Open Plurilateral Agreements, Global Spillovers and the Multilateral Trading System

Page created by Victoria Henry
 
CONTINUE READING
Open Plurilateral Agreements, Global Spillovers and the Multilateral Trading System
Working Paper

Open Plurilateral Agreements, Global
Spillovers and the Multilateral Trading
                System
Open Plurilateral Agreements, Global Spillovers and the Multilateral Trading System
Open Plurilateral Agreements, Global
      Spillovers and the Multilateral Trading
                     System
            Working Paper – This Version: 25/03/2020

                                                Authors:

                        Professor Bernard Hoekman, European University Institute

                                   Charles Sabel, Columbia Law School

Contact

Dr Christian Bluth
Project Manager
Global Economic Dynamics
Bertelsmann Stiftung
Telefon      +49 5241 81-81329
Mobil        +49 173 73 42 656
Fax          +49 5241 81-681329
christian.bluth@bertelsmann-stiftung.de
www.ged-project.de

Cover: nicknick_co – stock.adobe.com
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 3

Content
Bertelsmann Stiftung and WTO Reform ................................................................ 5

Executive Summary ................................................................................................ 6

Introduction ............................................................................................................ 10

1      Deadlock in the WTO as a driver of regionalism ........................................ 12

2      Why cooperate through trade agreements ................................................. 14

3      Open plurilateral agreements ....................................................................... 16

       3.1      Beyond reciprocity .....................................................................................................................16

       3.2      OPAs vs. PTAs ..........................................................................................................................18

       3.3      Current plurilateral deliberations in the WTO ............................................................................20

4      Preparing the ground for OPAs.................................................................... 21

       4.1      Informed plurilateral engagements and deliberation .................................................................21

       4.2      Governance of OPAs: Towards a Code of Conduct..................................................................23

5      Conclusion ..................................................................................................... 25

References ............................................................................................................. 26
Page 4 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    Abstract
    Problems involving regulatory design and cooperation to respond to climate change, the rise of the digital econ-
    omy and managing industrial policy conflicts call for cooperation to identify good practice and balancing the
    achievement of noneconomic objectives against competitive spillovers. Contrary to arguments that small group
    cooperation is second best in a world where consensus is not obtainable, open plurilateral agreements (OPAs)
    can be a first-best response to international collective action problems as it does not require all WTO members to
    participate or for the package deals that characterize trade negotiations. Sustaining an open, rules-based multilat-
    eral trading system calls for greater use of OPAs. The prospects for this would be enhanced if the trade policy
    community would build bridges to other organizations and epistemic communities and agree to a code of conduct
    for OPAs to ensure they support the open multilateral trade regime.

    Keywords: Open plurilateral agreements; WTO; trade agreements; WTO; cross-border spillovers

    Acknowledgements
    This paper is part of a research project on WTO reform supported by the Bertelsmann Stiftung. An earlier version
    was presented at the Pune International Centre/Ministry of External Affairs, Government of India conference on
    ‘Asia and the Emerging International Trading System’, Pune, February 28-March 1, 2020. We are grateful to
    Petros Mavroidis, Douglas Nelson and Robert Wolfe for helpful comments and discussions.
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 5

Bertelsmann Stiftung and WTO Reform
If international trade is not governed by rules, mere might dictates what is right. The World Trade Organization
(WTO) serves as a place where trade policy issues are addressed, disputes arbitrated, legal frameworks derived
and enforced. Through these functions, the WTO ensures that the rules of trade policy are inspired by fairness and
reciprocity rather than national interest. It is more important than ever to vitalise the global public good that it rep-
resents against various threats that have been undermining it.

The Global Economic Dynamics project of Bertelsmann Stiftung is a firm believer in rules-based international trade
and the WTO. In 2018, we published an extensive report with propositions on how to revitalise the WTO, based on
the deliberations of our High-Level Board of Experts on the Future of Global Trade Governance. In 2019 and 2020,
we follow up on this report with a series of policy contributions, providing fresh ideas and elaborating on concepts
already introduced in the report. These contributions cover the areas of the Appellate Body crisis, dealing with the
competitive distortions caused by industrial subsidies, enabling Open Plurilateral Agreements within the WTO while
providing reassurance to concerns of the membership at large with such forms of flexible cooperation and, finally,
improving working practices in WTO Committees.

We are grateful to Professors Bernard Hoekman and Charles Sabel for their expertise and advice which have been
a strong support for our WTO activities in general and for this paper specifically.

Andreas Esche                                      Christian Bluth
Director, Program Megatrends                       Project Manager, Global Economic Dynamics
Bertelsmann Stiftung                               Bertelsmann Stiftung
Page 6 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    Executive Summary
    National policies can give rise to negative cross-border spillovers. Addressing cross-border policy spillovers re-
    quires identifying those that are systemically significant and international cooperating to attenuate negative
    effects. Insofar as the policies impact on trade, in principle this is the task of the WTO, the international apex fo-
    rum for cooperation on trade policy and the negotiation and implementation of multilaterally agreed rules. The
    WTO has been unable to fulfill this role, reflecting differences in priorities across the membership, an erosion in
    trust, and deep-seated working practices that have impeded efforts to revise and update the rulebook. The result
    has been that since 1995 most new rulemaking has been through preferential trade agreements (PTAs), not the
    WTO.
    There is growing recognition that reforms are needed to improve the functioning of the WTO, including a willing-
    ness to pursue agreements pertaining to only a subset of WTO members but that are open to all WTO members
    and where benefits in principle extend to all countries on a nondiscriminatory basis. Open plurilateral agreements
    (OPAs) on specific policy areas or sectors of economic activity can complement discriminatory, closed PTAs, in
    the process supporting the multilateral trading system.
    Contrary to arguments that plurilateral initiatives are second best in a world where consensus is not obtainable,
    OPAs can be a first-best response. Cooperation aimed at identifying good regulatory practice and processes to
    determine whether different regulatory regimes are equivalent does not require all WTO members to participate.
    Nor does it call for the package deals that characterize trade negotiations.
    PTAs are inherently limited in their country coverage and are discriminatory by design – liberalization only applies
    among signatories. One consequence is that PTAs do relatively little to address global policy spillovers. Trade
    agreements are designed to address a specific problem: reducing the aggregate welfare cost associated with na-
    tional trade-restricting measures. If countries are large (enough) such policies impose negative externalities on
    trading partners. Often such policies are also costly to the countries imposing them. They will reduce aggregate
    real income if countries are small (cannot affect their terms of trade). Efforts by large(r) countries to shift the terms
    of trade in their favor may have the same result if other countries in turn impose barriers on imports.
    This terms-of-trade prisoner’s dilemma rationale for trade cooperation is complemented by a corollary role that
    trade agreements can play. The structure of trade policy in a nation is determined by political economy forces.
    Trade agreements permit governments to “mutually disarm” by changing the domestic political equilibrium that
    underpins the use of welfare-reducing restrictive trade policies. They do so by offering exporters better access to
    partner markets, creating incentives for exporters to provide domestic political support for liberalization. Moreover,
    because trade agreements are self-enforcing, they can help governments make credible commitments to sustain
    liberalization over time.
    These two conventional rationales for trade agreements ignore an increasingly important motivation for interna-
    tional cooperation. Changes in the structure and consequences of economic activity call for domestic regulatory
    measures to address associated market failures. Governments confront significant uncertainty how best to design
    such regulation to attain underlying objectives. Moreover, differences in regulatory regimes for a sector, product
    or activity give rise to transactions costs for firms operating internationally. Experience with WTO negotiations and
    the Paris Agreement make clear that common approaches reflected in binding multilateral agreements are un-
    likely to be feasible given the difficulty of attaining consensus. Instead, workable global solutions are more likely
    to emerge through encouragement of plurilateral initiatives (clubs) and efforts to ensure that over time these be-
    come the basis of a revamped rules-based multilateral trade regime.
    OPAs among groups of countries are more appropriate instruments to address international collective action
    problems and the trade costs of regulatory heterogeneity because the problems are more complex than the
    “terms-of-trade”-cum-commitment problems trade agreements are appropriate for. Problems involving regulatory
    design and cooperation to respond to climate change, the rise of the digital economy and managing high-tech
    industrial policy conflicts call for cooperation to identify good practice and balancing the achievement of noneco-
    nomic objectives against competitive spillovers.
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 7

OPAs can help parties understand and learn about the effectiveness of alternative policy options and their effects
on trade, and to identify approaches that are more effective as well as more efficient in terms of attenuating nega-
tive spillovers. International coordination and learning about good regulatory practice do not require a trade
agreement because the problem is not internalizing terms-of-trade spillovers or addressing commitment prob-
lems.
Of the so-called “joint statement initiatives” that are now being pursued in the WTO – spanning e-commerce, do-
mestic regulation of services, investment facilitation, and measures to enhance the ability of micro and small and
medium enterprises (MSMEs) to utilize the opportunities offered by the rules-based trading system – most ad-
dress coordination failures or entail joint efforts to identify good regulatory practices. The subjects of discussion
are all areas where there are potential gains from cooperation. However, apart from the e-commerce talks, they
do not address fundamental sources of recent trade tensions and conflicts. Nor do they deal with matters that will
become increasingly prominent soon, such as the use of trade policies to combat climate change.
For the credibility of the WTO it is critical that at least some of the ongoing plurilateral discussions result in agree-
ments. But what matters more for sustaining an open, rules-based multilateral trading system is to use OPAs to
manage industrial policy spillovers, regulate the digital economy and govern climate change-motivated trade poli-
cies.
The prospects for successfully using OPAs to do so would be enhanced if engagement extends beyond the trade
community and efforts are made to agree to a code of conduct for OPAs to address potential concerns of non-
participating countries.

Supporting plurilateral engagement

Successful international agreements addressing regulatory policies such as the WTO agreements on sanitary
and phytosanitary measures, technical barriers to trade and trade facilitation are all associated with a body of
agreed technical knowledge and accumulated good will among the relevant national regulatory agencies. The
same is true for all successful examples of international regulatory cooperation.
A necessary condition for successful OPAs is to create mechanisms that support informed deliberation in a given
policy area and fosters substantive, evidence and analysis-based discussion. Without robust information on ap-
plied policies across countries and experience in implementing them it is not possible to identify either good
practices, what policies create large spillovers that are systemically important, or efficient approaches to attenu-
ate such spillovers in ways that reflect and respond to local capabilities and priorities. Integrating the relevant
stakeholders, regulators, and sources of expertise (e.g., international organizations) in efforts to address such
questions is necessary.
Different models can be envisaged to prepare the ground for new OPAs. One is to work through the G20 Trade
and Investment Working Group, which spans G20 governments and the major international agencies. Another
approach is to create a sector-specific platform serviced by one specialized agency, as was done by the G20
through the 2016 Global Forum on Steel Excess Capacity (GFSEC), which was tasked with producing reliable
statistics on steel production capacity and identifying policies that affect steel production. Yet another option is to
bring together a group of independent policy research institutes and provide them with a mandate and the re-
sources to collect and analyze information to support engagement by countries to cooperate on a critical mass
basis.
In practice effective OPAs are likely to be policy and/or sector-specific, bringing together the WTO (trade commu-
nity) with other organizations that have a mandate in an area of overlapping interest. On climate change, for
example, the Paris Agreement and the WTO provide a basis for the formation of linked OPAs to support domain-
specific decarbonization regimes. The Paris Agreement authorizes countries to set national decarbonization tar-
gets and to form sector-specific ‘climate clubs’ for joint pursuit of national targets outside Paris and to count
progress achieved there towards their voluntary goals. An implication of the voluntary nature of national commit-
ments under Paris is that any penalty defaults defined by climate clubs involving trade restrictions fall outside the
Paris Agreement. Although countries can invoke the general exceptions provision of the WTO to justify the use of
Page 8 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    trade measures as part of decarbonization initiatives, an OPA can make explicit how trade sanctions will be ap-
    plied among members of the OPA to attain decarbonization targets they have agreed.
    Reconciling sectoral differences in domestic regulatory requirements pertaining to decarbonization of economic
    activity is just one, albeit very important example where OPAs can reduce the costs of regulatory heterogeneity.
    The concept can be applied as well to other policy domains, with clubs of countries, without the consent of other
    WTO members, defining regulatory standards for themselves, but committing that cooperation be open to partici-
    pation by any WTO member. As a result, participation would be selective, with a WTO member deciding to join
    some OPAs but not others.

    A governance framework for OPAs in the WTO

    While not a panacea, OPAs are a good path forward for countries desiring to deepen cooperation in a given pol-
    icy area or sector of economic activity. Although OPAs cannot alter the rights and obligations of WTO members
    that do not sign them, they do raise potential concerns for nonmembers. Even if – as we assume will be the case
    – agreements are applied on a nondiscriminatory basis, countries that decide not to participate may have an in-
    terest in what is discussed and agreed to constitute good practice.
    Agreeing to a set of binding principles that OPA signatories commit to abide by can help recognize valid concerns
    of nonmembers that OPAs be fully consistent with multilateralism. Ensuring that agreements are truly open to any
    country wishing to join, are fully transparent, and include mechanisms to assist countries not able to participate
    because of weaknesses in institutional capabilities would do much to ensure OPAs support the goals of the multi-
    lateral trading system.
    More broadly, developing a framework of general rules for registering OPA commitments, monitoring and evaluat-
    ing results, establishing penalty defaults and establishment of financial facilities to support expanded participation
    over time can help facilitate coordination among governments, specialized international agencies and interna-
    tional business organizations.
    A governance framework for OPAs can build on WTO precedent in the area of telecom regulation and take the
    form of a binding Reference Paper that would be incorporated into each OPA.
    A Reference Paper on OPAs could include the following elements:

        1. A provision making explicit that membership of an OPA is voluntary and that WTO members that decide
           not to participate cannot be obliged to join at a later date;
        2. The OPA is open to subsequent membership by WTO Members that did not join when it was first agreed;
        3. A section laying out the requirements and procedures to be followed for accession by aspiring members;
        4. A commitment that accession to an OPA cannot be on terms that are more stringent than those that ap-
           plied to the incumbent parties, adjusted for any changes in substantive disciplines adopted by signatories
           over time;
        5. Where feasible and in instances where capacities must be built for a country to meet OPA requirements,
           consideration be given to establish a stepwise schedule of compliance;
        6. A binding and enforceable provision committing signatories to provide assistance to WTO members that
           are not in a position to satisfy the preconditions for membership in terms of applying the substantive pro-
           visions of the agreement but desire to do so;
        7. Inclusion of consultation and binding conflict resolution procedures that may be invoked by non-signato-
           ries of OPAs if they perceive that incumbents impose more stringent conditions to accede to an
           agreement than apply to extant parties to the OPA, or if parties to an OPA do not live up to the commit-
           ment to respond to requests to provide assistance to nonmembers;
        8. Provisions that ensure the OPA is open in the sense of including transparency mechanisms to ensure
           that nonparticipants have full information on the implementation and operation of the agreement. These
           should include:
                a. Compliance with WTO requirements pertaining to publication of information on measures cov-
                    ered by the OPA;
                b. Simple, robust notification requirements for OPA members;
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 9

            c. Regular engagement of stakeholders in an ongoing conversation about how the agreement is
               working and future needs;
            d. Annual reporting to the WTO General Council by the OPA on its activities.

These principles do not include a requirement to provide ‘special and differential treatment’ (SDT) of the type
currently embodied in the WTO which permits developing countries to offer ‘less than full reciprocity’. Instead, the
focus is to assist countries to achieve the common regulatory objectives of OPA members. Including mechanisms
to assist countries improve their regulatoty regimes to be able to benefit from OPA is important for inclusiveness
and enhancing their relevance to low-income countries.
Page 10 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    Introduction
    Since the early 1990s, sustained economic growth in many parts of the world has led to a great increase in the
    global trade share of developing countries, driven by a rapid expansion in global value chains (GVCs), in turn re-
    flecting adoption of outward-oriented trade policies. The associated rebalancing of global output and income
    shares has helped lead to a “backlash against globalization” in many high-income countries, driven by the adjust-
    ment pressures and perceptions that the success of emerging economies is based in part on policies that unfairly
    advantage their firms. Further complicating matters, ongoing technological change and innovation is changing the
    composition of global trade flows towards services, e-commerce and cross-border digital transactions, generating
    new sources of economic adjustment pressures as well as opportunities.

    These developments call for revisiting and updating international trade cooperation. In principle this is the task of
    the World Trade Organization (WTO), the international apex forum for negotiation and implementation of multilat-
    erally agreed trade rules. The WTO has been unable to fulfill this role, reflecting differences in priorities across
    the membership, an erosion in trust, and deep-seated working practices that have impeded efforts to agree on
    changes to the rulebook. Consequently, most new rulemaking has been occurring in preferential trade agree-
    ments (PTAs), not the WTO.

    Abstracting from regional integration arrangements that go far beyond reciprocal trade liberalization and reflect
    political goals to foster deep integration through creation of an economic union – such as the European Union –
    trade agreements and the negotiating processes used to conclude them are designed to address a specific prob-
    lem: reducing the aggregate welfare cost associated with nationally adopted trade-restricting policies. If countries
    are large (enough) such policies impose negative externalities on trading partners. Often such policies are also
    costly to the countries imposing them. They will reduce aggregate real income if countries are small (cannot affect
    their terms of trade). Efforts by large(r) countries to shift the terms of trade in their favor may have the same result
    if other countries in turn impose barriers to their exports.

    Addressing this terms-of-trade prisoner’s dilemma rationale for trade cooperation is complemented by a corollary
    potential role for trade agreements. The structure of trade policy in a nation is determined by political economy
    forces. Trade agreements permit governments to “mutually disarm” by changing the domestic political equilibrium
    that underpins the use of welfare-reducing restrictive trade policies. They do so by offering exporters better ac-
    cess to partner markets, creating incentives for exporters to provide political support for liberalization. Moreover,
    because trade agreements are self-enforcing, they help governments make credible commitments to sustain lib-
    eralization commitments over time because reversal of liberalization will be met by retaliation by trading partners,
    hurting export industries and firms.

    These two conventional rationales for trade agreements1 ignore another motivation for international cooperation:
    to reduce the transactions costs of international regulatory heterogeneity for a given sector or product, and to
    identify how best to regulate economic activities to attain common economic or noneconomic objectives. The
    trade costs of regulatory heterogeneity may be reduced through coordination and learning, leading to adoption of
    common norms and gradual adoption of what has been determined to constitute good regulatory practices. Such
    cooperation does not require a trade agreement because the problem is not internalizing terms-of-trade spillovers
    or addressing time inconsistency problems by creating a credible commitment mechanism. Instead, what we call
    open plurilateral agreements (OPAs) can be used to support mutually beneficial cooperation. Because regulatory
    heterogeneity is increasingly rising to the fore as a factor creating trade costs, reflecting the steady rise in eco-
    nomic interdependency, OPAs can complement trade agreements as devices to support and sustain international
    cooperation. Moreover, OPAs offer a tool for countries to cooperate in addressing international collective action
    problems and for countries learn about and adapt policies to address market failures more efficiently. Climate
    change-related policies are a particularly important example. Finally, OPAs may also be a means to address the

    1
        See, e.g., Maggi (2014) and Limão (2016).
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 11

international spillovers of policies that cannot be addressed through PTAs because of free rider concerns. Indus-
trial subsidies are an example: agreement of rules of the game in this area require all of the large trade powers to
participate.

Open plurilateral agreements (OPAs) offer both the prospect of reducing regulatory compliance costs for firms
operating internationally and acting as a platform for large players to cooperate in attenuating negative spillovers
from national policies. Contrary to arguments that plurilateral initiatives are second best in a world where consen-
sus is not obtainable, OPAs can be a first-best response. Cooperation aimed at identifying good regulatory
practice and processes to determine whether different regulatory regimes are equivalent does not require all
WTO members to participate. Nor does it call for the package deals that characterize trade negotiations. OPAs
can be sector-specific, bringing together the associated stakeholders and leverage the expertise and experience
that is salient to a given activity and the spillovers it generates. 2

The international rules of the game were last revised in the early 1990s. They have not kept up with a rapidly
changing world economy in which emerging economies account for a large share of global output and where
cross-border flows of data, digital products and technologies are expanding rapidly. Competition between govern-
ments to stimulate domestic economic activity through ‘make it here’ policies is growing, often reflecting an
implicit if not explicit questioning of the distribution of the gains from trade. The US has reverted to “aggressive
unilateralism” including negotiation of bilateral ‘voluntary’ export restraints and import expansion commitments –
i.e., managed trade of the type last seen in the 1980s (Bhagwati, 1987; Bhagwati and Patrick, 1991). Globally,
rising use of trade-distorting policies is occurring in conjunction with a rapid shift towards an ever more globally
interconnected digital economy. These developments call for multilateral cooperation to revisit the rules of the
game in a variety of policy areas, including industrial policies and the regulation of cross-border data flows and
digital products.

National policies can give rise to negative cross-border spillovers. Policies restricting trade and investment are
designed to do so, while policies of a fiscal nature (tax exemptions, subsidies and related industrial policies) or
measures to combat climate change may do so. Addressing cross-border policy spillovers requires cooperation to
identify those that are systemically significant and negotiating rules that attenuate negative side effects. Insofar as
the policies impact on trade, in principle this is the task of the WTO. The WTO is the apex international forum for
the negotiation and enforcement of trade policy disciplines and commitments. The WTO has been unable to fulfill
this role, reflecting differences in priorities across the membership, an erosion in trust, and deep-seated working
practices that have impeded efforts to address both old and new policy externalities.

Many countries have responded to recent US unilateralism by ramping up efforts to conclude trade agreements
with each other. In parallel, plurilateral cooperation outside the narrow area of trade policy is pursed by many
countries, ranging from health and safety standards to taxation and regulation of financial service providers
(Hoekman and Sabel, 2018).3 This illustrates that many countries continue to pursue international cooperation to
deepen economic integration. The multidimensional nature of the policies that influence investment and opera-
tional decisions of international firms suggests a multidimensional response is in order. Part of that response
should center on revisiting the design and content of trade and investment agreements. In the WTO setting there
is a growing recognition that reforms are needed to improve the functioning of the organization, including a will-
ingness to explore plurilateral forms of cooperation under the umbrella of the multilateral agreements. The
challenge – and opportunity – is to ensure that any agreements that emerge are open as opposed to the closed
nature of most PTAs, in the process supporting gradual multilateralization (Hoekman and Sabel, 2019).

Our premise is that many critical mass initiatives, where the benefits extend on a nondiscriminatory basis to all
countries, should be feasible if they involve the key players in the G20. In practice, specific initiatives need not

2
  For example, Hoekman and Inama (2018) propose an OPA on rules of origin.
3
   The term plurilateral is used to describe different types of arrangements in the literature. In this paper the term “discriminatory plurilateral
agreement” (DPA) is used for so-called Annex 4 WTO agreements that allow for discrimination against non-signatories. In contrast, the term
“open plurilateral agreement” (OPA) is used to describe cooperation where benefits are applied on a nondiscriminatory basis to non-signato-
ries.
Page 12 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    necessarily include all G20 member countries. Indeed, imposing that constraint would greatly limit the scope for
    action given the wide divergences within the G20 as regards desirable trade policies. The critical mass needed to
    internalize a large share of the total benefits associated with rules for policies such as industrial subsidies is very
    small, essentially encompassing China, the EU (and UK), Japan and the US.

    The situation confronting the trading system today has parallels with the 1980s, which saw extensive recourse to
    trade-distorting measures in response to a rapid rise in exports from East Asian economies. This motivated the
    launch of a preparatory process by countries that informed the design of the Uruguay Round negotiation agenda.
    A similar effort is needed today, aimed at resolving the trade conflicts that are of greatest relevance from a sys-
    temic perspective. Two areas are particularly important: (i) rulemaking to address major international spillovers
    from national industrial policies; and (ii) improving the functioning of the WTO, including more effective ap-
    proaches to address disparities in capacity and economic development. Open plurilateral agreements (OPAs) can
    help on both fronts.

    The plan of this paper is as follows. Section 1 describes briefly some of the drivers of the turn to plurilateral coop-
    eration and away from fully multilateral initiatives spanning all 164 WTO members. Section 2 discusses rationales
    for – and tradeoffs associated with – embedding cooperation in discriminatory, closed, trade agreements (PTAs).
    Section 3 makes a case for open plurilateral agreements (OPAs) as a complementary, desirable, instrument to
    further deepen cooperation on a nondiscriminatory basis and briefly discusses ongoing plurilateral talks in the
    WTO. Section 4 presents some suggestions for governance principles that could be applied by participating WTO
    members to ensure that OPAs support the multilateral trading system. Section 5 concludes.

    1 Deadlock in the WTO as a driver of regionalism
    Many policy areas can generate spillovers for other countries, both negative and positive. Examples are export
    restrictions, which are detrimental to net importing countries but may benefit competing exporters and “green”
    subsidies (ranging from minimum feed-in prices for electricity generated from renewable resources to subsidies
    for the development or use of specific technologies) that help to address global climate change even though they
    may have adverse consequences for competing firms from other countries. Similarly, policies constraining digital
    trade, e-commerce and data flows may not have the goal of restricting trade but do so as a side-effect of the pur-
    suit of specific domestic regulatory objectives such as consumer protection and privacy.
    Support for trade is strong in most countries. Indeed, post-Trump support has been increasing in countries where
    surveys suggested a trend towards increasing critical views of globalization. In the EU, for example, Eurobarome-
    ter data indicate that 60% of Europeans consider free trade as positive. 4 This provides political support for one
    response of governments to the Trump administration’s unilateral decision to adopt an explicitly mercantilist trade
    policy: negotiation of trade agreements. The decision by the TPP-11 countries to move forward with the CPTPP,
    without the US, exemplifies that these nations continue to believe that opening markets and cooperating on trade
    policies is in their interest. The CPTPP includes provisions on policies that give rise to negative spillovers and that
    go beyond what is embodied in the WTO, including on digital trade and data flows. Similarly, post-2016 the EU
    has been active in pursuit of new PTAs that include provisions dealing with domestic regulatory policies, and
    many countries in Asia and Africa ramped up longer-standing efforts to negotiate PTAs, notably, the African Con-
    tinental Free Trade Area (AfCFTA) and the Regional Comprehensive Economic Partnership (RCEP).
    Such a dynamic is not observed in the WTO. Reasons for this include shifts in the power balance among its
    members, the legacy of the failed Doha Development Agenda (DDA) and the organization’s working practices.
    The core negotiation, transparency, and conflict resolution functions of the organization are not functioning effec-
    tively, undermining the WTO’s ability to fulfill its mandate. The failure of the Doha round in turn has precluded
    discussion of a new work program that includes the regulatory subjects that increasingly are of central concern to
    polities and international businesses.

    4
      Between 2010 and 2019, there was a 16-percentage point increase in positive responses to the question whether respondents benefited
    from international trade. At: https://ec.europa.eu/commfrontoffice/publicopinion/index.cfm/survey/getsurveydetail/instruments/special/sur-
    veyky/2246
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 13

Deadlock in the WTO has prevailed in part because of consensus-based decision-making. This permitted WTO
members to veto initiatives and block efforts to go beyond the issues on the DDA. A complementary factor in this
regard is that the WTO embodies special and differential treatment (SDT) provisions for developing countries
which entail a right to offer less than full reciprocity in trade negotiations and to delay or be exempted from the
application of certain WTO rules. The invocation of SDT by large and/or more advanced emerging economies is
increasingly opposed by many higher-income countries, first and foremost the US. Conversely, many developing
countries take the position that SDT is a core feature of the balance of rights and obligations associated with
WTO membership.
While consensus is primarily a practice and not a formal rule – voting is possible in principle – voting does not
occur, reflecting a widely held view this would undermine the legitimacy of WTO decisions. 5 Countries large and
small rely on the consensus practice as a guarantee that the results of negotiations are acceptable to them, en-
suring political ‘ownership’ of the WTO by members and their polities. This positive aspect of consensus decision-
making is offset by the possibility of blocking activities that may have nothing to do with rule-making negotiations,
such as setting the agenda of committee meetings or proposals to discuss trade policy-related matters that are
not covered by a WTO agreement or the DDA. The result has been that since the WTO was created in 1995 most
new rulemaking has been occurring in PTAs, not the WTO (Dür, Baccini and Elsig, 2014; Hofman et al. 2018).
In January 2020 there were 303 PTAs in force according to the WTO.6 They often have a regional focus: the EU
and its PTAs with neighboring countries; the AfCFTA in Africa; ASEAN and the Comprehensive and Progressive
Agreement for Transpacific Partnership (CPTPP) in Asia; and a variety of shallower agreements around the
world. Many countries have concluded multiple PTAs both with regional partners and across regions. While PTAs
can help reduce trade costs they are inherently limited in the coverage of the countries involved and are by de-
sign discriminatory – market access liberalization is on a preferential basis. Most do not have an accession
provision – one reason why there is such a plethora of PTAs. The CPTPP is an outlier in having a provision that
permits other countries to join. The CPTPP includes provisions on e-commerce, regulatory matters, investment,
and competition policy (including state-owned enterprises). If China and the EU were to join or link to the CPTPP,
this would reduce the fragmentation associated with bilateral PTAs and further expand trade cooperation to areas
not or partially covered by the WTO. In such a scenario, it is likely that the US would have incentives to consider
joining such a greatly expanded CPTPP to avoid associated trade and investment diversion costs.
The prospects for this appear rather dim. Major emerging economies such as China and India have not signed
deep PTAs. One consequence is that to date PTAs have done relatively little to address major sources of policy
spillovers – such as the use of subsidies – because of collective action (free riding) problems. China, the EU,
Japan and the US all engage in bilateral discussions with each other on trade-related matters. In addition, the EU,
Japan and the US have launched in a trilateral process to identify ways to strengthen disciplines on subsidies,
state-owned enterprises, and industrial development policies more broadly. A necessary condition for meaningful
outcomes is that all the major trading powers are involved in the associated deliberations-cum-negotiations.
There is no magic bullet: progress on rulemaking to resolve sources of policy conflicts and systemic spillovers
requires agreement between the large players.
A key question – both practical and analytical – is how to design trade agreements to incentivize engagement by
a sufficiently large number of significant countries. A corollary question is whether cooperation on policies such a
subsidies or digital economy regulation requires embedding in agreements that encompass market access liber-
alization commitments or can be pursued on a policy-specific basis. The latter is currently being pursued in the
WTO through plurilateral discussions on e-commerce and domestic regulation of services.

5
  Art. IX WTO specifies that if voting occurs, unanimity is required for amendments relating to general principles such as non-discrimination; a
three-quarters majority for Interpretations of provisions of the WTO agreements and decisions on waivers; and a two-thirds majority for
amendments relating to issues other than general principles. Where not otherwise specified and consensus cannot be reached a simple ma-
jority vote is sufficient. Art. X provides that a member cannot be bound by a vote on an amendment that alters its rights or obligations and that
it opposes. In such instances, the Ministerial Conference may decide to request that the member concerned withdraw from the WTO or to
grant it a waiver.
6
  https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/region_e/region_e.htm.
Page 14 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    2 Why cooperate through trade agreements
    Conceptually, trade agreements deal with two specific problems: reducing the negative spillovers generated by
    foreign trade policies – a ‘terms of trade’ externality; and/or an inability of a government to make a credible com-
    mitment to sustain a desired more liberal trade policy (Maggi, 2014). Both dimensions are potentially relevant as
    a motivation for including provisions on domestic regulation in a trade agreement as well as a focus on liberaliza-
    tion of discriminatory market access barriers. Regulation can affect the terms of trade by raising costs for foreign
    firms – even if regulations apply on a nondiscriminatory basis to foreign and home firms (Kox and Lejour, 2005).
    Moreover, desirable types of regulation may confront implementation difficulties because of political economy
    forces that a government might be able to overcome through binding treaty commitments. Even if commitment is
    the aim, improving market access remains the primary focus of trade agreements, as this is the mechanism
    through which credibility is obtained: it is market access that incentivizes the trading partner to enforce the com-
    mitment.
    Trade agreements have four salient characteristics that are relevant from the perspective of considering how they
    may support – or impede – deeper forms of market integration. First, they liberalize access to markets through a
    process of reciprocal exchange of trade policy concessions. The need for reciprocity on market access liberaliza-
    tion is well understood and reflects a mix of terms of trade considerations (for large enough countries) and
    political economy forces. Internalizing the benefits of liberalization can be achieved if the liberalization is recipro-
    cal. Second, they rely on the national treatment principle to prevent ‘concession erosion’ using domestic policies
    that may be designed to substitute for trade policies, while leaving parties free to define their domestic regulations
    as they wish. What matters here is that such regulation is applied equally to domestic and foreign agents. Third,
    and related to the previous characteristic, provisions on nontariff measures reflect a desire to facilitate trade (re-
    duce trade costs), not change or improve national regulation. Fourth, they are self-enforcing: the threat of
    withdrawal of market access commitments is the mechanism to sustain cooperation.
    Most PTAs are shallow integration instruments in the sense that signatories retain national regulatory sover-
    eignty: they are free to regulate as they wish as long as measures apply on a nondiscriminatory basis to domestic
    and foreign products (firms) – i.e., satisfy the national treatment and most-favored-nation (MFN) principles.7 Na-
    tional treatment is effective in preventing the use of domestic regulation to undercut negotiated trade liberalization
    commitments, but it does nothing to help move countries to improve regulatory outcomes over time. “Deeper”
    PTAs go beyond the four basic characteristics by including provisions on the substance of domestic regulation.
    Differences in regulation across jurisdictions for tangible and intangible products may impede trade by generating
    redundant transactions costs or segmenting markets. Governments have responded to demands from busi-
    nesses and citizens to bolster the governance of cross-border exchanges by (re-)designing trade agreements to
    go beyond traditional liberalization of trade in goods to encompass disciplines on policies affecting trade in ser-
    vices, protection of intellectual property rights, dimensions of foreign investment and regulation of product and
    factor markets more broadly. This may reflect concerns that trading partners adopt certain health, safety, labor or
    environmental regulations, often centered around alignment with international norms.
    There may also be efficiency rationales for pursuing cooperation on regulatory policies on a small group basis.
    One reason is that a uniform rule for a given policy may be inefficient; another is that even if there is agreement
    that a given regulatory rule is desirable, not all countries will satisfy the preconditions for implementing it.
    The great diversity in circumstances and priorities across the WTO membership implies “variable geometry” is
    and will be an inherent feature of regulatory cooperation. The challenge for the multilateral trading system is to do
    so in a way that supports rather than undercuts the WTO and recognizes that an exclusive focus on mini-lateral
    outcomes is suboptimal systemically as well as in terms of aggregate welfare gains. Large players such as the
    EU or the US may seek to “export” their preferred regulatory norms to trading partners (Lavenex, 2014) and do so
    in part by linking preferential access to markets to commitments by partner countries to change domestic regula-
    tory policies. Linkage to market access may be soft in the sense of not being enforceable, but what matters is that

    7
      The WTO encourages members to adopt international product standards if these exist, but national requirements that differ from interna-
    tional norms – if these exist – are permitted if they are not more trade restrictive than necessary to attain the underlying policy objective. See
    Mavroidis (2016) for an in-depth treatment of the genesis and substance of WTO rules.
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 15

this is a core feature of trade agreements. Market access is the carrot to induce a country to change its domestic
regulation or to do more to enforce specific regulations. An example is conditioning preferential access to the
market on reform and enforcement of labor standards, environmental policies or protection of human rights. 8
Both PTAs and multilateral WTO negotiating rounds involve bundling multiple issues into packages and embody
a complex mix of within- and cross-issue linkages. Cross-issue linkages are needed when policies are not sepa-
rable, i.e., policies either can substitute for each other or they are complements so that addressing one area
enhances the payoffs of cooperation in another. Issue linkage in international agreements involves the parties
connecting two or more policy areas in some way. If there are structural interactions between issue areas, linkage
may be both needed and beneficial (Spagnolo, 2001; Conconi and Perroni, 2002; Limão, 2005). If there are not,
issue linkage is not needed and may undermine cooperation. 9
Maggi (2016) identifies three types of issue linkage in international agreements: negotiation linkage; enforcement
linkage and participation linkage. The first of these involves negotiating two or more issues in one agreement,
with the possibility of trade-offs across issues, the goal being to conclude one agreement – a package deal.
Given agreement, enforcement linkage involves action in one issue area to enforce compliance with commit-
ments in another (cross-retaliation). Participation linkage comprise situations where the threat of sanctions in one
area induces participation in an agreement addressing another policy area. All three types of linkage fall under
the broader concept of conditionality – making cooperation in one area a condition for cooperation in another.
Conconi and Perroni (2005) contrast this notion of conditionality with a separation rule, in which there are explicit
prohibitions on using sanctions in one area to induce (enforce) cooperation in another.
In principle, issue linkage increases potential overall gains, but as demonstrated by the Doha round, crafting a
negotiating agenda that delivers large enough net gains to all parties is difficult. If policies are separable, cross-
issue linkage is not needed – the payoffs of cooperation are independent of what governments may or may not
do in other policy areas. There is no rationale for considering cross-issue linkage. There may also be no need to
tie cooperation to market access – i.e., to engage in what Maggi (2016) calls enforcement linkage. The potential
value of enforceability depends on the type of commitment that is undertaken. Binding dispute settlement en-
forced by the (threat of) withdrawal of market access is unlikely to be useful for encouraging cooperation on
regulatory matters. It is more likely to have a chilling effect on the willingness to consider cooperation – due to
fear of uncertain contingent liability or views by regulators that market access considerations will have adverse
effects on the realization of regulatory goals. 10 Different systems are needed, based on transparency mecha-
nisms (information collection, incident reporting, sharing of data, dialogue) and, as Hoekman and Sabel (2019)
argue, severability. The latter is a feature of the CPTPP chapter on regulatory coherence which is not subject to
binding dispute resolution. This was also taken off the table by the EU in the aborted TTIP talks.
‘Enforcement linkage’ may be a motivation to include regulatory provisions in trade agreements, but the desirabil-
ity of such mechanisms needs careful analysis. A PTA-centered approach may make it more difficult to sustain
regulatory cooperation. PTAs are conditional on acceptance of engaging in preferential liberalization of market
access. This is a requirement of WTO rules: ‘substantially all trade’ must be covered by a trade agreement for it
to be WTO-consistent. Thus, countries that are interested in deepening cooperation on domestic regulation and
non-trade areas of economic policy will need to be willing to engage on market access. In turn, existing PTA
members must accept extending access to their markets to new countries insofar as their PTAs have provisions
permitting accession. Incumbents may not be willing to do so for many reasons. Thus, the PTA route is an inflexi-
ble one, even for PTAs that have an accession provision – such as the CPTPP – given the need for far-reaching

8
  A feature of so-called nonreciprocal trade preference programs in which richer countries grant poorer countries better access to their mar-
kets without requiring the latter to offer reciprocity in terms of market opening is that conditionality may be imposed in other policy areas – i.e.,
there is cross-issue linkage.
9
  India’s failed attempt to link final adoption of the WTO Trade Facilitation Agreement (TFA) to concessions on agricultural support is an exam-
ple. See Hoekman (2016).
10
    Such concerns were an important factor in the demise of talks in the WTO on competition policy in the late 1990s and early 2000s. Compe-
tition authorities held the view that their mandate was to safeguard consumer interests, the contestability of markets and national welfare. In
doing so, they do not distinguish between the behavior of domestic and foreign firms on the market, as opposed to the focus of trade negotia-
tors on improving conditions of competition for national firms.
Page 16 | Open Plurilateral Agreements

    market access commitments that have nothing to do with regulatory cooperation. This applies to multilateral trade
    agreements as well.
    PTAs are also not a panacea as instruments to address concerns of citizens regarding non-trade policy dimen-
    sions. Many citizens of high-income countries consider globalization a threat to employment and a source of
    rising inequalities. These include the implications of trade agreements for regulatory powers and the desire that
    trade be conditioned on protecting the environment and social standards. As noted, such policy areas are in-
    creasingly addressed explicitly in trade agreements, e.g., through the inclusion of provisions that require action by
    signatory governments on social and environmental policies. PTAs permit market access to be used as a carrot
    (and a stick) to encourage adoption of commitments pertaining to these areas. Such linkage strategies can work
    when trade relations are asymmetric but are less feasible to implement when it comes to large countries such as
    China or India.
    Some foreign trade practices generating negative spillover effects cannot be addressed effectively through re-
    gional agreements that only include a subset of the major countries. PTAs offer only partial solutions to
    companies seeking a reduction in trade uncertainty and a level playing field. The same is true for citizens con-
    cerned with ensuring that trade supports societal goals and sustainable development. What is needed is to
    complement PTAs with forms of cooperation that are more open and inclusive. In some areas deeper cooperation
    on contested policies require all of the major traders to agree. In others cooperation may be feasible among sub-
    sets of countries without necessarily encompassing all major players.

    3 Open plurilateral agreements
    At the December 2017 Ministerial Conference, WTO members abandoned the long-standing view that the WTO
    should pursue agreements spanning all 164 members. This development offers a path for international coopera-
    tion that does not require all WTO members participate, and thus a potential alternative to what has been the
    primary alternative for countries seeking to deepen trade governance: discriminatory PTAs. Open plurilateral
    agreements (OPAs) involving groups of WTO members offer both the prospect of reducing regulatory compliance
    costs for firms operating internationally while enhancing the ability of regulatory agencies to attain societal objec-
    tives more efficiently.11
    Contrary to arguments that plurilateral initiatives are second best in a world where consensus is not obtainable,
    OPAs can be a first-best response to resolving problems associated with regulatory heterogeneity. Cooperation
    on regulatory matters does not require large-N participation or cross-issue linkage or the type of first difference
    reciprocity (Bhagwati, 1988) that is a basic feature of trade negotiations. Attempting to integrate regulatory coop-
    eration into the framework of ‘single undertaking’ type package deals that characterize trade negotiations is
    neither necessary nor desirable. Nor is the secrecy that is part of the trade negotiations process. Indeed, when
    pursuing regulatory cooperation secrecy is counterproductive. This is not to deny the close link that may exist be-
    tween market access and regulation, or that in some instances this link must be explicit in international
    cooperation between countries. What is feasible will depend of the type of issues involved.

    3.1 Beyond reciprocity

    In addition to formation of discriminatory PTAs that remove barriers of substantially all trade between signatories,
    the WTO offers two alternative mechanisms for Members to make trade policy commitments on a small group
    basis. One is to conclude a discriminatory plurilateral agreement (DPA) under Art. II.3 WTO; the other is a so-

    11
       Hoekman and Sabel (2019). Open plurilateralism as an organizing concept is an element of the Government of New Zealand’s trade policy
    strategy. See Vitalis (2018). New Zealand launched an initiative with Costa Rica, Fiji, Iceland, Norway and Switzerland on an open plurilateral
    Agreement on Climate Change, Trade and Sustainability, with a view to demonstrating how trade policy and trade rules can play a critical role
    in helping to drive the transformation of the economy to become more sustainable and inclusive. See https://www.mfat.govt.nz/en/media-and-
    resources/ministry-statements-and-speeches/trade-ministers-express-support-for-the-agreement-on-climate-change-trade-and-sustainability-
    at-the-world-economic-forum-davos-2020/.
Open Plurilateral Agreements | Page 17

called critical mass agreement (CMA). Both involve negotiated disciplines that apply only to signatories. They dif-
fer in that the benefits of a CMA apply on a nondiscriminatory basis to all countries, including non-participating
nations, whereas in a DPA they do not. Examples of CMAs include the Information Technology Agreement (ITA)
and agreements on basic telecommunications and financial services (Hoekman and Mavroidis, 2015b). The main
example of a DPA is the WTO Agreement on Government Procurement (GPA). In considering different types of
trade cooperation, countries must determine the need for cross-issue linkages, whether free-riding constraints
apply and, if so, what constitutes a critical mass of participation that internalizes enough of the benefits within the
participating group of countries.
Table 1 characterizes different types of trade agreements—multilateral package deals, PTAs, CMAs and DPAs.
All involve policy commitments and international cooperation among signatories. They differ in design and imple-
mentation. Types of cooperation included in the top part of Table 1 address policies that by design impede market
access. Multilateral package deals and CMAs that reduce market access barriers are only feasible if most of the
associated benefits is internalized by participants. Free riding concerns will otherwise preclude agreement. This is
a problem for trade liberalization because the WTO requires border trade policies to be applied on a most-fa-
vored-basis to all WTO members. This constraint can easily bind, as shown by negotiations on an Environmental
Goods Agreement (EGA) to reduce tariffs on products salient for reducing carbon emissions, which have not
been concluded because of free-riding concerns. Similar concerns arose in the now aborted negotiations on a
Trade in Services Agreement (TiSA). The ITA demonstrates that CMAs can be negotiated, but also that a neces-
sary condition is that a large enough set of countries participate.
The bottom part of Table 1 presents alternative types of cooperation where the primary focus is not on removing
market access barriers but on agreement to cooperate on domestic regulation. Such agreements can take the
form of harmonization (e.g., a commitment to develop and adopt common standards), implementing agreed good
regulatory practices, and mutual recognition of equivalence of standards or regulatory regimes. Agreement on
regulatory standards and regimes may be associated with improving access to markets insofar as regulatory
standards must be satisfied as a condition for supplying a product. What and how much can be done will depend
on whether free riding is a constraint. This will be a factor for narrow market access liberalization negotiations but
may be much less pertinent for regulatory cooperation given that countries can decide not to extend cooperate if
local circumstances or social preferences differ too much, and exclude countries that do not satisfy the negotiated
preconditions for cooperation to occur.
The benefits of cooperation may apply unconditionally to all countries on a nondiscriminatory basis or on a condi-
tional basis. Examples of the former include the WTO TFA which defines a set of good regulatory practices to
facilitate trade that all WTO members have agreed to implement, with countries determining for themselves the
timeline for implementation and having the ability to request technical assistance if needed. Other examples are
collaborative efforts in fora such as the OECD and APEC to define good regulatory practices and agreement by
countries to adopt these. They also include international collaboration to develop product and process standards
in inter-governmental bodies such as the ISO. Cooperation involving identification and agreement on good regu-
latory practices can be applied on an MFN basis as it is insensitive to free riding considerations: the policies are
in the self-interest of countries independent of whether other countries do so.

In practice, regulatory cooperation may need to be conditional on joint action by the parties. Such conditionality
will vary in intensity, ranging from low forms such as mutual recognition agreements that require satisfying mini-
mum standards, to very high (e.g., regulatory equivalence regimes). Countries that do not have adequate
regulatory institutions will not be able to benefit from mutual recognition, let alone equivalence arrangements. Co-
operation in such cases may require a focus on complementary measures such as development aid and related
measures to bolster regulatory capacity. Inclusion of technical or financial assistance was an important element of
the 2013 Trade Facilitation Agreement (Hoekman, 2016).
One type of OPA that falls into the category of a conditional agreement in the bottom right party of Table 1 is what
Mattoo (2018) calls destination-specific exporter regulatory commitments where a regulator (government) accepts
to look after the interests of consumers in countries to which firms under its jurisdiction export. Foreign consumer
interests would be defined by the regulatory objectives that have been established by the importing country, with
the exporting country regulator/government committing to attain these goals without necessarily adopting an iden-
tical regulatory regime. This is a form of regulatory cooperation that is more closely linked to market access
You can also read