Sudden Stops, the Real Exchange Rate and Fiscal Sustainability: Argentina's Lessons

Page created by Kevin Medina
 
CONTINUE READING
Inter-American Development Bank
                                        Research Department

                 Sudden Stops, the Real Exchange Rate
                       and Fiscal Sustainability:
                         Argentina’s Lessons

                                                  by
                                          Guillermo A. Calvo
                                          Alejandro Izquierdo
                                            Ernesto Talvi */

Abstract: We offer an alternative explanation for the fall of Argentina’s Convertibility Program based on
the country’s vulnerability to Sudden Stops in capital flows. Sudden Stops are typically accompanied by a
substantial increase in the real exchange rate that wreaks havoc in countries that are heavily dollarized in
their liabilities, turning otherwise sustainable fiscal and corporate sector positions into unsustainable ones.
In particular, we stress that the required change in relative prices is larger the more closed an economy is in
terms of its supply of tradable goods. By contrasting Argentina’s performance relative to other Latin
American countries that were also subject to the Sudden Stop triggered by the Russian crisis of 1998, we
identify key vulnerability indicators that separated Argentina from its peers. We also provide an
explanation for the political maelstrom that ensued after the Sudden Stop, based on a War of Attrition
argument related to the wealth redistribution conflict triggered by the Sudden Stop and fiscal collapse. This
framework also provides elements to rationalize the banking crisis that accompanied the fall of
Convertibility.

JEL Classification: F34, F41, E61
Keywords: Balance of Payments crisis, sudden stop, dollarization, fiscal sustainability, currency board

                                        First version: March 11, 2002

                                         This version: May 23, 2003

We want to thank Ricardo Caballero, Enrique Mendoza and Rick Mishkin for very useful comments and
Luis Fernando Mejía for excellent research assistance. The views expressed in this document are the
authors’ and do not necessarily reflect those of the Inter-American Development Bank.
*/ Guillermo Calvo, Inter-American Development Bank and NBER; e-mail: calvo@econ.umd.edu;
Alejandro Izquierdo, Inter-American Deve lopment Bank; e- mail: alejandroi@iadb.org;
Ernesto Talvi, Center for Economic and Social Policy Research (CERES); e- mail: etalvi@ceres-uy.org.
1. Introduction

   The fall of the Convertibility Program (i.e., the currency board regime) in Argentina

has stirred a lively discussion about the causes for its collapse. Several explanations have

been offered. The most popular one relates to the unholy combination of a fixed

exchange rate and large fiscal deficits that led to a rapid growth in public debt, severe

fiscal sustainability problems, and eventually, a loss of access to the credit markets.

Another popular view stresses the impact of a fixed exchange rate regime coupled with

devaluation by Argentina’s major trading partners as an important cause of real exchange

rate (RER) misalignment, which reduced profitability in the tradable sector. This, in turn,

slowed down investment and led the economy into a protracted recession as it deflated

away the RER disequilibrium.

    The purpose of this paper is to provide a different interpretation of the collapse of

Convertibility, which places special emphasis on two key structural characteristics of

Argentina’s productive and financial structure and on political economy considerations.

   Our point of departure is the Russian crisis of August 1998, which drastically

changed the behavior of capital markets. We believe that developments at the center of

capital markets were key to producing an unexpected, severe, and prolonged stop in

capital flows (hereon referred to as Sudden Stop, SS) to Emerging Market economies,

and Latin America was no exception.

    We will argue that in the case of Argentina two considerations played a crucial role

in magnifying the effect of the sudden stop in capital flows and in creating the fiscal and

financial problems that eventually Argentina had to confront, namely:

                                              2
a) A relatively closed economy, i.e., an economy with a small share of tradable

         goods output (more specifically, output that could swiftly be transformed into

         exports) relative to domestic absorption of tradable goods;

     b) Liability Dollarization (more specifically, large financial currency-denomination

         mismatches) in both the private and public sector.

     Being closed implies that the Sudden Stop (SS) may call for a sharp increase in the

equilibrium real exchange rate, RER (i.e., real depreciation). Liability Dollarization, in

turn, entails foreign-exchange-denominated debt in “peso producing” sectors (mostly

non-tradables) including the government, which implies large balance sheet effects when

the RER rises. Thus, these two factors represented a dangerous financial cocktail for

both the private sector and the government.

      Argentina’s Fall from Paradise could be rationalized by its commercial closed-ness,

and penchant for dollar indexation in the corporate sector. In that sense, the tragedy

needs no fisc to grab one’s imagination. Under liability dollarization the need for a sharp

(equilibrium) real devaluation in the aftermath of the SS hit first and foremost corporate

balance sheets. Perhaps more importantly, it lowered the collateral of non-tradable

sectors, which, by and of itself, brings about a stock retrenchment of credit to the non-

tradable sector (see, for example, Izquierdo, 1999 1). Hence, to the first exogenous

Sudden Stop, a second round follows, which validates and likely deepens the impact of

the first.

1
  This model assumes that non-tradable collateral is accepted by foreign creditors. In other models, such
as Caballero and Krishnamurty, 2003, where only tradable collateral is accepted and assumed to be fixed,
falls in the price of non-tradables do not have an effect on output because tradable collateral remains
unaffected. Even if this were the case, crises of this magnitude, which bring along fiscal un-sustainability,
could also alter the amount of tradable collateral since the tradable sector may be exposed to confiscation
from the public sector.

                                                      3
This kind of shock can only be met by a sale of assets, financial restructuring or

the initiation of bankruptcy procedures. No flow “belt tightening” of the corporate sector

could probably do the trick. The problem here, though, is that the shock hits a whole

sector, not just an individual firm. Prospects for individual firms are hard to assess when

they belong to a network immersed in financial difficulties. Thus, assets can only be sold

at rock-bottom prices, and financial restructurings and bankruptcy procedures are

especially hard and time consuming, which precipitate the economy into a protracted

recession. Under these circumstances, cries for help will likely rise from every corner,

and it will be politically very difficult for the government to stay put and wait for the dust

to settle – thus, unavoidably bringing into play strong and complex political economy

factors.

           A strong fisc could have come to the rescue by effectively socializing private

debts or providing additional collateral (like in Korea’s IMF-orchestrated bank

negotiations with external creditors in 1997, which eventually resulted in a rise in public

debt equivalent to more than 30 percent of GDP). As argued in Calvo, 2002b, the

government can play an important role in cases in which the economy is hit by low-

probability shocks, like the aftermath of the Russian 1998 crisis.2 However, and this is

when the fisc kicks in, given the financial structure of the public sector, Argentina’s

government was also exposed to exactly the same financial problems as the private sector

following the SS and the RER rise. The government thus became part of the problem

rather than (as in Korea) part of the solution. But our view departs from the fiscalist view

2
  The Russian crisis was not a low probability event. Savvy investors knew that sooner or later a crisis was
likely to erupt. Our claim, however, is that it was hard to even imagine, ex ante, that a crisis in a country
that represents less than 1 percent of world output would have such devastating effect on the world capital
market.

                                                      4
of the Convertibility’s demise. Argentina was fiscally weak (i.e. vulnerable to a Sudden

Stop) not because it had an unreasonably large current (flow) fiscal deficit –which it did

not— inconsistent with the fixed exchange rate regime. Argentina´s fiscal weakness lay

in that the government was unable to offset the fundamental vulnerabilities associated

with the country’s closed-ness and Liability Dollarization, the latter impinging upon both

public and private debt.

        Adding together private and public debt, and computing its share in GDP after the

Sudden Stop (involving a higher RER), it is clear that Argentina’s debt was dangerously

high, as early as 1999. For the sake of the argument, consider the case in which the

government socializes the larger GDP-equivalent debt incurred by corporates after such

change in the RER (which, as will be argued, hovers around 60 percent). Under those

circumstances, we will argue that the government would have been required to produce a

permanently larger primary surplus in excess of 3% of GDP. Permanently is a key word.

Sustaining higher levels of debt by implicitly collateralizing it with future flows of

primary surpluses is an extraordinarily difficult task since, for starters, future flows

depend on future governments. If credibility on future surpluses is at stake, the ability to

roll over the stock of debt would be severely hampered, creating a stock retrenchment

problem for the government, potentially as severe as that suffered by the private sector.

To illustrate this point, it is sufficient to say that a failure to produce such an adjustment

of the primary surplus on a permanent basis would have implied a 75% haircut on the

existing debt.

        To avoid a painful default, Argentina had to permanently and credibly raise its

primary surpluses. This could only occur by raising taxes or reducing primary spending.

                                               5
Raising taxes is particularly problematic when the corporate sector itself is under severe

financial stress and arrears with the public sector become very significant as a source of

financing. 3 As a result, raising taxes on the non-corporate sector and /or reducing

primary expenditures were the only options available, absent debt restructuring.

      The government was thus forced to engage in wealth redistribution policies across

sectors. This is where politics kicks in with full force, and phenomena like War of

Attrition among different groups in society develop. Wealth redistribution sets in motion

a tug-of-war in which decisions are delayed and, as the War of Attrition literature shows

(see Sturzenegger and Tommasi, 1998), can be highly disruptive. Thus, unless a

supranational entity generates a cooperative equilibrium, the impasse may take a long

time to resolve and may seriously deepen the extent of the crisis. Since no positive rate

of return can match losing a chunk of capital to the taxman’s ax, this impasse in resolving

which sectors would ultimately sustain the losses, brought about a grinding stop to all

investment projects, except for those few that could be safely shielded from the bloodbath

(e.g., black-market transactions). Under these circumstances, tax revenue falls, further

weakening the government’s fiscal situation. This, in turn, increases the expected

devaluation and sets in motion a new wave of credit cuts.

      At this stage, politically feasible solutions were inevitably going to involve spreading

the cost of adjustment among all players, making some type of debt restructuring

inevitable. In turn, expectations of debt restructuring would severely hit the banking

system to the extent that most of its assets consisted of government debt and dollar loans

to non-tradable sectors. It should therefore come as no surprise that a bank run

materialized as a corollary of the Sudden Stop.

3
    Moreover, under the corporate bailout scenario assumed above, this option would simply not be available.

                                                      6
Finally, a word on the role of the Convertibility regime itself. Argentina’s adherence

to its hard peg to the dollar probably made things worse, but for reasons not necessarily

related to competitiveness. As argued in Talvi (1997), incomplete but inevitable

adjustments can mask the gravity of the underlying fiscal situation. In the case of

Argentina, maintaining the peg and delaying the inevitable adjustment of the RER may

have contributed to conceal the true nature of its financial problems for a long period of

time, leaving politicians and the general public largely unaware of the gravity of the

financial situation, a factor that might have contributed to undermine the political support

for the necessary fiscal and financial adjustments. Furthermore, maintaining the peg left

Argentina without a valuable instrument of the adjustment package, namely, inflation,

which has proven, time and again, to be a very powerful tool for lowering government

expenditure (in real terms).

   The paper is organized as follows: Section 2 examines capital market trends in Latin

America following the Russian crisis of 1998 and provides a rationale for Sudden Stop

behavior. Specifically, we show that the nature of Sudden Stops has typically been large

and persistent. Section 3 dwells on conditions under which Sudden Stops lead to a sharp

depreciation of the RER, and ranks a set of Latin American countries in terms of

vulnerability to these shocks. Section 4 focuses more closely on Argentina. It discusses

fiscal sustainability and determines the sources of vulnerability to swift changes in the

RER, and computes how those changes affected Argentina’s fiscal position. Section 5

dwells on the effects of RER adjustment on the materialization of contingent liabilities

(particularly those arising from currency-denomination mismatches in the corporate

sector). We compute how Argentina’s fiscal position would have deteriorated even

                                             7
further under the assumption that the government would attempt (as it eventually did) to

bail out the corporate sector. Section 6 briefly touches upon the concealment of the

financial problems under Argentina’s hard peg, and analyzes likely performance under a

floating exchange rate regime following a Sudden Stop. The paper concludes with some

policy lessons for Latin America that emerge from Argentina’s experience, and an

Appendix that reviews the policies followed by Argentina.

2. The World Scene after Russia

Russia’s August 1998 crisis represents a milestone in the development of emerging

capital markets. Massive capital inflows that set sail to Latin America in the early 1990s,

financing high growth rates and large current account deficits, came all of a sudden to a

standstill following Russia’s partial foreign debt repudiation in August, 1998. It was hard

to imagine how a crisis in a country with little if any financial or trading ties to Latin

America could have such profound effects on the region. This puzzle seriously

questioned traditional explanations for financial crises (based on current account and

fiscal deficits) and led analysts to focus on the intrinsic behavior of capital markets. Thus,

it was argued that prevailing rules for capital market transactions may have been

responsible for the spread of shocks from one country to other regions (Calvo, 1999). 4

4
  As the argument goes, to the extent that there exist large fixed costs (relative to the size of projects) in
obtaining information about a particular country, resulting economies of scale lead to the formation of
clusters of specialists, or informed investors, who lead capital markets. These investors leverage their
portfolios to finance their investments and are subject to margin calls in the event of a fall in the price of
assets placed as collateral. Remaining investors, the uninformed, observe transactions made by informed
investors, but are subject to a signal-extraction problem, given that they must figure out whether sales of
the informed are motivated by lower returns on projects or by the informed facing margin calls. As long as
the variance of returns to projects is sufficiently high relative to the variance of margin calls, uninformed
investors may easily interpret massive asset sales as an indication of lower returns and decide to get rid of
their holdings as well, even though the cause for informed investors’ sales was indeed due to margin calls.

                                                       8
In Figure 1, spreads measured by the EMBI+ index show a dramatic increase

following the Russian crisis. Although they have since decreased, spreads exhibit a

substantial gap compared to pre-crisis levels, exceeding 250 basis points for 2001. 5 This

gap was much higher for 1999 and 2000 (over 700 basis points and 300 basis points,

respectively, see Table 1).

        Latin American markets were not the only ones hit by the higher cost of capital.

For most EMs higher interest rates were accompanied by a large reduction in capital

inflows. Figure 2 and Table 2 show that for the seven biggest Latin American economies

the decline was sharp, particularly for portfolio flows, mimicking the sharp interest rate

hike. The fact that the root of this phenomenon lied in Russia’s crisis indicates that the

capital-inflow slowdown contained a large unexpected component. “Large and highly

unexpected” are the two defining characteristics of what the literature calls Sudden Stop

(see Calvo and Reinhart, 2000). New information that a standstill in the capital account

can materialize for rather exogenous reasons (and for a whole region) such as the Russian

crisis, generating drastic effects on government sustainability (either because of debt

revaluation effects or the emergence of contingent liabilities), may reduce the appetite for

holding assets of countries that may be subject to big swings in the RER and are highly

dollarized in their liabilities. Thus, this realization could bring the capital account to a

lengthy standstill.

5
 We compare the lowest 1998 pre-crisis spread level to yearly averages of the spread measure in following
years.

                                                    9
Figure 1

       External Financial Conditions
       (EMBI+, Spread over US Treasuries)

1800
                                                                                                                           EMBI+
1600                                                                                                                       W/O Argentina

1400

1200

1000

 800

 600

 400
                               Oct-98

                                                                     Oct-99

                                                                                                         Oct-00

                                                                                                                                             Oct-01
   Jan-98

                                        Jan-99

                                                                              Jan-00

                                                                                                                  Jan-01
                      Jul-98

                                                           Jul-99

                                                                                                Jul-00

                                                                                                                                    Jul-01
             Apr-98

                                                  Apr-99

                                                                                       Apr-00

                                                                                                                           Apr-01
                                                 Source: JP Morgan Chase.

                                                                    Table 1

  Difference in Bond Spreads with Minimum Pre-Crisis Levels
                                   1999    2000       2001
            EMBI +                  666     307        393

            EMBI + w/o Argentina                                                        757                       315                        259

Source: JP Morgan Chase. Note: Values are yearly averages.

                                                                          10
Figure 2

                    Sudden Stop in LAC
                    (Capital flows, % of GDP)
               6%

               5%

               4%

               3%

               2%

               1%

               0%
                                                  1998-III

                                                                                            1999-III

                                                                                                                                   2000-III
                                                                                                                         2000-II

                                                                                                                                                                 2001-II
                     1997-IV

                                                             1998-IV

                                                                                                                                              2000-IV
                                        1998-II

                                                                                 1999-II

                                                                                                       1999-V
                               1998-I

                                                                       1999-I

                                                                                                                2000-I

                                                                                                                                                        2001-I
                Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela

                                             Source: Corresponding Central Banks.

                                                                                Table 2

                                  Capital Flows, % of GDP
                                                 1998.II  2001.III                                                                                      Reversal
             Capital Flows                         5.6       1.6                                                                                          -4.0
              Non-FDI Capital Flows                2.0      -0.9                                                                                          -2.9
              FDI                                  3.6       2.5                                                                                          -1.1

             Note: Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and
             Venezuela. Source: Corresponding Central Banks.

       Sudden Stops usually lead to a significant cut in current account deficits. Starting

in the fourth quarter of 1998, key Latin American countries showed a steady decline in

their current account deficits, which eventually reached a zero balance by the end of

                                                                                           11
2000. 6 This adjustment of the current account was on average equivalent to 5 percentage

points of GDP for the seven biggest Latin American economies (see Figure 3).

                                                                                               Figure 3

                      Sudden Stop and the Current Account in LAC
                      (4 quarters, % of GDP)

                 0%

                -1%

                -2%

                -3%

                -4%

                -5%

                -6%
                                          1997-III

                                                                                  1998-III

                                                                                                                                                                                                         2001-III
                                                                                                                          1999-III

                                                                                                                                                                 2000-III
                                                                        1998-II

                                                                                                                                                                                               2001-II
                                1997-II

                                                                                                                1999-II

                                                                                                                                                       2000-II
                       1997-I

                                                                                                                                              2000-I
                                                     1997-IV

                                                                                             1998-IV

                                                                                                                                                                            2000-IV
                                                               1998-I

                                                                                                       1999-I

                                                                                                                                                                                      2001-I
                                                                                                                                     1999-V

                  Includes Argentina, Brazil, Chile, Colombia, Mexico, Peru, and Venezuela

                                                         Source: Corresponding Central Banks.

3. Sudden Stops and Real Exchange Rate Adjustment

         So far we have made a case for the large external component accounting for the

observed fall in capital inflows. But what are the consequences of this event in terms of

RER behavior and debt sustainability analysis? Two key elements in this discussion are

6
  Although FDI flows fell on average in the aftermath of the Russian crisis, they did increase significantly
in Brazil, where FDI flows rose 80 percent in dollar terms from the second quarter of 1998 to the second
quarter of 2001. We follow up on this fact because it may be an important element behind the resumption
of capital flows to Brazil. A possible explanation is that higher interest rates led to sharp declines in
domestic collateral, adding to the perception that this asset class was more risky than expected. Thus,
domestic firms found it more difficult to finance the current operations and expansion plans, further

                                                                                                           12
the unexpected component of the Sudden Stop and its duration. It is clear that

expectations prevailing before the Russian crisis are unlikely to have factored in the

widespread effects on EMs that followed, so the unexpected element required for a

Sudden Stop is met. A different question is whether this shock was perceived as

temporary or highly persistent, which is quite relevant from a policy perspective. With

the benefit of hindsight it is easy to argue that the shock had a large permanent

component, since the stalling in capital inflows has lasted more than three years now. But

it is not clear that it was perceived as such from the very beginning (this is an important

point that we will revisit when we discuss Argentina in greater detail). Indeed, investors

and policymakers had witnessed a quick recovery of capital flows following the Mexican

(Tequila) crisis in 1995, which could have led them to expect a similar quick recovery

after the Russian collapse. But things turned out differently. Figure 4 shows that two

years after the Mexican crisis there was more than a complete recovery of capital flows,

whereas there has been no recovery in capital flows to the region since 1998 following

the Russian crisis.

depressing their plants’ market value. This may have opened attractive investment opportunities for G7-
based firms whose collateral was insulated from EM financial turmoil, leading to a sharp increase in FDI.

                                                    13
Figure 4

                   Sudden Stop in LAC
                   (Net private capital flows, US$ billions)
              75

              70

              65

              60

              55

              50

              45

              40
                      Tequila       Russia
              35
                        T                T+1               T+2              T+3

Note: “LAC” refers to Western Hemisphere countries, according to IMF definition.. “T” denotes the
year of occurrence of the crisis. Source: World Economic Outlook (IMF), December 2001.

        Sudden stops are also typically accompanied by large contractions in international

reserves and declines in the relative price of non-tradables with respect to tradables (i.e.,

real currency depreciation). By way of illustration, consider the case of a small open

economy that experiences a current account deficit before a Sudden Stop takes place. By

definition:

                                CAD = A * + S * −Y *,                                         (1)

where CAD is the current account deficit, A* is absorption of tradable goods, S*

represents net factor payments and transfers, and Y* is the supply of tradable goods. If

financing of the current account deficit is stopped, the full amount of that imbalance

                                                14
needs to be cut. Table 3 shows that current account adjustment can be sharp. Indeed, it is

not uncommon to see an abrupt adjustment towards current account balance within a year

following the Sudden Stop.

                                                  Table 3

                                  Current Account Balance, US$ billions
                                      ARG       BRA        CHL        COL     ECU
                       1998            -14.5    -33.4       -4.1       -5.2   -2.2
                       1999            -11.9    -25.4       -0.1        0.2    0.9
                       2000             -8.9    -24.6       -1.0        0.3    0.7
                       2001             -5.6    -23.2       -0.9       -2.1   -0.8

                              Current Account Change, % of 1998 Imports
                                     ARG       BRA       CHL       COL        ECU
                   1999 vs 1998       6.1      10.6      18.8      31.3       49.0
                   2001 vs 1998       21.1     13.5      14.9      18.0       21.3

              Source: World Economic Outlook (IMF), April 2002.

            A measure of the percentage fall in the absorption of tradable goods needed to

restore equilibrium is given by:

                                   η = CAD / A* = 1 − ω ,                                    (2)

where ω is a measure of the un-leveraged absorption of tradable goods, defined as:

                                   ω = (Y * − S *) / A * .                                   (3)

Notice that this measure captures the share of absorption of tradable goods that is

financed by the domestic supply of tradable goods.7 The lower this value, the higher will

be the share of absorption of tradables financed from abroad. In other words, relatively

closed economies with a small supply of tradable goods running a current account deficit

7
    Net of non-factor payments.

                                                     15
will be highly leveraged. As we will see later, this is an important consideration

regarding RER behavior after a sudden stop in capital flows.

        In order to obtain an estimate for η that can be used for cross-country

comparisons, we proxy A* by imports. We use the observed current account adjustment

for different periods, taken as a share of imports at the time of the crisis, in order to

illustrate the observed percentage fall in absorption of tradable goods that was required to

accommodate the change in the current account. Results are shown in Table 3 for 1999

and 2001. Countries like Chile, Colombia, and Ecuador, where the percentage fall ranged

anywhere from 18.8 to 49 percent, experienced a quick and substantial adjustment in

absorption of tradable goods by 1999. Adjustment in Brazil and Argentina has taken

longer, a phenomenon that we will analyze in more detail later.

        Having shown that the percentage fall of tradable goods absorption can be

substantial after a Sudden Stop, we now consider effects on non-tradable goods. A

common assumption in the literature is that preferences are homothetic, implying that the

income expansion path of tradable vis-a-vis non-tradable goods is linear. Under this

assumption, for a given RER, consumption of non-tradable goods is therefore

proportional to that of tradable goods.8 As a result, a decline in demand for tradable

goods of size η must be matched by a proportional fall of equal size in the demand for

non-tradable goods. Now consider the effects of this fall in demand on the RER. Given

that the price of tradable goods is determined from abroad, all we need to take into

account is the behavior of the non-tradable goods market. Define demand for non-

tradables as:

                                              16
h = a − χp ,                                                             (4)

where h is (the log of) demand for non-tradable goods, p is (the log of) the relative price

of non-tradable to tradable goods, i.e., the inverse of the RER, χ is a parameter, and a

captures the income effect. Then, for a given RER, the fall in demand following a Sudden

Stop is simply:

                                 da = η = 1 − ω .                                                         (5)

Assuming, for simplicity, that the supply of non-tradable goods is fixed (so that dh = 0),

then the required percentage change in the real exchange, after differentiation of (4), is

given by:

                                 − dp = (1 − ω ) / χ ;                                                    (6)

That is to say, the higher is the leveraged absorption of tradables, i.e. the lower is ω , the

higher the impact on the RER needed to restore equilibrium after a Sudden Stop. The

intuition for this result is that, in the short run, the ability to generate purchasing power in

terms of tradables is exports minus debt service. Thus, a Sudden Stop that requires a

larger proportional sacrifice in absorption in terms of tradables, the smaller is ω. Another

element that affects our measure of absorption leverage is non-factor payments (S*),

typically composed of interest payments, which implicitly captures indebtedness levels.

High external indebtedness therefore reduces available resources to finance absorption of

tradable goods, requiring greater RER realignment following the elimination of the

current account deficit. Given these characteristics, ω is a good summary statistic to

measure the impact on RER realignment. A further simplifying assumption we make is

8
  In what follows we abstract from investment. This is indeed a major omission, which is, however, likely
to be less misleading in a steady state context such as the present one. Catena and Talvi, 2001, reach similar
results in terms of a full- fledged dynamic model.

                                                     17
that the supply of tradable goods can be measured by exports whereas, as earlier noted,

imports serve as a proxy for absorption of tradables.9 Table 4 contains a list of Latin

American EMs ranked by this measure in 1998. Chile clearly leads the ranking in terms

of un-leveraged absorption. Argentina, although not the lowest ranked in the group,

stands 15 percentage points below Chile, indicating that it would need greater RER

realignment following a Sudden Stop.

                                                       Table 4

                          Un-leveraged Absorption Coefficient ( ω)
                           BRA        ARG       ECU        COL        CHL
                            0.56      0.66      0.66       0.70       0.81

                          Source: World Economic Outlook (IMF), and own
                          estimates. Note: Values are given for 1998.

           Another key element in determining the size of the required change in the RER is

given by the price elasticity of the demand for home goods, χ. Estimates for developing

countries are typically much lower than those for industrial countries, implying that

Sudden Stops can be much more devastating for EMs. Thus, not only are Sudden Stops a

much more common feature of developing countries (see Calvo and Reinhart, 2000), but

their effects can be more dangerous as well. Actually, the higher vulnerability of EMs to

Sudden Stops could partly explain their higher recurrence.

           Given this framework, we next ask what should be the size of RER realignment

following a Sudden Stop that requires a full adjustment of the current account deficit,

using 1998 as a starting point. To compute this, we make use of equation (6), taking a

value of χ = 0.4 (the lowest point estimate in the literature). Given that we measure the

9
    A scenario that is makes sense in the short run.

                                                         18
RER as the inverse of (antilog of) p, the rate of depreciation is -dp. Obviously, these

figures should not be taken at face value, but as a way of ranking the effects of a Sudden

Stop across countries.10 Table 5 shows the results. As it stands, this exercise indicates that

Argentina would have needed to depreciate its RER by 46 percent in order to bring down

its current account to zero, whereas Chile, for example would only have needed to

depreciate its RER by 32 percent. This means that Argentina would have needed to

depreciate its RER about 43 percent more than Chile in order to close the current account

gap.

                                               Table 5

                            Required % Change in Equilibrium RER
                         BRA      ARG      ECU        COL      CHL
                         52.5      46.2     46.1       43.0    32.4

                      Source: World Economic Outlook (IMF), and own
                      estimates. Note: Values are given for 1998.

        Moreover, since the Russian crisis, between 1998 and 2001Chile depreciated its

currency vis-à-vis the dollar by about 45 percent in real terms, and closed a current

account gap of almost 19 percent of imports. Chile’s current account deficit was

equivalent to 6 percent of GDP in 1998 and fell to zero in 1999. In this respect, it would

look like Chile’s adjustment was larger than that of Argentina, whose current account

deficit fell from 4.9 percent of GDP in 1998 to 2.4 percent of GDP in 2001. However, if

Argentina’s reduction in the current account gap is measured as a share of imports (the

relevant measure from our perspective), the reduction was also 19 percent, similar to the

adjustment observed in Chile. According to our model, Argentina’s depreciation should

10
  Here we have made several strong assumptions, such as that the supply of both tradable and non-tradable
goods are constant, and that the price elasticity of demand of non-tradables is low and the same across

                                                   19
have been at least as large as that of Chile (45 percent), clearly indicating that the

depreciation of the RER that effectively took place in Argentina (around 14 percent) was

far from sufficient given the underlying adjustment in the current account. 11 The slow

adjustment of RER observed in Argentina can be explained by the combination of a fixed

exchange rate and price stickiness (a relevant feature given the weight of public wages

and public utility fees in price behavior), which retarded the adjustment of the RER.

4. Debt Valuation and Fiscal Sustainability

        We now turn our attention to the effects of RER depreciation on fiscal

sustainability. It is not uncommon to find countries where public sector debt is largely

denominated in terms of tradables (see Table 6) and government revenue comes to a large

extent from non-tradable activities. This introduces a currency mismatch in the public

sector balance sheet, which makes any sustainability analysis highly susceptible to RER

swings.

        Consider the typical sustainability calculation, where the size of the primary

surplus necessary to keep a constant ratio of debt to GDP is computed, given a cost of

funds, and a growth rate for the economy. Take the standard asset accumulation

equation:

                                             (1 + r )
                                bt +1 = bt            − st ,                                             (7)
                                             (1 + θ )

countries. Again, these figures do not attempt to match observed figures, but to illustrate the main
transmission channels behind Sudden Stops.
11
   Had Argentina reduced its current account balance to zero, the required adjustment should have been
higher than that of Chile, as illustrated in Table 5.

                                                       20
where b is the debt to GDP ratio, r is the real interest rate on debt, θ is the GDP growth

rate, s is the primary surplus as a share of GDP, and t denotes time. To obtain a constant

                     −
debt to GDP ratio ( b ), the budget surplus must satisfy, assuming constant r and θ:

                                   −  (1 + r )    
                               s = b           − 1.                                            (8)
                                      (1 + θ ) 

                                                         −
Key to this analysis is the initial debt to GDP ratio ( b ), which, in turn, depends on its

denomination in terms of tradables and non-tradables. This ratio can be expressed as:

                                       −    B + eB *
                                       b=            ,                                           (9)
                                            Y + eY *

where e is the RER (defined as the price of tradables relative to non-tradables), B is debt

payable in terms of non-tradables, B* is debt payable in terms of tradables, Y is output of

non-tradables, and Y* is output of tradables. Obviously, debt composition, as well as

output composition, matter a great deal for sustainability analysis, because mismatches

between debt and output composition can lead to substantial differences in valuation of

the debt/GDP ratio following a real currency depreciation. For example, consider the
                      −
limit case in which b = eB * / Y , where all valuation effects take place on debt only.

This is the worst scenario in which RER depreciation hits fully on sustainability.

Another case that is particularly relevant is that in which (B / eB *) / (Y / eY *) = 1, i.e.,

when the composition of debt and output is perfectly matched. When this condition

holds, a change in the RER has no effect on fiscal sustainability. Table 6 shows how

countries ranked in terms of mismatch at the time of the Russian crisis.12 A value of 1

would indicate a perfect match, and a value of zero would indicate the highest degree of

                                                  21
mismatch. Clearly, the highest mismatch holds for Argentina. On the other side of the

spectrum lies Chile, the best-matched economy, with a value of 0.45.

                                                 Table 6

                            Public Sector Debt Mismatch Measure
                                 ARG        ECU      COL       BRA                     CHL
                  B/e B*          0.08      0.02      0.59      1.76                   1.30
                 Y/e Y*           8.63      2.94      6.36     12.34                   2.85
            (B/e B*)/(Y/e Y*)     0.01      0.01      0.09      0.14                   0.45

           Source: Own estimates. Note: Values are given for 1998.

For comparison purposes, we consider the effects of a RER rise of 50 percent on debt

valuation and fiscal sustainability for all the countries we selected, as of 1998. The

results are presented in Table 713. We see clearly that under this scenario, Argentina,

together with Ecuador, would be the hardest hit economy in terms of debt revaluation.

Just because of the relative price adjustment (holding the assumption that interest rates on

public debt and GDP growth remain unchanged), Argentina’s debt/GDP ratio would

jump from 36.5 percent of GDP to 50.8 percent of GDP, an increase of nearly 40 percent

on impact. Quite a different scenario plays out for Chile, where the debt revaluation

effect is minimal: public sector debt as a share of GDP increases from 17.3 percent to

18.7 percent. It is interesting to see that in the case of Brazil, a 50 percent rise in the

RER only affects the debt/GDP ratio by 14 percent. As we shall see later, in our view

this was a key element, together with a substantial adjustment in the primary surplus, to

12
   We proxy output of tradable goods (Y*) with exports. This measure is particularly relevant in the short
run, although it could underestimate tradable output in the long run.
13
   Calculations were made assuming that debt is issued either in terms of tradable goods, or in terms of
non-tradable goods. When debt is issued in domestic currency, the relevant price index for valuation
purposes is the consumer price level, which typically includes a share of tradable goods in the basket it
values. In this respect, real depreciation should affect the valuation of domestic-currency-denominated
debt through the tradable component of the price level, making the effects of a RER rise larger than

                                                    22
explain Brazil’s success in controlling its fiscal position after the real currency

depreciation it experienced in 1999.

                                                   Table 7

                          Fiscal Sustainability Under a 50% RER Depreciation
                                                ARG       BRA     CHL        COL                  ECU
    (a) Base Exercise
    Observed Public Debt (% of GDP)              36.5        51.0         17.3         28.4       81.0
     Real Interest Rate                           7.1         5.8          5.9         7.3         6.3
     Real GDP Growth                              3.8         2.0          7.5         3.6         2.6
    Observed Primary Surplus (% of GDP)           0.9         0.6          0.6         -3.0       -0.2

    i. Req. Primary Surplus (% of GDP)           1.2          1.9          n.a.         1.0        2.9
    (b) Change in Relative Prices
    Real Exchange Rate Depreciation              50.0        50.0         50.0         50.0       50.0
    Imputed Public Debt (% of GDP)               50.8        58.1         18.7         34.9       107.2
     Real Interest Rate                           7.1         5.8          5.9         7.3         6.3
     Real GDP Growth                              3.8         2.0          7.5         3.6         2.6

    ii. Req. Primary Surplus (% of GDP)          1.6          2.2          n.a.         1.2        3.9

    NPV of ii - i (% of GDP)                     14.3         7.1          n.a.        6.5        26.3
     Corresponding Debt Reduction (%)            28.2        12.2          n.a.        18.7       24.5
    ii - i (% of Government Expenditures)        2.3          1.0          n.a.         1.3        4.5

    Source: Own estimates. Note: Values are given for 1998. n.a.: Not applicable given that the
    real interest rate is smaller than the growth of GDP, so sustainability is not a concern.

         We also consider the effects on the required primary surplus following a rise in

the RER. Making use of equations (8) and (9), we calculate the required primary surplus

after revaluation of the debt/GDP ratio.14 It is important to note that these calculations

implicitly assume that the shock is permanent. Had the shock been temporary, the effects

on sustainability would be a lot less and, consequently, the need for adjustment would be

estimated here. This can be interpreted as the case where a portion of this debt is issued in terms of
tradable goods, so that the valuation effects of RER depreciation are larger.

                                                        23
smaller. But as it became apparent after the 1998 Russian crisis, this shock was highly

persistent, implying that the adjustment in the RER and its effect on debt valuation was

large as well. Of course, this was not clear at the time of the crisis, which led to

underestimating the necessary fiscal adjustment.

            Taking as a benchmark the case in which the RER depreciation is permanent, we

estimate changes in the required primary surplus needed for sustainability. The biggest

correction is for Ecuador (about 1 point of GDP). Argentina, for example, would require

an adjustment of 0.4 points of GDP. In order to assess the significance of this

adjustment, we estimate the net present value of the difference between the required

primary surplus before and after the RER depreciation, which is equivalent to the change

in debt before and after the shock, measured in percentage points of GDP.15 This figure

would be equivalent to 14.3 points of GDP for Argentina, and as much as 26.3 points of

GDP for Ecuador. Besides, these figures only represent changes in the required primary

surplus, and, in most cases, countries had much lower observed primary surpluses than

those required, meaning that the need for adjustment was much higher. In summary,

once again we see that highly indebted, dollarized and closed economies are bad

candidates to accommodate RER swings that will be fiscally sustainable.

            Given that we have used exports as a proxy for tradable goods output in these

calculations, we run the risk of overestimating the effects of RER depreciation because

tradable goods output will typically be higher than exports. In order to assess the

14
  Assuming interest rates and GDP growth remain at initial levels, which underestimates the required
primary surplus.
15
     This is computed as   ( s * − s )(1 + θ ) /( r − θ ) , where s* is the required primary surplus after the rise in RER (real
currency depreciation), s is the required primary surplus before the rise in RER, r is the real interest rate, and θ is the
growth rate of the economy. This is obtained by solving (7) forward and taking the difference between the stream of flows
valued at s* with respect to the stream of flows valued at s. In other words, it measures the change in debt (in percentage
points of GDP) that corresponds to the permanent increase in the primary surplus.

                                                                24
significance of this shortcut, we compare results against a more thorough measure of

tradable output typically used for this calculation. This measure defines a category of

output as tradable when imports plus exports of goods similar to those produced in that

category exceeds output by more than 5 percent. This is performed for categories defined

by the national accounting system at a one-digit level. Results are shown in Table 8. 16

                                                      Table 8

                         Fiscal Sustainability under a 50% Depreciation
                                         ARG         BRA      CHL       COL                    ECU
(a) Base Exercise
Observed Public Debt (% of GDP)              36.5                     17.3         28.4         81.0
 Real Interest Rate                           7.1                     5.9           7.3         6.3
 Real GDP Growth                              3.8                     7.5           3.6         2.6
Observed Primary Surplus (% of GDP)           0.9                     0.6          -3.0         -0.2

Req. Primary Surplus (% of GDP)              1.2                       n.a.         1.0          2.9
(b) Change in Relative Prices
Real Exchange Rate Depreciation              50.0                     50.0         50.0         50.0
Imputed Public Debt (% of GDP)               47.2                     18.1         32.3         98.9
 Real Interest Rate                           7.1                     5.9          7.3          6.3
 Real GDP Growth                              3.8                     7.5          3.6          2.6

Req. Primary Surplus (% of GDP)              1.5                       n.a.         1.1          3.6

NPV of i - ii (% of GDP)                     10.7                      n.a.        3.9          17.9
  Corresponding Debt Reduction (%)           22.7                      n.a.        12.1         18.1
i - ii (% of Government Expenditures)         1.7                      n.a.        0.8          3.1

Source: Own estimates. Note: Values are given for 1998.

         As can be seen by comparing Table 8 with Table 7, although there are some

differences in debt to GDP ratios, the required primary surplus following an adjustment

16
   Results for Brazil could not be computed, given that national accounts data is not split according to
standard classification.

                                                     25
in relative prices does not change substantially, implying that our first approximation is

indeed a good one to evaluate the effects of a Sudden Stop.17

         Now that we have provided examples of the effects on the RER of closing the

current account gap, and examples of debt revaluation for a given depreciation of the

RER, we put both pieces together for the case of Argentina, and analyze the effects of a

sudden stop in capital inflo ws in 1998 (results are summarized in Table 9). In our

example, following a Sudden Stop, Argentina’s RER would have to rise by about 46

percent. Had this depreciation occurred, the country would have displayed a debt/GDP

ratio of 49.7 percent, a considerably larger value than that observed in 1998 (which was

36.5 percent of GDP). Under favorable growth and interest rate assumptions,18 the

permanent primary surplus needed to sustain the new (and higher) debt/GDP ratio would

have been equivalent to 1.6 points of GDP, 0.7 percentage points of GDP higher than the

observed figure (0.9% of GDP).

         The above analysis only considers valuation effects, but Table 9 also examines

two other factors associated with the Sudden Stop: interest rates and economic growth.

On the one hand, if our hypothesis that the Russian crisis changed investors’ perceptions

about the risk associated with EM bonds is correct, then interest rates are likely to rise.

On the other hand, the fact that GDP growth rates fell all over Latin America may have

increased expectations of much lower growth than originally expected.

17
    Even more thorough measures that split national accounts data at two or more digit levels may yield
different results, but that information was not available for all countries in our sample, so we rely on
calculations at a one digit level only.
18
   The growth rate used for this exercise is the geometric average of the previous 10 years. Interest rates
are average rates on public debt prevailing in 1998. Both measures do not account for the fact that
following a sudden stop in capital flows interest rates typically increase and growth prospects decline.

                                                      26
Table 9

                                    Fiscal Sustainability in Argentina Under Alternative Scenarios in 1998
                                                   Debt to GDP i . Adjustment in        NPV of i .      i . (% of Gov. Debt
                                                     Ratio (%)      Prim. Surplus /a (% of GDP) Expenditures) Reduction (%)
(a): Baseline /b                                         36.5              0.3              9.3               1.5      25.6

(b): Change in Relative Prices to close current      49.7             0.7             22.6              3.6             45.4
account deficit (RER depreciation of 46.2%)

(c): (b) + 200 BPS Increase in Real Interest         49.7             1.7             32.8              8.3             66.0
    Rate

(d): (c) + 1% Reduction in Real GDP Growth           49.7             2.2             35.6             10.8             71.7

(e): (d) + Contingent Liabilities                    58.6             2.7             44.5             13.5             75.9

Source: Own estimates.
a/ The observed primary surplus for 1998 was 0.9 percent of GDP. b/ The baseline scenario assumes a long run rate of growth
of 3,8% and a 7,1% real interest rate.

             Re-computing our estimates under the assumption that interest rates remain 200

basis points higher than in 1998 (an increase similar to the observed increase in EMBI

spreads in 2001 compared to pre-Russian crisis levels) and growth estimates fall by one

percent, the primary surplus needed to achieve fiscal sustainability following a Sudden

Stop, goes all the way to 3.1 percent of GDP, or about 2.2 percent of GDP above the

observed value for 1998 (see Table 9). The needed adjustment is equivalent to 13.5

percent of total expenditures, a large figure from a political perspective. Alternatively,

the size of debt reduction required for sustainability in the absence of a fiscal adjustment,

exceeds 75 percent once we factor in all the different elements of a Sudden Stop that

affect the fisc. From a credit risk perspective, this is also a large figure that helps us

understand why under imperfect credibility on future primary surpluses, the ability to roll

over the existing stock of debt was severely hampered after the Sudden Stop. It is worth

Thus, sustainability calculations are less demanding than those that would prevail had these additional
effects been incorporated. We account for this later on.

                                                                 27
noticing that under the 1998 baseline scenario 19 it is not evident that Argentina’s fiscal

position was out of control. Indeed, standard sustainability analysis indicates that the

difference between the required and observed primary surplus was 0.3 percentage points

of GDP at prevailing RER, growth and real interest rate levels (see Table 9).

Undoubtedly, Argentina was quite vulnerable to RER swings, but it was not clear before

the Russian crisis that Argentina’s fiscal position was out of hand in the absence of a

Sudden Stop.20 This warns about the need to obtain risk-weighted measures of fiscal

sustainability that account for the occurrence of events such as a Sudden Stop. This type

of tool could prove beneficial to internalize the need for more conservative fiscal policy.

        This experience highlights two relevant aspects pertaining debt: both debt levels

and indexation clauses are crucial in determining the effects of Sudden Stops on

sustainability. High debt levels imply little room for cushioning valuation effects.

Higher debt service, in turn, may imply higher RER swings. And dollarization (or

indexation to the dollar) can trigger substantial valuation effects that may compromise

solvency.

        It is useful to contrast the Chilean and Argentine experiences in terms of

sustainability. Chile was subject to a Sudden Stop that forced the country to bring the

current account to almost a zero balance, an adjustment equivalent to 18.8 percent of

imports. Yet, it fared much better in terms of fiscal sustainability. Chile differed from

Argentina in two respects. First, as we already argued in the previous section, Chile

required a smaller RER realignment given the country’s openness and low indebtedness

position. Second, recalling our exercise on the valuation effects of a rise of 50 percent in

19
  That is when we take the prevailing average interest rate, growth rate and RER instead of imputed post-
shock levels.

                                                    28
the RER (close to Chile’s effective depreciation of 45 percent) described in Table 7, it is

clear that Chile’s debt/GDP ratio remained almost unchanged. Chile’s relatively high

share of tradables in GDP, and relatively low ratio of debt in tradables to total debt,

helped dampen the effect of the rise of the RER on sustainability. Thus, very little

changed in terms of sustainability for Chile after the Sudden Stop. Moreover, the RER

shift was successful in switching production to tradables (an effect that we do not

consider in our model), thus compensating in part for the standstill in capital flows.

Table 10 shows the change in exports relative to the change in the current account deficit

observed one year and three years after the Russian crisis, as an indication of the

contribution of exports in closing the current account gap. It clearly shows that Chile was

highly successful in switching production to tradables, something that did not occur in

Argentina, in part because the RER misalignment was providing little incentive to do so.

                                                  Table 10

                           Exports Change / Current Account Change, %
                                    ARG        BRA       CHL    COL                      ECU
                 1999 vs 1998      -127.5      -47.6      11.1   8.7                      8.0
                 2001 vs 1998        -1.8       82.7      79.1   43.8                    41.8
                                          Exports Change, %
                                    ARG        BRA       CHL    COL                      ECU
                 1999 vs 1998       -10.6       -6.5      2.4    3.5                      5.0
                 2001 vs 1998        -0.5       14.3      13.4   10.2                    11.3

             Source: World Economic Outlook (IMF), April 2002.

           Another interesting case to contrast with Argentina is that of Brazil. Why was the

rise in the RER in Brazil successful? Three factors contribute to its explanation. First,

by 1999, the country’s adjustment of the current account was equivalent to only 10.6

percent of imports, far below the 44.2 percent that would have occurred had the current

20
     This assertion is made without considering the possibility that the RER was appreciated by 1998.

                                                      29
account deficit been completely eliminated. So what made Brazil avoid a bigger

adjustment? Contrary to the experience of other countries, the Sudden Stop in Brazil was

short-lived and quickly compensated by FDI flows, which increased 80 percent in dollar

terms between the second quarter of 1998 and the second quarter of 2001. According to

our view, this prevented an even larger currency meltdown. 21 Second, Brazil’s level of

indebtedness was quite high in 1998 (51 percent of GDP) and a sustainability analysis

along the lines presented here would have shown that large fiscal adjustment was also

needed. After the 1999 crisis and in contrast to Argentina, Brazil responded with a

severe fiscal adjustment, which increased its primary balance considerably by 3.5%

points of GDP in 1999. This adjustment proved to be politically feasible and long

lasting, two factors that are crucial in explaining Brazil’s success in weathering the

Sudden Stop, something that was unattainable by Argentina. And third, a crucial

difference with Argentina is that by 1998, although Brazil’s public debt was higher as a

share of GDP than in Argentina, it was only partially dollarized, as Table 6 shows. Since

the level of dollarization was also relatively low in the private sector, contingent

liabilities were kept in check, an issue we will discuss further in the next section.

Therefore, revaluation effects of real currency (i.e., a rise in RER) over the public

debt/GDP ratio were not substantial.

21
   One can only conjecture that to the extent that FDI flows were due to opportunities facing foreign
investors given the low valuation of Brazilian firms after the devaluation of the Real (a one time shot),
Brazil should be ready for additional fiscal adjustment in case FDI flows do not proceed at the previously
observed pace.

                                                     30
5. Real Exchange Rate Adjustment and Contingent Liabilities

       So far we have not discussed another issue that further raises the hurdle for any

type of sustainability analysis following a Sudden Stop, namely, the existence of

contingent liabilities of the public sector, originated in the corporate and banking sectors.

Here the financial system becomes an element of extraordinary importance. It is not

uncommon, as was the case of Argentina recently (and cases like Thailand, for example,

in previous crises), to find that commercial bank loans are heavily dollarized, whereas a

large proportion of bank debtors obtain income from non-tradable activities. This

currency mismatch between debtors’ revenues and liabilities can easily lead to financial

distress following large swings in the RER, as balance sheets deteriorate dramatically

with the increased value of loans, which usually render these sectors bankrupt. To the

extent that expectations concur that the public sector is willing to bail out banks and/or

the corporate sector in the event of a crisis (another common feature of recent crises),

then this bailout ought to be added to the sustainability analysis of the fisc. The

combination of big RER swings, highly dollarized public debt, and the materialization of

contingent liabilities of this sort can send debt/GDP ratios to skyrocketing levels,

rendering public sector accounts bankrupt. Argentina suffered from all of these. Rough

estimates of the bank bailout yield anywhere between US$7bn and US$13bn, and this

excludes previous rediscounts and repos placed with public banks to finance their deposit

losses equivalent to about US$6bn. Putting it all together yields an additional burden of

US$13-19bn, which raises the debt/GDP ratio after the shock to anywhere between 55.8

and 58.6 percent, almost two thirds higher than the pre-crisis 1998 measure!

                                             31
Obviously, public debt surges of this magnitude are the prelude to a wealth

redistribution conflict given the size of the required adjustment. Once all elements

triggered by the Sudden Stop are factored in, 22 the primary balance needed to regain

sustainability would have exceeded 3% of GDP, a figure never attained by Argentina in

its recent history (see Table 9). In order to achieve this, the government would have

needed to come up with new sources of financing or a cut in expenditures. It is evident

from our previous discussion that the corporate sector could not be considered a good

candidate for taxation, given that it was facing the same balance sheet breakdown and

credit crunch confronted by the government. Thus, abstracting from default, the

government was left with basically two alternatives: taxing consumers or reducing

expenditures via wage cuts. Both instruments were to some extent used by different

ministers during the de la Rua administration, but they proved to be politically very tricky

because both were mostly placing the burden over the shoulders of the middle class, de la

Rua’s main political constituency. Besides, these loosing groups in the wealth

redistribution game eagerly challenged the implicit decision of the government to leave

external creditors unscathed. The redistribution conflict gave rise to a war of attrition in

which decisions were delayed, deepening the extent of the crisis and the credibility of the

public sector in terms of its ability to generate fiscal surpluses of the magnitude needed to

regain sustainability. This, of course, closed any remaining open doors to government

financing from abroad, thus making it clearer that the solution to this conundrum would

most likely involve debt restructuring, something that lay at the heart of the bank run

experienced in 2001. Most bank assets comprised loans to the private sector (most of

22
   That is, valuation effects, interest rate increases, growth slowdown and the emergence of contingent
liabilities.

                                                     32
them exhibiting currency mismatch) as well as government bonds. Both stocks would be

severely hit at the time of the crisis. This realization precipitated a run by depositors in

order to avoid the expected confiscation of their deposits.

                In summary, when judging sustainability by taking into account the

valuation impact of a Sudden Stop and the cost of a bail out of the corporate sector on the

balance sheet of the government, it would become apparent that by late 1999 Argentina

had acquired a large debt problem as summarized in Table 9. To “fix” this problem

would have required very large cuts in government expenditures at a time when the fixed

peg to the dollar left Argentina without a valuable instrument, i.e., inflation, to engineer

large government expenditure reductions which are politically very costly to implement

in an explicit way.

       Once we take into account the standards set by the new equilibrium RER, the de

la Rua administration was facing an uphill battle in order to restore creditworthiness. The

fair question to be asked is whether adjustments of such magnitude would have been

feasible with standard fiscal policy instruments. Under lack of credibility, Argentina was

definitely facing a stock problem, which can hardly be resolved with a tool such as the

public sector deficit, which represents a flow, unless it is expected to be long-lasting.

This was a tall order given the weak political structure underlying de la Rua’s

administration. Indeed, at this stage it would have been extremely difficult for any

government to search for a solution that did not involve some form of debt restructuring.

       Before concluding this section, let us revisit the issue of the expected duration of

the Sudden Stop and expectations about Argentina’s lack of fiscal sustainability. As it

has already been argued, all sustainability calculations presented here were made under

                                              33
You can also read