vom 2. September 1974, (BGBl.
   1974 I, 2149).
48
   Erbguth, Die Abstimmung von Nutzungsansprüchen und Schutzerfordernissen in marinen Räumen, lecture held as part of the
   series "Räume - Ein Schlüsselbegriff der Geistes-, Sozial- und Naturwissenschaften", University of Rostock, 24 January 2008,
   retrieved from http://www.iuk-verbund.uni-
   rostock.de/fileadmin/IUK/Ringvorlesungen/Raeume/080124_Erbguth_Marine_Raeume.pdf (11 April 2012), p. 3. Translated
   from German by author.
49
   The continental shelf was defined differently back then compared to the more current UNCLOS, as “the seabed and subsoil of
   the submarine areas adjacent to the coast but outside the area of the territorial sea, to a depth of 200 metres” (Art. 1
   Convention on the Continental Shelf). However, according to Art. 311 (1) UNCLOS, the UNCLOS’ definition prevails over the
   Geneva convention’s.
50
   Proklamation der Bundesrepublik Deutschland über die Errichtung einer ausschließlichen Wirtschaftszone der
   Bundesrepublik Deutschland in der Nordsee und in der Ostsee vom 25. November 1994, (BGBl. 1994 II, 3770).
                                                                                                                             10
national territory. The sovereign rights assigned to Germany as coastal state are functionally

limited to the ones listed in Art. 56 (1) UNCLOS.

            Neither is the continental shelf part of a state’s national territory. It “comprises the

seabed and subsoil of the submarine areas that extend beyond its territorial sea throughout

the natural prolongation of its land territory to the outer edge of the continental margin, or to a

distance of 200 nautical miles from the baselines from which the breadth of the territorial sea

is measured” (Art. 76 (1) UNCLOS), whichever is greater. Also the sovereign rights a coastal

state has here are fairly similar: it “exercises over the continental shelf sovereign rights for

the purpose of exploring it and exploiting its natural resources.” (Art. 77 (1) UNCLOS)

Although the rights “do not depend on […] any express proclamation” (Art. 77 (3) UNCLOS),

Germany did proclaim their part of the continental shelf in 196451.

            However, the “legal status of the superjacent waters or of the air space above those

waters” (Art. 78 (1) UNCLOS) are not affected by the sovereign rights the coastal state has

with regards to the continental shelf. Thus, with its proclamation, Germany did not obtain a

possessive entitlement to any area, whether to soil or water, and both exclusive economic

zone and continental shelf do not form part of Germany’s national territory. Germany’s

national territory is restricted to its land territory, internal waters and territorial waters.

            2.3 Consequences for Offshore Wind Parks

            For wind parks this means that taxes become due for income earned by onshore wind

parks anywhere on Germany’s land territory as well as by offshore wind parks located in the

territorial waters. Due to national parks as well as fairways being located in Germany’s

coastal area52, most of its wind parks however are not within territorial waters but in the area

of the exclusive economic zone. Does this mean then that no taxes become due?

            Not necessarily. According to Art. 56 (1) (a) UNCLOS, Germany has “sovereign rights

for […] the economic exploitation and exploration of the zone, such as the production of

51
     Proklamation Festlandsockel (fn. 45).
52
     Wustlich, Das Recht der Windenergie im Wandel: Teil 2: Windenergie auf See, in: Zeitschrift für Umweltrecht 2007, Vol. 18(3),
     122–130, p. 123. See also: Waldhoff/Engler, Küste (fn. 37), p. 255.
                                                                                                                              11
energy from the […] winds” as well as according to Art. 56 (1) (b) (i) UNCLOS “jurisdiction

[…] with regard to the establishment and use of artificial islands, installations and structures”.

This jurisdiction includes questions regarding “customs, fiscal, health, safety and immigration

laws and regulations.” (Art. 60 (2) UNCLOS) Therefore, a wind turbine as an installation to

exploit the exclusive economic zone’s wind with the goal of producing energy is subject to

German taxes.

            The same holds for the continental shelf. Although Germany’s sovereign rights there

are functionally limited to the exploration of natural resources (Art. 77 UNCLOS) – in contrast

to the explicit mentioning of the exploitation of renewable energy in the EEZ’s applicable Art.

56 UNCLOS –, Art. 60 UNCLOS “applies mutatis mutandis to […] installations […] on the

continental shelf” (Art. 80 UNCLOS) and therefore also to wind parks installed on the

continental shelf.

            Still, not every wind park’s revenues are automatically subject to taxes. In case the

turbine is owned by a company that is a German tax resident, the income of this turbine (or,

in the case of several turbines, of the wind park) is subject to the company’s unlimited tax

liability. It will be taxed as part of the taxpayer’s world-wide income. In case the turbine or

wind park is owned by a non-resident company however, its income is not source income as

defined in §49 EStG since the EEZ is not part of the German national territory. For a

corporation that only has a limited tax liability this means that it can simply pocket any

revenues generated in the EEZ without paying taxes to the German authorities. This was the

case until recently that is.

            The German legislative has dealt with the problem of defining German national

territory with regards to taxation three times: In 1974, the Bundestag, with the approval of the

Bundesrat, passed a law that would include “the part of the continental shelf that Germany is

entitled to”53 in its definition of the German inland – but only “as far as the exploration and

53
     Zweites Steueränderungsgesetz 1973 vom 18. Juli 1974, (BGBl. 1974 I, 1489), p. 1489. This change did not only apply to the
     EStG (p. 1489), but also to the KStG (p. 1494) and the GewStG (p. 1495). Translated from German by author.
                                                                                                                            12
exploitation of natural resources of the seabed or its subsoil”54 is concerned. Thus, non-

resident corporations’ wind parks that are located in Germany’s EEZ or on its part of the

continental shelf were still not subject to German taxes, since the exploitation of wind to

produce energy does not fall under this qualifier. As Wustlich pointed out, “the use of wind

energy is an indirect utilization of the sun’s radiation energy that causes temperature and

pressure differences by warming the earth’s surface that themselves cause airflows that are

called winds.“55 Thus, a turbine producing energy from wind cannot be characterised as an

installation that exploits the natural resources of the seabed or its subsoil and therefore does

not fall under the new definition of inland.

           In 2006, the Bundesrat tried to correct that and explicitly include “the production of

energy and the utilisation of renewable energies”56 in the utilisations of the continental shelf

that would constitute activities in the German inland for §1 (1) EStG, §1 (3) KStG and §2 (7)

No. 1 GewStG. The reason for this resolution was that they thought it “unfair that the

realization of profits through exploration and exploitation of the German continental shelf’s

seabed would lead to domestic income while other activities with the goal of realizing profits

in the same spatial area would not.”57 The Bundestag however voted down the Bundesrat’s

proposal. They suggested that the question of taxing the utilization of renewable energies to

produce energy would be dealt with in one of the future tax laws, “because this proposal’s

economic consequences on the development of renewable energies and especially the

offshore wind energy in the short and medium term cannot be evaluated conclusively”58 at

that point in time.

           In 2007, the Bundesrat again proposed the same amendment. They argued that in

the meantime, it became clear that more and more corporations started activities in the area

above the continental shelf with the goal of realizing profits. It was unfair that German

companies had to pay taxes on revenues generated with wind parks while non-residents did

54
     Zweites Steueränderungsgesetz 1973 (fn. 53), p. 1489. Translated from German by author.
55
     Wustlich, Windenergie auf See (fn. 52), p. 129. Translated from German by author.
56
     Stellungnahme des Bundesrates: Entwurf eines Jahressteuergesetzes 2007 (JStG 2007), BR-Dr 622/06 (Beschluss), p. 1.
     Translated from German by author.
57
     Bundesrat JStG 2007 (fn. 56), p. 3. Translated from German by author.
58
     Unterrichtung durch die Bundesregierung: Entwurf eines Jahressteuergesetzes 2007 (JStG 2007) - Stellungnahme des
     Bundesrates und Gegenäußerung der Bundesregierung, BT-Dr 16/3036, p. 19. Translated from German by author.
                                                                                                                           13
not59. This differing treatment clearly resulted in a competitive advantage of foreign over

German companies, which were both operating within the same spatial area, where

Germany has functionally limited sovereign rights.

         This time, the Bundestag did not reject the Bundesrat’s proposal, but declared to

further look into it60. The EStG, KStG and GewSt were finally changed accordingly within the

framework of the Annual Tax Act 200861. German source income for non-resident taxpayers

with limited tax liability thus, from the assessment period 2008 forward, includes revenues

generated by exploiting the German continental shelf to produce energy from renewable

sources, i.e., also by wind parks located in the areas defined by the UNCLOS as exclusive

economic zone and continental shelf as far as they concern the coastal state Germany.

         Still, another tax, namely the insurance tax, managed to slip through the reform. Until

this day, establishments that are located outside of Germany’s territorial waters but are still

on Germany’s continental shelf, are not subject to insurance tax. Only recently, on 25 May

2012,      the     federal     government          submitted       a     draft     law     to    the     Bundesrat62

(Verkehrsteueränderungsgesetz) with the aim of including the exclusive economic zone in

the scope of the insurance tax code from 1 January 2013 forward. Contrary to the

government’s view, according to Behrendt et al., this law’s aim is not simply to clarify the

scope of the insurance code that is supposed to have included the EEZ even before 201363.

It is rather a “first-time justification of a national tax claim in this area”64. Only if this law

actually is passed, another loop hole will be closed and offshore wind parks are subject to

the same taxes as onshore wind parks.

59
   Stellungnahme des Bundesrates: Entwurf eines Jahressteuergesetzes 2008 (JStG 2008), BR-Dr 544/07 (Beschluss), p. 3.
60
   Cf. Unterrichtung durch die Bundesregierung: Entwurf eines Jahressteuergesetzes 2008 (JStG 2008) - Stellungnahme des
   Bundesrates und Gegenäußerung der Bundesregierung, BT-Dr 16/6739, p. 31.
61
   Cf. Jahressteuergesetz 2008 (JStG 2008), (BGBl. 2007 I, 3150), pp. 3150, 3165, 3168.
62
   Cf. Gesetzesentwurf der Bundesregierung: Entwurf eines Gesetzes zur Änderung des Versicherungsteuergesetzes und des
   Kraftfahrzeugsteuergesetzes (Verkehrsteueränderungsgesetz – VerkehrStÄndG), BR-Dr 301/12.
63
   Behrendt et al., Praxisfragen zu deutschen Besteuerungsrechten im Zusammenhang mit Offshore-Windparks in der
   deutschen ausschließlichen Wirtschaftszone, in: Betriebs-Berater 30/2012, 1827–1835, p. 1834.
64
   Behrendt et al., Besteuerungsrechte (fn. 63), p. 1834.
                                                                                                                     14
2.4 Selected Issues

         After the exploration of the general rules and their historical development, I will now

focus on two special issues: the border dispute between Germany and the Netherlands who

never clearly defined a certain border section of their continental shelf, which is now a

problem for a wind park in construction, as well as the next generation technology floating

wind turbines and the question of taxing their revenues in the light of the previous remarks.

         2.4.1 The Wind Park “RIFFGAT” and the German-Dutch Border Issue

         As discussed in chapter 2.2, “[t]he sovereignty of a coastal State extends […] to an

adjacent belt of sea, described as the territorial sea.” (Art. 2 UNCLOS) A problem only arises

if the territorial waters of two adjacent or opposite countries overlap. In that case, the

UNCLOS determines that the states concerned need to agree on a course of the border, or

in absence of such an agreement, “neither of the two States is entitled […] to extend its

territorial sea beyond the median line every point of which is equidistant from the nearest

point on the baselines from which the breadth of the territorial seas of each of the two States

is measured.” (Art. 15 S. 1 UNCLOS) A boundary line deviating from this provision is only

legal if there is a “historic title or other special circumstances” (Art. 15 S. 2 UNCLOS).

         A conflict between Germany and the Netherlands arose because, while Germany

claims to have a historic title on the whole Ems, based on a deed of enfeoffment of 155865,

the Netherlands claim the above described compromise of the median line of Art. 15 S. 1

UNCLOS (the so-called Thalweg Theory66), which would make two thirds of the River Ems

Dutch67. Both countries are dependent on the Ems for an access to their harbours and thus

have an interest in a peaceful regulation of this area.

65
   Emperor Ferdinand I claimed in this deed: “The Ems is part of the county East Frisia!” (Bundesverband der See- und
   Hafenlotsen e.V., INFO - Nachrichten für See- und Hafenlotsen, 2004, No. 45, retrieved from
   http://www.bshl.de/downloads/info45.pdf (26 June 2012), p. 6; translated from German by author). Aubin/Menzel argue that
   the exercise of its rights by Germany and its predecessors in title during the following centuries establish Germany’s
   “immemorial possession” (Aubin/Menzel, Die niederländischen Ansprüche auf die Emsmündung, Hamburg 1949, p. 53) of
   this area in a powerful way that is hardly comparable to any other case, since it stems from a time even before the states
   existed in today’s form (ibid.).
66
   Cf. Bundesverband der See- und Hafenlotsen e.V., INFO (fn. 65), p. 6.
67
   Treviranus, Der deutsch-niederländische Ems-Dollart-Vertrag, in: Zeitschrift für ausländisches öffentliches Recht und
   Völkerrecht 1963, Vol. 23, 536–553, p. 540.
                                                                                                                           15
On 8 April 1960, the bilateral treaty Ems-Dollart-Vertrag was signed. Its goal, “to

ensure the seaward accessibility of their harbours”68 (Art. 1 S. 169) was supposed to be

reached with pragmatic regulations, while upholding each country’s understanding of the

course of the border70 (Art. 1 S. 2, Art. 46 (1)), “in the spirit of good neighbourhood”71 (Art. 1

S. 1).
                                                                                                              72
           Fig. 6: Germany’s and the Netherland’s perception of their borders in the Ems-Dollart-Area

           Their pragmatic solution included the functional allocation of sovereign rights that

were only partly linked to a geographic separation of the area. Germany, for example, was

responsible for all water engineering works except for those that were solely beneficial to

Dutch harbours (cf. Art. 8-11). A binding geographic border in the Ems-Dollart-Area was not

part of the agreement and neither of any of the subsequent treaties of 1962, 1975, 1980,

1984 and 199673.

68
     Translated from German by author.
69
     The article numbers refer to the Vertrag zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und dem Königreich der Niederlande
     über die Regelung der Zusammenarbeit in der Emsmündung (Ems-Dollart-Vertrag), (BGBl. 1963 II, 602) from this point
     forward, unless otherwise stated.
70
     Cf. Fig. 6. See also Article 2 of Vertrag zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und dem Königreich der Niederlande über
     die seitliche Abgrenzung des Festlandsockels in Küstennähe, (BGBl. 1965 II, 1142) and Appendix B.
71
     Translated from German by author.
72
     http://commons.wikimedia.org/wiki/File:Deutsch-Niederl%C3%A4ndische_Grenzfrage.svg (18 June 2012).
73
     Zusatzabkommen zu dem zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und dem Königreich der Niederlande am 8. April 1960
     unterzeichneten Vertrag über die Regelung der Zusammenarbeit in der Emsmündung (Ems-Dollart-Vertrag), (BGBl. 1963 II,
     653); Abkommen zur Änderung des Vertrages vom 8. April 1960 zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und dem
     Königreich der Niederlande über die Regelung der Zusammenarbeit in der Emsmündung (Ems-Dollart-Vertrag), (BGBl. 1978
     II, 310); Vertrag zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und dem Königreich der Niederlande über die gemeinsame
     Information und Beratung der Schifffahrt in der Emsmündung durch Landradar- und Revierfunkanlagen, (BGBl. 1982 II,
     1016); Vertrag zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und dem Königreich der Niederlande über die Zusammenarbeit im
     Bereich von Ems und Dollart sowie in den angrenzenden Gebieten (Kooperationsvertrag Ems-Dollart), (BGBl. 1986 II, 511);
     Ergänzendes Protokoll zu dem am 8. April 1960 unterzeichneten Vertrag zwischen der Bundesrepublik Deutschland und
     dem Königreich der Niederlande über die Regelung der Zusammenarbeit in der Emsmündung (Ems-Dollart-Vertrag) zur
     Regelung der Zusammenarbeit zum Gewässer- und Naturschutz in der Emsmündung (Ems-Dollart-Umweltprotokoll), (BGBl.
     1997 II, 1703).
                                                                                                                           16
According to Treviranus, such a definition would not even make much sense due to

the natural unevenness of the river bed and associated difficulties for ships to stay within a

certain fairway, which in turn would lead ships to pass a German-Dutch border several times,

intentionally or not.74

            The border issue came up again in 2010, when a discussion about the legitimacy of a

wind park in the area with competing understandings of the German-Dutch border within the

Ems-Dollart-Area flared up. The wind park “RIFFGAT”, operated by a consortium of EWE

ENERGIE AG and ENOVA Energiesysteme GmbH & Co. KG, was supposed to be

established 15 km north-west of the island of Borkum, “within the 12 nautical mile-zone of

Lower Saxony”75.
                                                                  76
            Fig. 7: The location of the wind park “RIFFGAT”

            Since the German operators firmly believed that only German territory was affected,

they only applied to the German authorities for a permit to build the park. The Netherlands

however were of the opinion that part of the three lines of ten wind turbines each, occupying

a total area of 13.2 km2 including a security zone77, were on Dutch territory and thus needed

a Dutch permit as well. After having waited for the German permit for three to four years78,

another authorization process would further shift the date of the park’s entry into service.

74
     Cf. Treviranus, Ems-Dollart-Vertrag (fn. 67), p. 546–547.
75
     Offshore-Windpark RIFFGAT GmbH & Co. KG, RIFFGAT_factsheet_10_gesamt.pdf, retrieved from
     http://www.riffgat.de/presse/informationsmaterial/ (18 June 2012).
76
     http://www.riffgat.de/uploads/pics/lageplan_kabeltrasse_640.jpg (18 June 2012).
77
     Offshore-Windpark RIFFGAT GmbH & Co. KG, RIFFGAT factsheet (fn. 75).
78
     According to a taz.de article of 23 December 2010, they waited for three years (taz.de, Deutsch-Niederländische
     Nachbarschaft: Grenzkrieg fällt aus, article of 23.12.2010, taz.de, retrieved from http://www.taz.de/!63337/ (18 June 2012)),
     according to a De Gelderlander article of 14 January 2011, they waited for four years (De Gelderlander, Nederland en
     Duitsland praten over zeegrens, article of 14.01.2011, De Gelderlander, retrieved from
     http://www.gelderlander.nl/nieuws/algemeen /binnenland/7971679/Nederland-en-Duitsland-praten-over-zeegrens.ece (18
     June 2012)).
                                                                                                                                 17
Furthermore, to apply for a permit under a different national law would have meant to expose

oneself also to different regulations regarding the participation of the public and the hearing

of environmentalists79 and Dutch environmentalists already voiced their concerns: “The

tideland association is anxious about [the wind park] having a negative effect on flora and

fauna in that area.”80 Therefore, bilateral diplomatic talks started in November 201081, without

any result until 1 June 201282. However, it seems the issue has been solved in the

meantime, since on 15 June 2012 – with nearly one year delay83 – works started on the high

sea and the first monopiles were rammed into the seabed84.

            Due to the secrecy of the diplomatic meetings, there is no public information available

about on what basis a solution was found and with which process. It would have been better

to apply for a permit in both countries from the very beginning, as for example was the case

with the power cable NorNed85 that connects Norway’s and the Netherland’s electricity grids.

But there is no point crying over spilt milk. In my opinion, a solution could have been found

by drawing parallels to existing bilateral treaties.

            First, there is the Ems-Dollart-Treaty itself86. On two occasions, the German

authorities are responsible for German residents and the Dutch authorities for Dutch

residents – in the whole disputed area: that holds for vessels and for fishing and hunting. In

Art. 32 (1) it is stated that “[r]egarding the mouth of the Ems […] German vessels are

considered as within the scope of German law, Dutch vessels as within the scope of Dutch

79
     NWZonline, Für Politiker ist Grenze erreicht, article of 19.03.2012, Nordwest Zeitung, retrieved from
     http://www.nwzonline.de/Region/Artikel/2827783/F%FCr-Politiker-ist-Grenze-erreicht.html (18 June 2012).
80
     Savelberg, Grensruzie met Duitsers, article of 11.08.2011, De Telegraaf, retrieved from
     http://www.telegraaf.nl/binnenland/10350965/__Grensruzie_met_Duitsers__.html (18 June 2012). Translated from Dutch by
     author.
81
     NiederlandeNet, Grenzstreit: Streit um Windpark zwischen Deutschland und den Niederlanden, article of 15.08.2011,
     NiederlandeNet, retrieved from http://www.uni-
     muenster.de/NiederlandeNet/aktuelles/archiv/2011/august/0815grenzstreit.shtml (18 June 2012).
82
     De Telegraaf, 'Gaatje' in slepend conflict met Duitsland, article of 1 June 2012, De Telegraaf, retrieved from
     http://www.telegraaf.nl/binnenland/12267353/___Gaatje__in_conlict_Duitsland__.html (18 June 2012).
83
     Bauchmüller, Bizarrer Streit um Nordsee-Windpark: Rotoren in der Rätselzone, article of 10.08.2011, Süddeutsche Zeitung,
     retrieved from http://www.sueddeutsche.de/politik/bizarrer-streit-um-nordsee-windpark-rotoren-in-der-raetselzone-1.1129806
     (18 June 2012).
84
     Cf. Offshore-Windpark RIFFGAT GmbH & Co. KG, EWE: Erster Gründungspfahl für Offshore-Windpark "Riffgat" ragt aus der
     Nordsee, press release, 15 June 2012, Oldenburg, retrieved from http://www.riffgat.de/presse/pressemitteilungen/pm-
     display/article/ewe-erster-gruendungspfahl-fuer-offshore-windpark-riffgat-ragt-aus-der-nordsee/ (23 June 2012).
85
     Ministerie van Economische Zaken, Landbouw en Innovatie, COBRAcable: Entwurf des Berichts zu Reichweite und
     Detailniveau des Umweltverträglichkeitsberichts, 2010, retrieved from
     http://www.agentschapnl.nl/sites/default/files/sn_bijlagen/bep/60-
     Hoogspanningsverbindingen/COBRAcable/Overig/Duits/Cobra-Reichweite-DE-341015.pdf (18 June 2012), p. 29.
86
     Ems-Dollart-Vertrag (fn. 69).
                                                                                                                            18
law”87. Art. 35 (1) S. 2 reads “the German fishery and hunting superintendence officers are

responsible for the German fisher- and huntsmen, the Dutch ones for the Dutch fisher- and

huntsmen.”88 One could deduce from the underlying thought of these two sections that

German authorities could be responsible for German project sponsors and Dutch authorities

for Dutch project sponsors89. Thus, it would have been legal for the Offshore-Windpark

RIFFGAT GmbH & Co. KG to only apply for a permit in Germany.

          Second, the 1996 Ems-Dollart-Umweltprotokoll90 further emphasises this thought

through its Art. 6 (2) S. 2: “This approval [for intended actions that are scientifically harmful to

the area’s environment] is given to Dutchmen and Dutch residents by Dutch [authorities], to

Germans and German residents by German authorities.”91

          Third, and most importantly, there is the supplementary treaty of 196292, which was

ratified due to the discovery of a considerable deposit of natural gas in Groningen, the

Netherlands, that suggested another deposit under the Ems River. In this treaty, Germany

and the Netherlands agreed upon the equal division of both exploration costs and revenues

of the findings (Art. 5 (1), (3)). Furthermore, in Art. 4 (2) they manifest: “The treaty parties

may grant authorizations [to explore and exploit natural resources] that are valid for the

whole area [i.e., the border area that is in dispute], based on their domestic law.”93 As

explained on page 13, producing energy from wind cannot be seen as the exploitation of

natural resources as for example defined in Art. 1 of the said treaty. However, this section

shows that for some administrative tasks, it was agreed upon – by both parties – that one

country itself could authorise works in the disputed area, based on its domestic law. And this

is exactly what Germany had done for the wind park RIFFGAT.

          Concerning the process of finding a solution: the Ems-Dollart-Commission would

have had to be asked for arbitration, in my opinion, to determine on whose territory the wind

87
   Translated from German by author.
88
   Translated from German by author.
89
   Within clearly defined borders, this would not be possible according to Art. 56 (1) UNCLOS; the coastal State alone would
   have jurisdiction. However, since the area discussed here does not clearly belong to the one or the other state, in my opinion,
   a new way to come to a solution for this wind park could be a possibility.
90
   Ems-Dollart-Umweltprotokoll (fn. 73).
91
   Translated from German by author.
92
   Zusatzabkommen Ems-Dollart-Vertrag (fn. 73).
93
   Translated from German by author.
                                                                                                                              19
You can also read