Lowering Generic Drug Prices Less Regulation Equals More Competition

Page created by Aaron Delgado
 
CONTINUE READING
MEDICAL CARE
Volume 41, Number 1, pp 135–141
©2003 Lippincott Williams & Wilkins, Inc.

                                  Lowering Generic Drug Prices
                           Less Regulation Equals More Competition

                 ASLAM H. ANIS, PHD, DAPHNE P. GUH, MSC,            AND   JOHN WOOLCOTT, MA

   BACKGROUND. In Ontario, Canada, the 70/90               as the number of generic firms increased
regulations were instituted in May 1993 to                 within these periods. However, this decrease
establish provincial government procurement                in P was significantly less in the AP (median:
prices for generic drugs. Accordingly, the first           0.75 f 0.68 f 0.67) than in BP (0.71 f 0.61 f
generic entrant’s price could not exceed 70% of            0.53) as the number of generics increased from
the incumbent’s branded price. Subsequent                  1 to 2 to 3, respectively. The regression analysis
entrants’ prices could not exceed 90% of the               showed that the price ratio in the AP was
first entrant’s price.                                     higher than that in the BP by 0.05, 0.09, and 0.13
   OBJECTIVE. These regulations’ impact on ge-             for first, second, and third generic entrant
neric market competitiveness are evaluated.                respectively.
   DESIGN and METHODS. Data on 518 drugs                      CONCLUSIONS. Our findings show that the
spanning nine therapeutic classifications were             70/90 regulations not only failed to achieve
collected for the period of 04/01/1987 to 12/31/           their goal of lowering the procurement price
1998 from Ontario Drug Benefit formulary and               but instead the opposite occurred. The man-
IMS Canada. The period 04/01/1987 to 04/30/                dated procurement price became a focal point
1993 was defined as the before period (BP) and             and resulted in a clustering of prices around
05/01/1993 to 12/31/1998 was the after period              the maximum allowable levels with little price
(AP). We compared the price ratio (P ⴝ PG/PB)              dispersion.
between BP and AP and performed regression                    Key words: Drug policy; drug price regula-
analysis to assess the determinants of P.                  tion; generic market competitiveness. (Med
   RESULTS. P in both the BP and AP decreased              Care 2003;41:135–141)

   When available, the use of generic as opposed to        natives. This may be because of the lower costs of
brand prescription drugs can significantly reduce          production associated with generics who do not
costs for drug insurance plans. Additionally, price        have to incur R&D costs and the increased compe-
regulation is often used to further reduce costs.          tition which results after the expiry of the branded
Often drug price regulation is tied to drug substitu-      products’ patent. This process is facilitated by regu-
tion laws to redirect dispensing toward cheaper            lations that attempt to lower generic prices while
generics from more expensive branded drugs. His-           increasing generic competition.
torically the prices of generic drugs are significantly        Although well intentioned, price regulations are
lower than the prices of the relevant branded alter-       often poorly conceived. Several studies have doc-

   From the Department of Health Care and Epidemi-            Address correspondence and reprint requests to:
ology, University of British Columbia, Centre for Health   Aslam H. Anis, PhD, CHEOS, 620-1081 Burrard St.,
Evaluation & Outcome Sciences, St. Paul’s Hospital,        Vancouver, B.C., Canada, V6Z 1Y6. E-mail:
Vancouver, British Columbia.                               anis@cheos.ubc.ca
   An earlier version of this paper was presented at the
3rd World Conference of International Health Econom-          Received October 12, 2001; initial review December
ics Association, July 22 to 25, 2001, York, UK.            14, 2001; accepted July 12, 2002.

                                                                                                            135
ANIS ET AL                                                                                        MEDICAL CARE

umented the association between price regula-              may be charged by manufacturers. Under the
tions and a rise in the average price of generic           regulations, a generic drug manufacturer wanting
drugs and a reduced dispersion of prices that              their product to be eligible for reimbursement
normally existed between generics.1–3                      under the ODB plan must first have their product
    In a typical marketplace, free and unfettered          listed as interchangeable under the Drug Inter-
exchange between suppliers and demanders of                changeability and Dispensing Fee Act (DIDFA)
goods and services occurs on a regular basis. No           and listed on the ODB Formulary. To be listed, the
rules or regulation are necessary for the smooth           price of the generic drug cannot exceed a specified
functioning of such markets. The equilibrium price         (maximum) level with respect to the branded
of the competitive market ensures that there is            manufacturer’s price. The 70/90 regulations stipu-
neither “excess”demand nor supply in the market.           lated that the first generic entrants’ price could not
With numerous buyers and sellers these markets             exceed 70% of the incumbent branded product
are assumed to be competitive, and any attempts            price. Subsequent entrants could not price their
to raise prices above the competitive equilibrium          product at greater than 90% of the first entrants’
level would be unsustainable because the compe-            price, which essentially limits the subsequent en-
tition would attract all the business. The market          trants’ price to be at most 63% of the relevant
for prescription pharmaceuticals does not, how-            branded product price.
ever, resemble the competitive market scenario.                The 70/90 regulations were first introduced as
First, for the most part, there are few, rather than       the 75/90 regulations in May 1993 and were
numerous sellers. Second, the demanders (physi-            subsequently amended and became the 70/90
cians) are not consumers, and furthermore often            regulations in November 1998 (see Appendix A.
the demanders and consumers are not the pur-               Table 1). The only difference between the 75/90
chasers. This creates a market imperfection where          regulations and the 70/90 regulations is that under
the ramifications of price changes are not directly        the former, the first entrant had to offer a 25%
felt by the consumers and therefore have negligi-          discount on the incumbents’ branded product,
ble effects on demand. Thus, a rationale for im-           which under the latter was increased to 30%. The
plementing price regulation exists.                        objective of this study was to evaluate the impact
    In the province of Ontario, Canada, for the past       of these regulations, and given that the current
three decades, Drug Product Selection/Substitu-            regulation is known as the 70/90 regulation, we
tion (DPS) laws, have been enforced regarding              refer to these regulations as the 70/90 regulations
price, interchangeability, legal liability, etc. for all   on generic market competitiveness throughout the
eligible prescription drugs.4 The Ontario Drug             remainder of the text.
Benefit (ODB) publishes a formulary listing of all             Parenthetically it should be noted that in 1991
eligible drug products and the price for each              pharmacoeconomic guidelines were introduced in
dosage form that will be paid directly to pharma-          Ontario.6 However, these guidelines applied spe-
cists when the drug is dispensed to anyone cov-            cifically to new drugs seeking ODB formulary
ered by the provincial plan. The drug cost for             inclusion. Branded products already on the ODB
multiple-source drugs was determined as the low-           formulary and generic products (existing or new
est price submitted to the formulary by any eligible       entrants) were exempt.
manufacturer and was designated as the Best
Available Price (BAP). For single-source drugs, the
BAP referred to the only price submitted to the                       Materials and Methods
formulary. The philosophy of the BAP-type system
was to force suppliers of multiple-source drugs to            To assess the impact of the 70/90 regulations,
compete among each other by submitting low-                we compared the price ratio between the relevant
price bids. By designating the lowest-price bid as         generic and branded drug products launched be-
the BAP and additionally requiring pharmacists             fore and after the regulations. A sample of drug
via substitution legislation to substitute all pre-        products listed under the ODB Formulary between
scriptions for the cheaper BAP products, it was            April 1, 1987 to December 31, 1998 was selected
hoped that a substantial cost savings could be             from the following therapeutic classifications: car-
achieved.5                                                 diovascular drugs, antiarthritics, psychotherapeu-
    The 70/90 regulations specifically govern the          tics, antiinfectives, analgesics, neurologic disor-
pricing of generic drugs and limit the prices that         ders, cholesterol reducing/lipotropic drugs,

136
Vol. 41, No. 1                                                             DRUG PRICE REGULATIONS

proprietary analgesics, and diuretics. These thera-    first generic product over the branded product, the
peutic classifications together accounted for more     ratio of the second generic entrant over the
than 50.5% of the prescriptions written in Canada      branded product and the ratio of the third generic
for 1999.7 The ODB Formulary, updated and pub-         entrant over the branded product.
lished periodically, contained information regard-         Occasionally, the market in the before and after
ing the interchangeable drug categories and pric-      periods changed from a situation of one branded
ing data for all drug products. Additional data        firm to a situation of one branded and two generic
regarding launch dates of individual generic prod-     firms without the intermediate case of one
ucts was obtained from the Drugstore and Hospi-        branded and one generic firm. Similarly, there also
tal Database constructed by IMS Canada.                were instances where the market changed from
   The study sample was primarily selected based       the situation of one branded and one generic firm,
on the availability of the data. A pharmacist re-      to one branded and three or more generic firms
viewed the database and some inconsistencies           directly. When this occurred, the price ratios of first
with respect to launch dates were found. These         generic product, second generic product and/or
inconsistencies related primarily to situations        second generic product over branded product
where: (1) for the same drug product, multiple         would not be available. Furthermore, because we
drug manufacturers were named because of li-           did not have pricing data before April 1987, no
censing arrangements between parties; or (2) a         price ratios could be calculated when more than
new drug information number was subsequently           three generic products within the same inter-
issued for an existing drug product as the new         changeable drug category were already present in
drug information number may have been issued           the market before April 1987.
because of a change in the manufacturing site or a         The precise expiry date of each patent during
change in the source of raw materials for the drug     the study period was not available to us. Patent
product. In these circumstances, these observa-        expiry was inferred from generic entry. The num-
tions were excluded from the study. Also excluded      ber of first, second, or third generic entrants is
were generic products owned by branded firms           governed entirely by patent expires, market size
known as “fighting generics” or “pseudo-               and entry conditions. To observe that there were
generics.” They were excluded from the analysis        more first entrants in either period is a function of
because they do not typically compete with the         both the number of patent expires, and the profit
incumbent branded firm. On the contrary, these         potential of generic entrants, which, among other
“pseudo-generics” allow the owner of the patent        factors would be a function of market size in the
(branded firm) to segment the market in a manner       relevant therapeutic category.
that maximizes their revenues from both the brand          Univariate analysis using nonparametric
version and generic version.                           (distribution-free) Wilcoxon rank sum test was
   As the regulations were first introduced in May     performed to compare PG/PB in the before period
1993, the period between April 1, 1987 and April       versus the after period.4 We chose the Wilcoxon
30, 1993 was defined as the before period while        rank sum test, which tests the hypothesis that the
the period between May 1, 1993 and December 31,        distributions of the two populations are the same
1998 was defined as the after period. Each generic     because our data are skewed.
drug product was classified as being launched in           Multiple regression analysis was additionally
the before period or in the after period. The order    performed to identify the determinants of the ratio
at which each generic drug product launched            of price. In the final regression model, the vari-
within each interchangeable drug category was          ables included were the period at which the
also determined from its launched date.                generic product was launched (before period or
   For each generic product, the price ratio, which    after period), the number of generic product exist-
was defined as the price of generic product over       ing in the market the generic product (0, 1, 2), their
the price of branded product (PG/PB) in the same       interaction term, and the therapeutic classification.
interchangeable drug category, was calculated. We      The regression model was estimated using Gen-
used the first available pricing data for both the     eralized Estimating Equations approach because
generic and branded products in the same edition       when generic products were from the same inter-
of the Formulary after the launch date of the          changeable drug category, the price of these
generic product to calculate PG/PB. Three types of     branded products would contribute to more than
price ratio were examined in our study: the ratio of   one price ratio and these ratios may not be con-

                                                                                                         137
ANIS ET AL                                                                                         MEDICAL CARE

sidered as independent observations.8 A simple               TABLE 1. Summary of Price Ratio by Generic
exploratory analysis was also performed to check if           Entrant Before and After Price Regulations
there is an increasing trend of price ratios over
                                                                                     Estimated Price Ratio
time for first, second, and third entrants                                                 (PG/PB)
respectively.
                                                                                     04/01/87-   05/01/93-
                                                           Comparison                04/30/93    12/31/98    P
                                                                        st
                      Results                              Branded vs. 1 generic
                                                             N                           52          19
    A total of 125 branded drug products (ie, 125            Mean                       0.70        0.73
interchangeable drug categories) and 510 generic             SD                         0.13        0.03
products were selected. Of those, 19 branded drug            Median                     0.71        0.75   0.42
products had only one generic product competing              Q1–Q3                   0.64–0.75   0.71–0.75
in the market during the study period, 23 with               Range                   0.32–1.00   0.67–0.75
                                                           Branded vs. 2nd generic
two, 37 with three, 32 with four, and 14 with more
                                                             N                           56          22
than four competing generic products. Because of             Mean                       0.55        0.71
the availability of the pricing data as explained            SD                         0.21        0.13
earlier, the number of price ratios we were able to          Median                     0.61        0.68   0.01
obtain was 71, 78, and 69 for first, second, and             Q1–Q3                   0.47–0.71   0.67–0.75
third entrant, respectively. Out of a total of 125, we       Range                   0.05–0.90   0.46–1.11
only had 71 first entrant prices because 47 of the         Branded vs. 3rd generic
remaining 54 cases resulted in a market where two            N                           33          36
generics entered simultaneously and for the re-              Mean                       0.50        0.65
maining seven cases, the branded drug was un-                SD                         0.21        0.08
                                                             Median                     0.53        0.67   0.0001
listed and its price was no longer available. In total,
                                                             Q1–Q3                   0.38–0.60   0.60–0.67
23 branded drugs were excluded for the reasons               Range                   0.04–0.95   0.46–0.90
listed in the previous section; 21 were launched in
the before period whereas two were launched in
the after period. Among the excluded branded
products, 11 (all in the before period) were               before period by 0.05, 0.09, and 0.13 for first,
“pseudo-generics”.                                         second, and third generic entrant, respectively.
    Table 1 and Figure 1 present the summary               Moreover, as the number of generic product in-
statistics and box plots of the price ratio between a      creases from 1 to 2 and 3, the price ratio decreases
new generic product and the respective branded             in the before period by 0.08 and 0.16 whereas it
product according to the before period and after           only decreases in the after period by 0.04 and 0.08,
period. It shows that the price ratio in both the          respectively. The results of the multivariate analy-
before period and the after period decreased as the        sis resolve that a significant degree of change in
number of existing generic products increases.             the price ratio (PG/PB) can be attributed to the
However, the data clearly show that this decrease          period in which the generic drug was introduced.
in price ratio is substantially less in the after period   These findings, like those of the univariate analy-
than in the before period. Additionally, the sub-          sis, are consistent with the hypothesis that the
stantially smaller spread of the price ratio in the        pricing regulations have the intended effect of
after period suggests that the generic products in         raising generic prices.
the after period were priced at the level close to
what the regulation set. However, in the before
period, many generic products were priced at a                                Discussion
much lower level. Additionally, plots of price ratios
over time by generic entry did not reveal signifi-            Our findings suggest that Ontario’s 70/90 Reg-
cant trends.                                               ulations failed to achieve their goal of lowering the
    The results from the regression analysis are           cost of generic drugs for the ODB plan. The
presented in Table 2. The results suggested that           generic marketplace appears to be an inherently
after the therapeutic class being adjusted, the price      competitive marketplace in which there is a natu-
ratio in the after period was higher than that in the      ral, market-imposed pressure on the first generic

138
Vol. 41, No. 1                                                               DRUG PRICE REGULATIONS

                                                                                     FIG. 1. Price ratio by order
                                                                                     of generic entry.

entrant to not set prices too high and as the            such that all generics are treated as a homogenous
number of competitors increases with entry of            good. That is generic firm specific prices do not
additional generic firms, prices are driven down-        exist. All generics are paid the same reimburse-
ward. The data also suggests that in the after           ment amount, the BAP. Hence, cutting prices does
period, the decrease in price ratio caused by in-        not necessarily generate market to the firm cutting
creased number of generic firms is much lower,           the price but that all generics in the specific market
which is supportive of the premise that price            now receive a lower reimbursement.
controls have interfered with natural competitive           More generally speaking, the lowest submitted
forces. The question that must then be addressed         price was designated as the BAP, yet the submit-
by policy makers is, whether there is a role for         ting bidder did not get any special rights as the
regulation in the market of post patent pharma-          sole supplier at this bid. All generics were allowed
ceuticals? The answer which this paper along with        to supply at this price. This led to a flawed process
others show that to date the stated goals of             for generating competitive bids and the addition of
legislation are not being met and therefore differ-      the 70/90 regulations did not alter this basic flaw,
ent approaches should be explored.1–3,8,9                ie, lowest bidder did not get the sole supplier
   It is our contention that the 70/90 regulations       contract.5
created a focal point for setting the initial price of      As illustrated by Caves et al,11 in unregulated
any generic product. A potential generic entrant         markets, generics were found to be priced approx-
has no incentive to submit a price lower than the        imately 60% less than branded products facing
mandated ceiling price because, given inelastic          only one generic competitor. In addition, the paper
demand and substitution legislation, it is the profit    showed that the greater the number of generics in
maximizing price except for instances where entry        the market the lower the generic prices. Using
is unprofitable. The preceding is similar to the         Canadian data within the context of formulary
effect of implementing price caps or cost ceilings.10    pricing similar to the ODB framework, Anis5 dem-
Furthermore, the nature of the generic market is         onstrated a similar result. Using six countries (US,

                                                                                                            139
ANIS ET AL                                                                                          MEDICAL CARE

     TABLE 2. Estimated Coefficients of the                   this regulation led the price of branded products
    Regression Model* on Price Ratio (PG/PB)                  facing generic competition to increase and generic
                                    Estimated
                                                              firms also raising their prices with fewer firms
Variable                          Coefficient (SE)     P      entering the market. When faced with entry price
                                                              regulation, Abbot3 noted that branded firms, given
After May, 1993                     0.05 (0.03)      0.11     their monopoly power, set launch prices 50%
No. of existing generic product    ⫺0.04 (0.01)      0.003    higher than they would in an unregulated market.
Interaction                         0.04 (0.02)      0.04        A limitation of our study is that because the
Therapeutic classification                                    ODB Formulary was normally updated and pub-
  Cardiovascular                     0.52 (0.03)     0.0001   lished semi-annually, the drug prices listed could
  Antiarthritics                     0.47 (0.03)     0.0001   be different from the launch price of those phar-
  Psychotherapeutic                  0.37 (0.05)     0.0001   maceuticals. Also, we did not look at the usage
  Antiinfectives                     0.50 (0.03)     0.0001   levels of the generic products to analyze whether
  Analgesics                         0.54 (0.04)     0.0001   the 70/90 regulations had an effect on usage levels.
  Neurological disorders             0.47 (0.05)     0.0001   Another issue that was beyond the scope of this
  Cholesterol/lipotropic             0.65 (0.03)     0.0001   paper was the impact of the 70/90 regulations in
  Proprietary analgesics             0.44 (0.01)     0.0001   preventing generic entry. This would occur if
                                                              branded firms were to price their products below
   N ⫽ 218.
                                                              the normal levels or if the mandatory discount
   *Pearson Goodness-of-Fit statistic over its degrees
of freedom is 1.06.                                           prevented potential entrants from being able to
                                                              feasibly making a profit. A lack of a control group
                                                              was another limitation of this study and we real-
UK, Denmark, Holland, Germany, and South Af-                  ized that there might be some confounding factor
rica) with varying levels of pricing freedom with             that caused the differences in the price ratios
respect to new product pricing, Reekie2 compared              between periods. Because Ontario is the largest
pricing of the top five products. He showed that in           market in Canada, Ontario generic prices were
markets with greater pricing freedom, competition             likely to be applicable to the rest of the country as
created by rival products lowered the price of                well. Therefore, even though the 70/90 regulations
medicines.                                                    were specific to Ontario, other provinces in Can-
   The Gordon Commission report),13 which in-                 ada could not be used as controls. Because the
vestigated drug pricing in Ontario was particularly           regulation originally restricted the first generic at
critical of the failure of the ODB formulary prices           75% of the branded product, we have observed
to reflect the true acquisition cost of drugs and             price ratios of first generic entrant to the branded
referred to this practice as “spread pricing.” Ac-            product over 0.70 and close to 0.75. However, we
cording to this practice, manufacturers included a            believed that subsequent amendments to the pric-
margin over cost in their price submission to the
                                                              ing restrictions that set the maximum price ceiling
formulary in attempts to prompt pharmacists to
                                                              for the first generic at 70% instead of 75% of the
price select in their favor ie, choose to dispense
                                                              incumbent’s price, were merely incidental to the
their particular drug product.13 Lexchin9 found
                                                              original change in paradigm in 1993.
that indeed the greater the level of competition
                                                                 Finally, with previous studies showing that
and consequently the greater the number of pro-
ducers the smaller is the spread and consequently             prices resulting from Ontario’s BAP-type of for-
the lower the cost of drugs.                                  mulary not being competitive5,8,13 and the anti-
   Similar to the 70/90 regulations, the Omnibus              competitive effects of the 70/90 regulations dem-
Budget Reconciliation Act of 1990 (OBRA 1990)                 onstrated in this study, the spill-over effects of
allowed Medicaid (US federally funded health                  these regulations on other Canadian provinces
insurance program) to adopt a most-favored-                   needs to be considered. Given that Ontario is the
customer rule with respect to pharmaceutical pur-             largest market in Canada, the impact of the 70/90
chases.12 The OBRA 1990 allowed Medicaid to                   regulations could result in increased generic drug
purchase pharmaceuticals at a given percentage                prices across the country. This is a concern that
below average price if the best price was not low             should not be ignored by policy makers both
enough. It has been shown by Scott-Morton1 that               within and outside of the Ontario market.

140
Vol. 41, No. 1                                                                DRUG PRICE REGULATIONS

              Acknowledgments                             Ontario and Canada. Pharmacoeconomics 1993;
                                                          3:354 –361.
   The authors acknowledge the assistance of Dianne         7. IMS Health. Canadian Pharmaceutical Industry
Calbick, and IMS Canada in researching and preparation    Review. Pointe Claire, Quebec; 2000.
of this manuscript.                                          8. Liang KY, and Zeger SL. Longitudinal data
                                                          analysis using generalized linear models. Biometrika
                                                          1986;73:13–22.
                   References                                9. Lexchin J. Effect of generic drug competition on
                                                          the price of prescription drugs in Ontario. CMAJ
   1. Scott-Morton F. The strategic response by phar-
                                                          1993;148:35–39.
maceutical firms to the Medicaid most-favored-
customer rules. Rand J Econ 1997;28:269–290.                 10. Laffont J, Tirole J. A theory of incentives in
                                                          procurement and regulation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press;
   2. Reekie WD. How competition lowers the costs
                                                          1993:75–76.
of medicines. Pharmacoeconomics 1998;14(Supp 1):107–
113.                                                         11. Caves RE, Whinston MD, Hurwitz MA.
                                                          Patent, expiration, entry, and competition in the US
    3. Abbott TA. Price regulation in the pharmaceu-
                                                          pharmaceutical industry. Brookings Papers on Economic
tical industry: Prescription or placebo? J Health Econ    Activity, Microeconomics 1991;1– 48.
1995;14:551–565.
                                                            12. US Congress, Office of Technology Assess-
  4. Anis AH. Substitution law, insurance coverage,       ment. Pharmaceutical R&D: Costs, risks and rewards.
and generic drug use. Med Care 1994;32:240 –256.          Washington DC: US Government Printing Office;
   5. Anis AH. Pharmaceutical prices with insurance       OTA-H- 1993:522.
coverage and formularies. Can J Econ 1992;25:420 – 437.      13. Gordon JRM. Report of the Commission on the
  6. Detsky A. Guidelines for economic analysis of        pricing of multiple-source drug products in Ontario.
pharmaceutical products: a draft document for             Kingston, Ontario: Mimeo; 1984.

                                                   Appendix

                      APPENDIX A. TABLE 1. 70/90 Regulations: Legislative Framework
Time                                                      Regulations

May 1993      75/90 program was imposed under the Prescription Drug Cost Regulation Act (PDCRA) and the
                  Ontario Drug Benefit Act (ODBA). According to the regulations, new first generic products
                  were not designated and listed unless they were priced at or lower 75% of the equivalent brand
                  name product. New second and subsequent generic products were not listed and designated
                  unless priced at or below 90% of the lowest priced listed comparable product.
Nov 1998      The new 70/90 Regulations were embraced under section 11 of Regulation 201/96 under the ODBA.
                  And under Subsection 7(2) of Regulation 935 under the Drug Interchangeability and
                  Dispensing Fee ACT (DIDFA) which, prior to May 27, 1996 was known as PDCRA. According
                  to the amended regulations, the drug benefit price of new first generic products must be equal
                  to or less than 70% of the price of the original products. Restrictions on the pricing of new
                  second and subsequent generic products were maintained.

                                                                                                           141
You can also read