Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu

Page created by Johnnie Goodman
 
CONTINUE READING
Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu
Water: Commodity
 or Commons?

Suzi Kerr, Motu
(with Andrew Coleman and Josh Pemberton)
Network Waitangi Otautahi, Feb 3013
Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu
Both – in balance?

1.   Economics and valuing water

2.   Institutions: community management (local
     commons) and regulation

3.   Institutions: markets
Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu
Economics and valuing water

•   What are economists doing when they value the
    environment?
•   Which assumptions do they make that thinkers in
    other disciplines might challenge?
•   How might “value” be conceived of by non-
    economists?
Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu
Why is economics used to value the
          environment?
•   Evaluating options: cost-benefit analysis
    •   An objective way to make decisions?
Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu
What do economists mean by
                 “value”?
•   Value in exchange
    •   As compared to value in use: Smith (1776)

    •   Diamonds vs. water paradox

•   Value as a subjective statement of individual
    preferences: Hicks (1939), Debreu (1959)
    •   As compared to something external such as labour: Ricardo
        (1821), Marx (1867)
Water: Commodity or Commons? - Suzi Kerr, Motu
How does economics value
      environmental goods?
               Total economic value

   Use value          Option Value     Non-use value

Market   Non-market              Existence    Bequest
How does economics value
            environmental goods?
•   Revealed preference techniques
•   Stated preference techniques

•   Aggregating values
•   Value as a statement of preference relative to other
    goods
Issues with preference aggregation
•   How do we make interpersonal comparisons
    (Harsanyi, 1955)
     •   In politics
     •   When we value the environment
          • Scenario 1: (0.10 x $90) + (0.01 x $10) = $9.10
          • Scenario 2: (0.10 x $10) + (0.01 x $90) = $1.90
Issues with preference aggregation
•    How do we make interpersonal comparisons
     (Harsanyi, 1955)
     •   Comparisons between societies
          • Richland: 0.1 x $200 = $20

          • Poorville: 0.1 x $20 = $2

          • Basel Convention

• Future generations (Fitoussi et al, 2009)
     • ‘Endogeneity’ – their constraints and preferences depend on
       our decisions now
How else might “value” and “the
      environment” be understood?
•   Intrinsic value: (Næss 1988)
•   Environment not an asset: spiritual view (Roberts,
    1995)
•   Preferences might not reflect moral concerns as to
    “right” and “wrong” (Flynn, 2000) or Kantian duties
    (Kant, 1785)
•   Law: value in process, not just outcome (Dicey, 1885)
    (Bingham, 2010)
•   Incommensurability (Raz, 1998)
What can economics contribute?
•   Role of concepts such as scarcity and opportunity cost
•   Thinking of value in terms of preferences, and weighting
    these to sum across individuals are normative choices.
•   Is use of economics inherently in conflict with spiritual
    and moral incommensurable values?
    •   Preferences can reflect needs of future generations
        (etc), moral concerns, but do not necessarily do so.
    •   Intrinsic value is, by definition, incapable of being
        reflected in preferences.
The value of water?

value

                  Value of extra water

   Incommensurable value?
                                         Water in streams
                                         Personal water use
What does this mean for decision
               making?
•   The cost-benefit framework for valuing the
    environment is premised on challengeable
    assumptions.
•   Communication across disciplines will be enhanced if
    we are aware of these assumptions, and of the
    strengths of the economic approach.
•   How and why we value water should affect how we
    govern and manage it
Institutions: community management
   (local commons) and regulation
 In 1990, two landmark economics books were
    published:

 Douglass C. North Institutions, Institutional Change, and
   Economic Performance.

 Elinor Ostrom Governing the Commons: The evolution of
    institutions for collective action
Both were based on historical analysis of the way groups
    of people/societies/ countries developed
    institutions - rules - to organise the way they
    conduct themselves.

North emphasised that societies have
   1. formal rules
   2. informal rules
   3. enforcement mechanisms
Ostrom investigated the way that groups / societies
 sometimes develop institutions to solve “common
 pool resource” allocation problems:
1. fishing
2. “commons” grazing
3. water abstraction and use
4. forest use
5. pollution
6. irrigation
7. climate change
Resource
catchment
             Regulation
                                     Voluntary instruments

                  Regulation
                          Price based
                          instrumentsments
Technology                                            Education
                                                      Information
Common Pool Resources

These are natural or human-created resources where
   1. one person's use reduces other peoples’ use, either now
      or in the future
   2. It is difficult or costly to exclude other people from using
      the resource.

Common Pool Resources have traditionally been
   considered subject to the “tragedy of the
   commons”
A game theory representation of the tragedy of the
commons

Player 2          Extract            Extract
Player 1          cooperatively      exploitatively

Extract                (10,10)
cooperatively

Extract                                     (5,5)
exploitatively
A game theory representation of the tragedy of the
commons

Player 2          Extract            Extract
Player 1          cooperatively      exploitatively

Extract                (10,10)              (4,14)
cooperatively

Extract                 (14,4)              (5,5)
exploitatively
The efficient solution is to cooperate

But each player has an incentive to cheat no
  matter what the other player does

The “Nash equilibrium” is that both extract
  exploitatively, leading to suboptimal results for
  everyone.
Common Pool Resources

According to the tragedy of the commons, CPRs are
   subject to inefficient undersupply or overuse.

   1. They are undersupplied if those who provide them cannot
      stop others from using them
   2. They are overused if a user extracts more than they
      otherwise because of concern others will use the resource
      if they don’t.
Common Pool Resources
Traditionally, it has been argued that to solve the
   tragedy of the commons:
  1. The resource can be regulated by a government
  2. The resource can be privatised so the costs and benefits of
     using the resource are internalised.
Government regulation: cheaters are punished

Player 2         Extract            Extract
Player 1         cooperatively      exploitatively

Extract                                        (4,14)
                       (10,10)
cooperatively                              (4,0)
Extract                  (14,4)
                                           (5,5)
exploitatively          (0,4)
Common Pool Resources
Ostrom argued that neither methods were always successful

(1) It is expensive for a government to monitor whether people
    are cooperating or cheating.
(2) A government may not always catch cheats, or may punish
    falsely people who are cooperating
(3) A government may not impose the correct fines
(4) A government may not know the appropriate carrying
    capacity
(5) It may not be easy or desirable to create clear property rights
    over a resource such as water.
Common Pool Resources
Ostrom observed that historically the problem was often solved
     by small groups of people forming an institution - rules and
     enforcement mechanisms – governing the use of the
     common pool resource.

   Small groups can sometimes solve these issues because the
      “game” is repeated many times, raising significantly the
      benefits of cooperation.

   Small groups of users are also very good at monitoring, so can
      quickly tell if someone is cheating

   Small groups can negotiate agreements at low cost.
Common Pool Resources
By analysing a large number of examples, she derived
    conditions where
   1. A group organised itself to efficiently use a common pool
      resource
   2. Groups were unable to organise themselves to solve the
      tragedy of the commons.
Example: Fishing in Alanya, Turkey

                           •Inshore fishery

                           •Fisherman ballot for a sequence
                           of turns to different spots

                           •Self-monitoring: when it is your
                           turn to good spot you go out
                           early

                           •Group enforcement
Example: grazing Swiss mountaintops

                           •Existed 6 centuries

                           •Well defined private property
                           rights plus common rights to
                           graze cows
                           •Strict rules covering entitlement
                           to graze, boundaries, obligations,
                           enforcements
                           •Democratic evolution of rights
                           •Considerable diversity of rules
                           to meet local needs
Example: Water in Valencia, Spain

                            •Many examples of water rights
                            go back 1000 years in arid region
                            •Irrigation rights clearly
                            specified: farmers can abstract
                            what they need , but only in turn
                            •Open weekly water court still
                            meets, judgements are oral but
                            binding, and can exclude farmers
                            from future access
                            •Self monitoring as water is
                            scarce and farmers waiting their
                            turn observe actions of others.
7 conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(1) Clearly defined boundaries
   Individuals or households who have rights to abstract must be
       clearly defined, as must the boundaries of the CPR
7 conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(2)Appropriate rules for local conditions
   The appropriation rules restricting time, place, technology and
       quantity of extraction are related to local conditions.
7 conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(3)Collective Choice Arrangements
   Most individuals affected by the operational rules can
      participate in modifying the rules
7 conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(4) Monitors
   Monitors, who actively audit CPR conditions and appropriator
      behaviour, are accountable to the appropriators – or are
      the appropriators themselves.
   Low cost monitoring is usually by design: people work in
      teams, or a resource is handed from one user to another
      with incentive to monitor
7 conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(5) Graduated Sanctions
   There should be a graduated scale of punishments for
       violators, taking into account experience and seriousness
       of the offence.
   Punishment is costly. At time external enforcement may be
       needed.
7 Conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(6) Conflict resolution mechanisms
   Appropriators and officials have rapid access to low cost local
      arenas to resolve conflicts among appropriators or
      between appropriators and officials
7 Conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(7) Minimal recognition of rights to organise
   The rights of appropriators to devise their own solutions are
       not challenged by external government authorities
7 Conditions for cooperative solutions to CPR problems

(8) Large systems need nested levels
Limitations and failure

• The above examples tend to be local and
  small (up to several thousand appropriators)

•   Why do cooperative solutions fail, and why
    aren’t there more of them?
Limitations and failure

(1) (Robert Bates) These institutions have
    considerable organisational costs……and
    these costs are themselves a common pool
    resource problem that can be difficult to
    solve.
   There is an incentive to free-ride on these costs
   These cost are much higher when there are heterogeneous
       users and or resource uses
Limitations and failure

(2) Central Government interference.
   There is considerable tension for the desirability of local
       solutions to local circumstances, and the wish for
       Governments to impose “one-size-fits all” rules to achieve
       environmental objectives.

   Central government need to devolve decision making rules to
       local groups

   Need to solve:
   Who exercises the authority to make the rules?
   What is the content of the rules?
Limitations and failure

   Often-times government rules are too clumsy/ lack local
       monitoring and enforcement to solve the problem

   Imposition of external access rules is a major reason for
      collapse of local fisheries in many areas, and for the
      exploitation of local forests.
Limitations and failure

But…..
   Local groups can go off the rails and expropriate, not manage.
       Checks and balances are needed.
   Local groups may need government to solve complex conflict
       situations/ conduct enforcement/ fend off invasive
       outsiders.
   Local groups often need funding…
   => One solution is to form a network of local groups to
       provide counterbalance to government.
Limitations and failure

(3) Rapid increase in resource price/ local population

   Management of a resource is endogenous to the level of
      scarcity. Typically water rights are not needed where
      water is plentiful.
   A steep increase in the incentive to expropriate (one of gains
       are greater than the returns from repeat usage) can
       undermine the incentives for local management.
   Local agents have inadequate ability to compete with
       outsiders
Conclusion
Voluntary mechanisms can work and have worked to
    solve resource issues

There is a lot of knowledge about the circumstances
    where they are successful

Clear boundaries, monitoring, and enforcement are
    crucial.

Appropriate relation with central Government is vital.
Institutions: Markets for quality
and quantity allocation
How could we allocate rights
 to discharge nutrients and
 use water efficiently,
 equitably and acceptably?

How can we handle water if
 we do make it a commodity?
Initial allocation in regulatory context

Perfectly flexible                 Rigid – no
transfers of rights                movement of
(e.g. Perfect                      rights
market)                            (e.g. Non-
                                   transferrable
                                   riparian rights

Only need to focus                 Equity and
on equity                          efficiency may be
                                   in conflict
Water markets (quality or quantity)

•    mobilise private information and innovation
•    are not the only solution / not market or other
     solutions
    Need enough heterogeneous actors and abatement options/ideas to
       make it worthwhile and to function well
    Complementary instruments – education, social pressure, … essential
•    don’t directly raise rights definition,
     monitoring/compliance costs
    Any limit that has property-specific obligations must allocate, monitor
        and enforce.
    Trading can reduce these costs by lowering cost pressure
• Process to define and share allowances is critical
Principles for allocation
  1. Equal sharing

  2. “Polluter pays” – but who is
     responsible?

  3. From each according to his(her) ability
     to pay
Allowance allocation determines cost
sharing/net gains

• Public gains benefits from protection
• Landowners pay mitigation costs
• How allowances are allocated and whether
  auctions/buy backs are used determines final
  cost sharing
• Administrative allocation – determines
  mitigation costs
• In a market:
  Those who can sell, gain.
  Those who need to buy bear extra costs.
Markets: translating principles into allowance
allocation options

                                            Marginal cost
     $

                                   Environmental
                                   limit

         BAU
Unregulated position             Cap                        pristine

                       Controllable nutrients/water use
Markets: translating principles into allowance
allocation options

                                Marginal cost
   $

  P*

       BAU             Cap              Controllable
                                    nutrients/water use
Markets: translating principles into allowance
allocation options

                                         Marginal cost
   $

  P*

                                    Allowance
                                    value

       BAU                    Cap                Controllable
             Abatement cost
                                             nutrients/water use
Cost sharing among sources/users
Equity
1. Compensate for loss in asset value
   Capitalisation of direct mitigation costs and lost opportunities
2. Don’t penalise those who have mitigated
 Allocate on basis of potential not just historic nutrient
  loss/water use
Efficiency
3. Avoid strategic behaviour – ‘baseline grabbing’
    Allocate on fixed or historic basis
4. Minimise adjustment costs
    Allocate on basis of current emissions
Short versus long-term allocation

Short term
Efficiency issues in markets and costs of
  adjustment – tend toward grandparenting
Existing users have paid for value in
  land/improvements values

Long term
Markets are likely to become more efficient.
  Assets depreciate and best practice is easier.
  Farmers with debt have high discount rates
Equity issues dominate – tend toward allocation
  to potential users; community
Key take-away messages on markets and
allocation

• Increase flexibility where possible to reduce
  need to consider efficiency in initial allocation
• Focus on equity of cost bearing (resource
  sharing) – not allocation itself
• Avoid reallocation – set out transition path at
  start
• Make rights clear and stable
  Clear rules for when/how they will change
Summary - value
• Water has many values – some are captured by
  economics and some not
• Which values are important should drive
  governance
• Clearer discussion and better information can lead
  to better decisions
• Role of economics:
  • How to maximise value to collection of individuals
  • How benefits and costs will be distributed across
    individuals
Summary – institutions and markets

Small cohesive                            Large,
group                                     heterogeneous
Low pressure                              group
                                          High pressure

Community                                 Formal regulation
governance       Informs development of
informal         formal institutions
Summary – why markets?

Markets
Engages many actors in searching for solutions

Separate three issues to make decision making simpler

   Environment: Limits and compliance

   Efficiency

   Distribution
www.motu.org.nz
How can we be smart?
Focus on what we really care about – economic
 growth may be the result but it is not the main
 objective
Political freedom
Strong social networks
Absence of corruption

                          Equality and    Social
                          stability of    well-
 Mental health            wellbeing       being
 Friends, family
 Job – job stability
 Relative income levels
What drives wellbeing?
Relative incomes matter most not absolute levels
  (Easterlin Paradox)

Loss of income matters more than gain – therefore focus
  on stability and sustainability

“Political freedom, strong social networks and an
  absence of corruption are together more important
  than income in explaining well-being differences
  between the top and bottom countries. At the individual
  level, good mental and physical health, someone to
  count on, job security and stable families are crucial”
  World Happiness Report
You can also read