"OBAMACARE AND BEYOND": AN ANALYSIS OF HEALTH CARE COVERAGE IN THE UNITED STATES

Page created by Dustin Patel
 
CONTINUE READING
“OBAMACARE AND BEYOND”: AN
ANALYSIS OF HEALTH CARE COVERAGE
       IN THE UNITED STATES

                       Department: Economics
                                   By Rio Dhat
INTRODUCTION

       The health care system in the United States encompasses so many individuals,

businesses, and interest groups, that it can be difficult to pinpoint the most optimal approach to

serve everyone’s unique needs and wants. An effective policy response must focus on what is

most enriching for the majority: aiming to improve the overall quality of the system and

positively impact the health status of all citizens, while subsequently minimizing costs. The

current organizational structure has clear failings that contribute to a delivery system that lags

behind many other industrialized nations who exhibit a larger amount of state assistance to their

citizens; showing that it is possible to intervene in health care and still maintain a high level of

quality.

       With spiraling expenditures and numerous market distortions affecting the health care

system in America, there seems to be consensus that some amount of change in the insurance

coverage structure is essential. Concerns centered on adverse selection, where overall premium

prices are driven up because of a lack of participation in the market, lie at the heart of the

discussion, and increasing the number of covered individuals from current levels of 83 percent

can attempt to overcome such issues (U.S Census Bureau, 2011). Although there are many

considerations to be made in such a substantial reform, a key aspect of the discussion revolves

around the nature of health care: is it a right, or a privilege? While striving to answer that vital

question, this essay will focus on the government’s responsibilities to its citizens, the merits of

President Obama’s “Affordable Health Care Act”, and consequently the impacts of potential

intervention on the health care market in terms of cost, quality, and overall economic impact.

                                                                                                       1
THE NEED FOR REFORM

       Before the Affordable Health Care Act was established in 2010 and state assistance for

citizens was relatively low, the United States lagged significantly behind all major OECD

nations in key health care indicators, also having the highest amount of expenditure on health

care as a percentage of gross domestic product (WHO, 2013). These results paint a harsh picture

of the health care system in the United States, and contribute to a feeling that change is

imperative. Additionally, as virtually all of these higher-ranking OECD countries provide

universal health care, while also having lower expenditures, it raises the question of why the U.S.

does not participate in a similar type of system, or at least take some aspects of the alternative

market structures prevalent in high-performing nations.

Table 1

Source: OECD Health Data 2012

                                                                                                     2
KEY CONCERNS

       An investigation into the nature of the issues and market failures that befell the health

insurance market prior to the implementation of the Affordable Health Care Act can portray the

limitations of having a largely private marketplace for health care coverage. Adverse selection,

the inflexibility of the market, and negative externalities caused by large numbers of people

without health insurance can be seen as the main problems affecting the industry. These issues

have led to increasingly high expenditures and market distortions that have negatively impacted

the quality of care in the health system.

       Firstly, adverse selection caused by asymmetric information is a considerable problem in

the individual insurance market. Because individuals know more about their health status than

insurers (asymmetric information), inefficient, “risked-based sorting” (Cutler and Zeckhauser,

1997) plans prevail, making it difficult for healthy people to achieve reasonable rates (adverse

selection). This undesirable result arises from the fact that many individuals who are currently

healthy will not buy insurance, but in contrast, sick individuals will often purchase coverage

plans. Consequently, when people with a higher likelihood of becoming sick purchase

insurance, their costs and premiums are correspondingly high, which drives up the prices for all

individuals (both healthy and sick). As a result, the price of health insurance a typical person

would face in the individual market greatly exceeds the average cost of covering that individual.

       Another significant concern in the health insurance market relates directly to the lack of

flexibility and choice over coverage plans, which gives more control to providers, while also dis-

empowering consumers. To eliminate the market failure that results from a provider-favored

market, efforts must be made to reduce the cost and difficulties with individuals who are

compelled to shop for health coverage. The vast number of current plans in the market can make

                                                                                                    3
it problematic for low-income individuals with limited education to purchase the most

appropriate form of insurance, and it can be an arduous process for individuals to switch their

coverage. These factors often lead to consumers choosing plans that do not reflect their best

interests, usually involving higher premiums that disadvantage both the individual and the wider

participant pool.

       To maintain the U.S’ strong economic standing globally, any type of health care reform

must take into account potential affects on businesses. Because of the prominence of employer-

sponsored health insurance, small firms are currently at a large disadvantage to larger businesses.

High administrative costs and concerns among insurers about adverse selection contribute to

higher premiums for smaller employers, which reduces their willingness to offer health insurance

as part of their compensation package to employees. Consequently, this disadvantage can affect

the ability of small businesses to attract quality workers. This market failure associated with

small firms can also lead to broader economic effects, such as a reduced amount of individual

entrepreneurship, due to the risks (high costs of health insurance coverage) of starting up their

own businesses.

ROLE OF GOVERNMENT

       When discussing an ideal approach to solving the issues relating to health care coverage,

the broad role of the government in all markets in the economy must first be defined. Some

individuals, including President Obama, argue that it is an essential mechanism for promoting

economic growth and providing a level of fairness for all American citizens, regardless of socio-

economic status. In contrast, others assert that the government’s main role is to essentially “step

                                                                                                      4
back”, as has been done in the past, and allow the true workings of free market capitalism to play

out to their maximum effect.

        Although proponents of the hands-off concept of government intervention may point to

the benefits of competition and market efficiency, the poor results (both in terms of high costs

and quality of care) prove that this has not worked effectively in America’s health sector. A

long-standing laissez-faire approach in the United States has left a wide and growing gap in

health coverage, with the number of uninsured individuals rising at an ever-increasing rate.

        The newly implemented “Obamacare” health coverage laws aim to achieve both the goal

of expanding coverage to more individuals, and to additionally reduce health care costs

throughout the country. In addition to providing health benefits for low-income citizens, the

reform also claims to enhance the country economically. Operating under the premise that

increasing the number of covered individuals will lead to a more efficient and cost effective

health insurance market, as well as improving the quality of the labor force, the Affordable

Health Care Act attempts to solve market distortions by increasing government intervention in

the provision and management of health insurance.

        When determining the optimal path for health care coverage, (whether public or private,

or a mixture of both) the key functions of the government must be considered. One of the key

responsibilities of the government is to look after the best interests of its citizens; thus it can be

suggested that it is potentially immoral that the state would not assist citizens in need of health

care, if they could not afford private options. Fundamentally, the provision of free (or

subsidized) health care can be argued to be a “moral obligation”, and essentially an action that

the government is compelled to provide to its poorest citizens, given the amount of power those

individuals have instilled in them from the democratic system.

                                                                                                         5
POTENTIAL SOLUTIONS

       Economically, two main considerations can be analyzed relating to health care coverage.

Primarily, the cost of health care is a major concern to government: if it is too high there are

large budgetary consequences, which negatively impacts the Federal Deficit, and also reallocates

capital away from other areas of the economy. Secondly, if the quality of health care services is

poor, there will be detrimental results for the economy, putting downward pressure on economic

growth, because of losses in productivity and output from workers. These aims are consistent

with the objectives of the Affordable Health Care Act implemented by the government in 2010.

       Combating adverse selection in the market should be viewed as a key economic objective

for the government, as it directly contributes to higher premiums, adding to the overall cost of

health care in the United States. The Affordable Health Care Act does attempt to quell this issue

by mandating health insurance to all individuals (apart from those in financial hardship).

Consequently, moving from the current system to one with widespread participation would bring

healthy and sick individuals together in the market, forcing premiums down, and thus decreasing

overall expenditure on health care. The Council of Economic Advisors assess that this

participation would lower the cost of health insurance by around 20 percent, or $1000 per

person, which would reduce the expenditure as a percentage of GDP approximately 0.3 percent

(CEA, 2009). In essence, the government’s proposal looks to solve the problem of adverse

selection by increasing the number of individuals in the market, thereby creating more affordable

insurance costs for all involved. (CEA, 2009).

       Improving the functioning of the health insurance market to ensure that providers are not

taking advantage of consumers should also be an ambition for the government. The Affordable

Health Care Act strives to solve the issue of a producer favored market by introducing

                                                                                                    6
“Affordable Insurance Exchanges”, which aim to provide consumers with added protection from

providers: allowing premiums to be jointly negotiated, increasing information about the design

of the plans, and coordinating risk adjustment to reduce insurer’s risk in the event of adverse

selection within the exchange (CEA, 2009). As such, the improved flow of knowledge regarding

the policies from the insurance providers would allow consumers to make more efficient choices

and lead to decreased costs. Additionally, the standardized application forms and streamlined

insurance purchases may also reduce the growth of administrative costs, which are currently a

major factor of health care expenditure in the U.S (Health Care Cost Institute, 2010).

       When determining government-assisted strategies to improve the coverage system it is

crucial that competition continues to be key principle of its overall efficiency. Many other

countries have had success with universal health care plans, although there is a fear that such a

transformation would reduce quality in the market, due to the reduction of competition that

would occur. Fundamentally, the Affordable Insurance Exchange attempts to improve

competitiveness in the private market, even though it is a state run program. In theory, the

exchange will make it easier for individuals and small businesses to compare private qualified

health plans, which would force businesses to either increase the quality of the plans, or reduce

prices (or both). Consequentially, this proposal has the potential to generate greater efficiencies

in the marketing and distribution of coverage, which could lead to lower premiums and higher

coverage rates.

       Another large distortion of the current health system is the enormous financial risk many

uninsured individuals face. Because a large percentage of personal bankruptcies in America

result from high medical expenses, any reduction to this number can benefit the economy (U.S.

Courts, 2012). Increasing coverage by providing exchanges, subsidizing low-income

                                                                                                      7
individuals, and removing pre-existing condition clauses can allow individuals to purchase

policies that administer coverage for extremely high expenses. In essence, the reduction of

financial risk for uninsured individuals would allow benefits to be seen in the wider economy, as

these people would be able to spend more of their income of other consumer goods and services,

increasing the nation’s GDP.

       In many countries with a mixture of private and public health care, there are concerns that

public patients receive lower quality care than privately insured individuals. This was a major

objection raised by political opponents in congressional debates concerning the “Obamacare”

plan. Additionally, some studies suggest that many health providers offset financial losses that

occur from treating uninsured individuals through providing lower quality care than for that

given to insured patients (Daysal, 2009). This research provides empirical support for claims

that the optimal policy response should indeed focus on expanding private health insurance

coverage, as failure to do so will lead to inequalities in care for a large number of people.

Additionally, the health benefits of coverage expansions would not be limited to the uninsured.

For contagious diseases such as influenza, quality care for more individuals would prevent the

spread of the illness to others, which would allow them to continue working and being

productive members of the economy. This positive externality shows that an expansive and “all

inclusive” approach to healthcare can benefit the entire economy, and not just the uninsured.

                                                                                                   8
LABOR MARKET EFFECTS

       A large number of the uninsured individuals are currently in the American workforce,

and their health is paramount to overall productivity of the economy, with estimates suggesting

over 48 million people are without coverage in the country (U.S. Census Bureau, 2012). If the

health status of these individuals were to improve, more people would be able to work, and those

who were in the labor force would be more productive. With increased access to insurance and

health care, many of the uninsured presently not healthy enough to maintain employment would

be able to participate in the workforce. Studies have found that the 17 million disabled

individuals in America are three times more likely to be out of the labor force than healthy

people (CEA, 2009). Any reduction in this number would improve the labor force participation

rate. As such, if more individuals were in the workforce, the overall capacity of the economy

would increase, allowing more goods and services to be produced.

       The ever-growing group of uninsured older workers in the economy would also directly

benefit from easier access to health care coverage (through subsidized plans, insurance

exchanges, etc.). Enabling pre-Medicare eligible individuals to maintain their health status to

ensure they can continue participating in the labor force is important for their well-being. If

these individuals were able to work for a longer time period, they would expand their years of

earning wages. In turn, savings and retirement income would increase, as well as Federal

income and tax revenue. In addition to these financial benefits for the government, Federal

expenses would also be decreased, because the number of people receiving Social Security

Disability Insurance would be reduced, lowering the government’s social financial strain in the

long term.

                                                                                                  9
Workplace productivity is another way in which improved access to health insurance and

medical care could positively affect labor supply through decreased absenteeism. Healthier

individuals would be more likely to show up at work, and this would allow firms to produce

more output. This is a large problem for the economy because absenteeism has been proven to

have extremely high long-run indirect costs through losses in productivity. Many of the costliest

conditions (such as depression) can often be efficiently managed with prescription medications,

made more affordable by health insurance (CEA, 2009). Essentially, the expansion in coverage

proposed by the Affordable Health Care Act would lead to important gains in workplace

productivity from improved health care.

        Although the new government plan, in theory, will positively affect the provisioning of

health insurance, there are a number of concerns with the act’s policies. Because the Affordable

Health Care Act subsidizes insurance premiums for low-income individuals and families that are

newly insured, the policy may create incentives to stay in a low-income situation, thus reducing

motivation to join the workforce. With the new baseline for Medicaid being raised to 133 percent

of the poverty level, some individuals may find it more cost-effective to stay below this baseline,

and receive complementary care (CEA, 2009). Fundamentally, the government must ensure that

costs of private insurance stay relatively low, to ensure individuals still strive to enter the

workforce, and increase their incomes.

        The provision of heath insurance through employers is the most prominent form of

coverage in the U.S.; thus effective reform has the ability to improve the actual efficiency of the

labor market. Presently, due to limitations relating to pre-existing conditions, many workers that

may desire a change in jobs choose not to, out of concern that they would lose access access to

insurance coverage or face less comprehensive policies elsewhere. A more flexible system

                                                                                                  10
would allow for many of these workers to migrate to jobs where they would be more productive,

thus increasing labor market efficiency in the economy. The Affordable Health Care Act seeks

to provide this flexibility, through both the removal of pre-existing conditions, and the

introduction of the Affordable Insurance Exchange, which also enables a greater deal of choice

for workers.

         If nothing is done to improve the functioning of the health insurance system, there could

be severe consequences for the overall efficiency of the labor market. In concrete terms, one

study approximates that individuals would be around 25 percent less likely to change jobs if

were to lose health insurance (CEA, 2009). This figure shows that many people in the economy

would choose to stay in jobs for a longer period of time, when instead they could move to other

areas, where they could operate with greater efficiency.

INTERNATIONAL COMPARISON

         An alternative method of determining the most optimal coverage system is to consider

the approaches world leaders in health care have embraced. Despite the fact that there have been

no major rankings since 2000, the World Health Organization’s top five countries from the

health system rankings at that time were all shown to include some function of universal health

insurance provided by the government, along with a steady mixture of private coverage (WHO,

2000).

         Although the designation is controversial, the World Health Organization named France

as the world leader in health care in 2000. As such, a measured comparison between America

and France can offer critical answers to the coverage debate. In terms of the key health indicators

(life expectancy, infant mortality rate, mortality rate, and fertility rate), France vastly

                                                                                                 11
outperforms the U.S., while also having a lower health care expenditure per capita (WHO, 2012).

Additionally, around 95 percent of French citizens are covered by government healthcare

through the Universal Health Coverage Act (CMU), through one of three main schemes (Sandier

et al, 2004). In comparison to the U.S, the remaining 5 percent of citizens are covered by

alternative, private policies.

        Control of health care expenditures is a major concern in the U.S., while in France it is a

heavily regulated area, with strong government controls. Each year the French parliament passes

an Act on Social Security Funding based on the reports of the Accounts Commission, and the

National Health Conference (Sandier et al, 2004). The benefits from the report include: a

“ceiling” for health insurance spending for the following year, a report on trends in health care

policy, and the establishment of separate funds for developing pharmaceuticals and the

modernization of hospitals (Sandier et al, 2004). From a financial standpoint, the “hands on”

approach of the French government, (as opposed to the laissez-faire system in America) suggests

that a more efficient allocation of capital can arise from the centralization of decisions relating to

health care expenditures.

        Quality of care is a secondary area where the French health system is superior to the

American structure. This may be due in part to the majority of the population being covered by

health insurance, but can also be attributed to the importance of “The Ministry of Health”, the

state agency responsible for over-seeing the overall structure. The government’s central health

division approves base agreements from health insurance companies to ensure that they comply

with the regulatory framework established by parliament (Sandier et al, 2004). In doing so, the

power of coverage providers is reduced, allowing consumers to benefit from fair, cost-effective

plans. Essentially, because the French provide a higher amount of state assistance to citizens,

                                                                                                    12
universal rules can be applied, which lead to policies that encompass the interests of the

majority.

ECONOMIC EFFECTS

           The most reliable estimates currently suggest 48.6 million individuals are without health

care (U.S. Census Bureau, 2011). Bringing a larger number of individuals to participate in the

market will positively affect the country as whole. Since government spending on

uncompensated care (services without reimbursement) is approximately $43 billion (over 0.3

percent of GDP) a reduction to this figure would greatly reduce the Federal burden on health

care. Consequently, with an expansion in coverage to an additional 32 million individuals (as

aimed for by the plan), the government would benefit from large savings that it could allocate to

other areas of the economy. In essence, when combined with the reductions in individuals’ health

insurance costs per year of around $1000, the removal of these distortions by the Affordable

Health Care Act can discard around 0.6 percent of GDP of wasted expenses (CEA, 2009), and

thus increase overall economic efficiency in the U.S. Furthermore, without such a measure

designed to increase participation in the private marketplace, both adverse selection and

uncompensated care costs would increase over time, as the number of uninsured would continue

to rise.

           It is also important to consider the overall cost of increasing government intervention in

health care when analyzing the merits of the reform. Recent estimates suggest that the total cost

of providing health insurance coverage to the uninsured, taking into account the decreases in

spending that would occur (uncompensated care, etc.), would be roughly $125 billion per year,

dispersed among individuals, states and the Federal government (CEA, 2009). However, because

                                                                                                    13
these costs are budgeted to come from increased state revenue and savings in the Federal budget,

there will be no major concerns of increasing insurance coverage, on the deficit.

        The ultimate measure of policy efficiency is for the benefits to outweigh the costs; thus

the Affordable Health Care Act must be measured by how well it performs from a financial

standpoint, as well as for quality factors. Putting a monetary value on improvements in citizen’s

health statuses is key information when evaluating overall benefits. Expansions in health

insurance to previously uninsured individuals lead to significant reductions in overall mortality

and infant mortality, from the increased utilization of medical care (Currie and Gruber, 1996).

Due to lives that would be saved, and the increased quality of life that would occur for many

other individuals, a positive value to the economy of around $180 billion a year has been

estimated from the increased coverage (CEA, 2009). In essence, the actual lives saved represent

a financial benefit to the economy, allowing more individuals to work and contribute to firms

producing goods and services for a longer period of time. Additionally from a moral standpoint,

every extra life that is saved as a result of the policy supports the notion that the government is

fulfilling an obligation to its citizens, which is a strong political driver of support.

CONCLUSION

        The American health system has the potential to be among the greatest in the world; able

to utilize its large population, physical resource base, and strong financial capital. However,

analyzing the key economic, moral, and political factors regarding health coverage, there is no

doubt that the current structure in the U.S. is in need of reform now more than ever. Although

there will be continual arguments over whether the provision of health insurance is a privilege or

a right, simple comparisons with other OECD countries (such as in table 1) show that the United

                                                                                                      14
States has a considerable task ahead if it is to reduce expenditures, and raise the quality of care in

the nation.

       Expanding coverage for 32 million individuals, as planned under the Affordable Health

Act, will directly affect the growing cost of health care in America. The reduction in

expenditures is a key factor in the government’s new reform. The expansion of coverage will

remove many of the market distortions in the health insurance industry by simply increasing the

participant pool. If the issues of adverse selection are subdued (as planned), all individuals in the

market will be able to benefit from lower premiums, and better choice of plans. The

implementation of subsidized coverage, as well as the Affordable Insurance Exchange, and

removals of limitations on conditions are all positive steps to control cost growth. If these

provisions are implemented effectively in future years, Federal expenditures will decrease,

positively impacting national savings levels, thus reducing the government’s considerably large

financial strain regarding health care.

        The cost-benefit analysis that has been completed also points to a positive result of

expansion of coverage to the economy. From the CEA report in 2009, there stands to be a gain of

around $75 billion to $125 billion per year from the increase, taking into affect labor market

gains, decreased expenditures, and reduced individual financial risk. Essentially, from a long-

term standpoint, there are more financial benefits than costs to the economy of expanding

coverage. Consequentially, the non-measurable gains to the low-income individuals that would

benefit from the reform also support the notion that the moral and political responsibilities of the

government are being fulfilled, enabling citizens to truly benefit from an equal sense of

entitlement.

                                                                                                   15
References

"Bankruptcy Statistics." United States Courts. U.S. Government. Web. 22 Feb 2013.

Currie, Janet and J Gruber. “Health Insurance Eligibility, Utilization of Medical Care, and Child
Health,” Quarterly journal of Economics, 1996: 431-466

Cutler, David M. and Richard J. Zeckhauser. "Adverse Selection In Health Insurance," Forum
for Health Economics and Policy, 1998, v1, Article 2.

Daysal, Meltem. “Does Uninsurance Affect the Health Outcomes of the Insured? Evidence from
Heart Attack Patients in California,” University of Maryland, 2009

"Health Care Cost and Utilization Report: 2010." Health Care Cost Institution. `. (2012).Web. 22
Feb. 2013.

"OECD Health Data 2012 How Does the United States Compare." OECD, Web. 22 Feb 2013.

Sandier S, Paris V, Polton D. “Health care systems in transition: France”. WHO Regional Office
for Europe on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies, 2004.

United States. Council of Economic Advisers. Economic Case For Health Care Reform. 2009.
Web.

World Health Organization. The World Health Report 2000- Health Systems: Improving
Performance. 2000. Web.

World Health Organization. World Health Statistics 2012. 2013. Web.

Walt, Carmen, Bernadette Proctor, and Jessica Smith. "Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance
Coverage in the United States: 2010." U.S. CENSUS BUREAU. 2011: 60-239. Web. 22 Feb.
2013.

                                                                                               16
You can also read