THE EFFECTS OF THE US-CHINA TRADE WAR AND TRUMPONOMICS

Page created by Gordon Lucas
 
CONTINUE READING
THE EFFECTS OF THE US-CHINA TRADE WAR AND TRUMPONOMICS
Forum Scientiae Oeconomia • Volume 7 (2019) • No. 1

The effects of the US-China
trade war and Trumponomics
  Olaniyi Evans
ABSTRACT                                                             DOI: 10.23762/FSO_VOL7_NO1_3
Trumponomics describes the economic policies of U.S.
President Donald Trump and has an “America-first” ap-
proach. The Trump administration risks creating a more
fragmented global economy, and has started the biggest
global trade war to date. The various sides are still on ten-
terhooks and threatening to impose additional tariffs worth
hundreds of billions of dollars. Using deadweight loss (also
known as excess burden or allocative inefficiency) and
Harberger’s triangle, this study shows that the trade war is
devastating not just for the US and China, but for the entire
global economy: (i) the prices of items that directly affect
consumers’ welfare will rise; (ii) firms will face extra costs for
exports; (iii) investors will become more nervous; (iv) some
investors will diversify into Bitcoin and other cryptocurren-
cies; (v) the trade war could turn into a currency war; (vi)
even developed countries could be hit by the trade war; and
(vii) tariffs applied on developing countries’ exports would
rise steeply. In a trade war, everyone may lose.                                       Olaniyi Evans
                                                                                e-mail: oevans@pau.edu.ng
KEY WORDS                                                                       School of Management and
Trumponomics, US-China trade war, consumers, stocks,                 Social Sciences, Pan Atlantic University,
cryptocurrency, Brexit.                                                                       Lagos, Nigeria

Introduction
   A trade war is an economic conflict that jobs from foreign competition (Coughlin et
results from extreme protectionism where al., 2000).
countries raise or create tariffs (or other           In 2017 and 2018, President Donald
trade barriers) against each other in retali- Trump embarked on a protectionist cam-
ation to trade barriers created by the other paign in an attempt to bring manufacturing
party. A consequence of a misapprehen- jobs back to the United States from other
sion of the benefits of free trade, trade wars nations such as China where such jobs
can be instigated if one country perceives have been outsourced (Costinot, 2009;
another country’s trading practices to be Zoellick, 2017). He imposed a new import
unfair (Krugman, 2016; Zoellick, 2017). It duty on 818 goods from China totalling $34
can therefore result from a protectionist billion. China retaliated in kind, imposing
stance. Protectionism restricts interna- a 25% duty on the import of U.S. goods,
tional trade, though most often the general also totalling $34 billion.
intent is to protect local businesses and             The advantages and disadvantages
                                                   of such protectionism are the subject of
	 A tariff is a tax imposed on imported goods and
   services.                                       fierce debate which has a long history
Paper received: 27 November 2018 • Paper revised: 12 February 2019 • Paper accepted: 20 February 2019
48                                      Forum Scientiae Oeconomia • Volume 7 (2019) • No. 1

     in political economy and world politics             (2017), Jakupec (2017), Locke (2017) and
     (Findlay, 2017; George, 2017; Irwin, 2017;          Jakupec (2018).
     Alden 2018). Standard economic theory                  Trumponomics takes an “America-first”
     highlights the adverse effects of trade pro-        approach; by doing so, it risks creating a
     tectionism (Draper, 2017; Fong, 2017; Zis-          more polarised global economy. In fact,
     simos, 2017; Weingast, 2018). Critics argue         it has triggered the biggest global trade
     that protectionism can lead to increases in         war by imposing a new import duty on 818
     the price of domestic manufactured goods            goods from China totalling $34 billion. Chi-
     as well as slow economic growth and                 na has retaliated in kind, imposing a 25%
     cultural exchange down. However, propo-             duty on the import of U.S. goods, also to-
     nents argue that the free trade principle           talling $34 billion. The Trump administration
     that trade is mutually beneficial for coun-         has also extended the trade war to Canada
     tries. They also claim that protectionism, in       (which has imposed tariffs on $12.8 billion
     conjunction with well-crafted policies, can         worth of US goods in return), the EU (which
     provide competitive advantages and gen-             has enforced tariffs on $7.2 billion of US
     erate more jobs (Costinot, 2009; Abboushi,          products in return), and Russia (which has
     2010).                                              also enforced 25-40% additional duties on
        However, it is difficult to uncover any          the import of American products). In 2018,
     widely accepted ramifications and effects           President Donald Trump threatened signifi-
     of the US-China trade war from this debate.         cant tariffs on Chinese goods, including as
     Thus it is not clear what the effects and           much as $500 billion on products includ-
     implications of the US-China trade war are          ing steel and soy. He has also threatened
     likely to be. This study fills the gap, identi-     to pull the U.S. out of the World Trade Or-
     fying the effects of the US-China trade war         ganisation (WTO). The Trump administra-
     on consumers, firms, stocks, cryptocur-             tion and the affected countries are still on
     rency, and both developed and developing            tenterhooks and threatening to impose ad-
     countries. The layout of this article is as fol-    ditional tariffs worth hundreds of billions of
     lows: the next section discusses Trumpo-            dollars.
     nomics and the US-China trade war; Sec-                With the imposition of tariffs, the Trump
     tion 2 describes the theory of deadweight           administration hopes to reduce the large
     loss and Harberger’s Triangle in relation           US trade deficit with China as well as to
     to the US-China trade war; and Section 3            impel China to make key adjustments to its
     presents the implications of the US-China           economic policies, including reducing ex-
     trade war. The last section contains the            isting tariffs and limiting the alleged theft of
     conclusion to the paper.                            US intellectual property by Chinese firms.
                                                         The Trump administration seeks to use
     1. Trumponomics and the                             trade negotiations to massage its elector-
     US-China Trade War                                  ate’s concerns over the lost manufactur-
        Trumponomics describes the economic              ing industries of the US rust belt and the
     policies of U.S. President Donald Trump for         perception that China’s trade practices are
     restructuring trade deals, cutting personal        “not fair” and threaten the US in high-tech
     and corporate taxes, and introducing large          sectors. While much focus has been on
     fiscal stimulus measures focused on infra-          tariffs on steel and other heavy industrial
     structure and defence. For further details
                                                         	   The WTO is the only global impartial organisa-
     of the appurtenances and technicalities of
                                                              tion which regulates trade among the 164 coun-
     Trumponomics, see Ruccio (2017), Ghosh                   tries that belong to it.
The effects of the US-China trade war and Trumponomics                                         49

goods, the US tariffs also target a range of Perelman, 2011; Sřrensen, 2011; Harberger
high-tech industries, particularly where the and Just, 2012; Wang and Chen, 2012). In
Chinese are likely to become leaders in the the case of tariffs, the amount of the tariff
next decade. This has further led credence drives a wedge between what consum-
to the argument that, in recent times, the ers pay and what producers receive, and
rise of China and other vibrant emerging the size of the wedge is equivalent to the
economies has posed huge competition deadweight loss from the tariff (Figure 1).
for the US and other developed econo- The area denoted by the triangle arises
mies, with uneven patterns of winners and from the fact that the intersection of the
losers within them (Rugman and Li, 2007; demand and supply curves is cut short
Hsiang, 2016; Lee and Schwartz, 2016; so that the producer and consumer sur-
Rugman, 2016).                                 pluses are also cut short. The loss of such
                                               un-recouped surplus is the deadweight
2. Theoretical framework                       loss. Economists such as James Tobin
2.1. Deadweight loss and Harberg- have argued that triangles do not have a
er’s Triangle                                  significant effect on the economy, but oth-
    Deadweight loss (also known as excess ers such as Martin Feldstein have argued
burden or allocative inefficiency) is the that, on the contrary, they can significantly
loss of economic efficiency that occurs affect long-term economic trends by spin-
when equilibrium for a good/service is not ning the trend downwards and magnifying
achieved (such that optimal or allocative losses in the long run (Tobin, 1977; Feld-
efficiency is not achieved). It is the loss stein, 1999; Fletcher, 2011; Spulber, 2015;
of welfare, social surplus or utility for con- Blinder, 2016; Rösl and Tödter, 2017).
sumers/producers due to reasons such
as tariffs, subsidies, taxes, price ceilings/ 2.2. Application to the US-China
floors, externalities and monopoly pric- trade war
ing (Coughlin, 2010; Dixon and Rimmer,           The Harberger’s triangle or tariff wedge
2010; Irwin, 2010; Porcher, 2014). For tar- is the deviation from the equilibrium price/
iffs, deadweight loss is the excess burden quantity as a result of tariff imposition. Put
created due to a loss of benefit to partici- differently, the Harberger’s triangle or tar-
pants in trade, which can be consumers, iff wedge is the difference between what
producers or the government. If a tariff is consumers pay and what producers re-
imposed on a firm for each unit of the good ceive (net of tariff) from a transaction. The
it imports, the new equilibrium price will be first round of tariffs on $34 billion worth of
higher (Chen and Ma, 2012). Therefore, Chinese imports means that the price for
some of the burden is passed on to the the American buyers is greater than the
consumer, and this leads to a reduction in price for the Chinese sellers. With such
trade on both sides. The loss in welfare is tariffs, consumers pay more than they did
attributable to a shift to less efficient mar- before, and suppliers receive less for the
ket outcomes which lead to wastage or the good than they did before. Represented by
underutilisation of resources.                 the shaded Harberger triangle in Figure 1,
    Harberger’s triangle, attributed to Arnold the deadweight loss created by the tariff
Harberger, can be used to study the dead- is equal to
weight loss (as measured on a demand                                                    (1)
and supply curve) created by government
intervention in a market (Magee, 2011;
50                                      Forum Scientiae Oeconomia • Volume 7 (2019) • No. 1

                            Figure 1. Harberger’s Triangle for the US-China Trade War

                                            Source: Own elaboration.

        For example, when America imposes a               tariffs will have wider effects on consum-
     new import duty on China, the tariff drives          ers, sellers and the global economy.
     a ‘wedge’ between the price American con-
     sumers pay and the price Chinese sellers             3.1. Consumers
     receive. The difference between the price               Firms are likely to pass on the additional
     that consumers pay and the price that sell-          costs of imposed tariffs to consumers by
     ers receive is equivalent to the size of the         raising prices. The prices of items that
     per-unit tariff. In line with the law of supply      directly affect consumers’ welfare, such
     and demand, as the price paid by consum-             as food, prescription drugs and foreign
     ers increases, and the price received by             holidays, will therefore rise. Unlike stocks,
     sellers decreases, the quantity that each            prices would rise over a period of months
     wishes to trade will decrease.                       rather than immediately, demonstrating the
        After the tariff is imposed, a new equi-          time it may take before consumers begin to
     librium is reached where consumers pay               feel the effects of the trade war. However, in
     more and the quantity traded falls. With             spite of expectations, these tariffs may not
     such tariffs, the equilibrium price is P*,           bring manufacturing jobs back. Any jobs
     where the difference between the buyer’s             created in industries protected by tariffs
     (Pc) and seller’s prices (Ps) equals the val-        would be offset by those lost in industries
     ue of the tariff (Figure 1). The total of the        that make use of these products and which
     shaded triangular region is the Harberger’s          would face rising costs, and due to export
     triangle which represents the magnitude of           sectors being hit by retaliatory tariffs.
     the loss of welfare. While the top shaded
     triangle represents the loss of welfare to
                                                          3.2. Businesses
                                                             It should be noted that the longer the
     consumers (the demand side), the lower
                                                          trade war continues, the likelier firms are
     shaded triangle represents the loss of wel-
                                                          to get hurt. American businesses have
     fare to sellers (the supply side).
                                                          reported increased prices as a result of
     3. Implications                                      the tariffs, compelling them to make hard
      In line with the deadweight loss in the             choices such as laying off workers or de-
     Harberger’s triangle, tariffs and counter-           laying expansion plans. Many companies
The effects of the US-China trade war and Trumponomics                                           51

will shift production overseas to circum-        base noticeably more nervous, which may
navigate the tariffs because they may not        worsen as the trade war continues.
want to absorb extra costs for exports
(e.g. Harley-Davidson). Cases like Harley-       3.4. Cryptocurrency
Davidson have shown that Trumponomics             Recent history has shown that crypto-
does indeed have weaknesses. It may be         currencies blossom when countries battle
difficult for the US to resolve trade deficits uncertain economic times. For example,
bilaterally, especially with China. A lot of   Chinese switched to cryptocurrencies
US companies have moved their produc-          when their national currency, the yuan,
tion to China; they operate within complex     was devalued. Similarly, in 2016, Bitcoin
international networks and protection will     experienced a significant increase during
not bring them back to the US. The trade       Brexit. As the US takes on more countries
war could still extend into areas that have    on a trade war, the value of national curren-
not been considered. For example, it could     cies will likely decline, including US dollars,
extend into bureaucratic hurdles for com-      and investors will look for alternate ways to
panies operating abroad, and interference      store their wealth. Traditionally, investors
in the licensing process.                      have stored their wealth in precious met-
   Similarly, a growing number of Chinese      als such as gold and silver, but their ac-
companies are adopting crafty ways to          quisition and storage are complicated and
evade higher tariffs on their exports to the   expensive. Cryptocurrencies offer the best
US. They remove the “Made in China” label      alternative.
by shifting production to countries such as       Cryptocurrencies are digital currencies
Mexico, Serbia and Vietnam. For example,       in which encryption techniques are used to
Hl Corp, a Shenzhen-listed bike parts mak-     control the units of currency and verify the
er, has moved production to Vietnam.           transfer of funds, functioning independ-
                                               ently of a central bank. Cryptocurrencies
3.3. Stocks and Investors                      such as bitcoin provide an outlet for wealth
  Investors generally loathe any sign of that is beyond restriction and confiscation.
protectionism in global markets. For exam- Though cryptocurrencies are volatile, some
ple, U.S. stocks declined, with the Dow fall- investors with appetite for risk may diver-
ing more than 200 points immediately, after sify into Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies.
the Trump administration imposed duties As the trade war hits more countries with
on Chinese goods. Fears of a global trade economic instability, cryptocurrencies are
war dragged equity prices down, with all set to increase.
of Wall Street’s major indexes recording
declines. The Dow Jones Industrial Aver- 3.5. Currency war
age fell by 84.83 points to 25,090.48, while     The trade war could turn into a cur-
the broader S&P 500 Index fell by 0.1% to rency war, as theoretically and practically,
2,779.42, with the bulk of its primary sectors cheaper currency may be a potential way
booking losses. Industries tied to primary to offset import tariffs (Biswas and Sen-
goods led the decline. The VIX fear index gupta, 2015; Chow, 2017; Vashneya and
went below 12 on a scale of 1-100, where Gupta, 2017). For example, the yuan has
20 is the historic average. Within this time, weakened lately against the dollar. The de-
stocks on all the major US indexes have valuation of the yuan could be the first sign
been adversely affected. Indeed, the trade that the ongoing trade war may descend
war is making a large part of the investor into a currency war. However, it is an open
52                                    Forum Scientiae Oeconomia • Volume 7 (2019) • No. 1

     question whether it is a conscious policy       and development around the globe. More-
     move (China has a semi-managed cur-             over, developing countries are likely to face
     rency). Since devaluation makes exports         higher tariff barriers which may be unfa-
     cheaper and more competitive against for-       vourable to export-oriented growth. Some
     eign manufacturers, allowing the national       of the growth miracles, including Japan
     currency to weaken will soften the blow         and South Korea, were driven by increased
     of tariffs on the economy, ceteris paribus.     exports to developed countries.
     Conversely, it will make foreign products
     more expensive, reinforcing the effects of      Conclusions
     the tariffs.                                       Using deadweight loss (also known as
                                                     excess burden or allocative inefficiency)
     3.6. Developed countries                        and Harberger’s triangle, this study has
        Even developed economies could be            shown that the US-China Trade war could
     particularly affected in such a case. For ex-   have boomerang effects and various im-
     ample, Britain is a relatively open economy,    plications. Firms are likely to pass on the
     advocating for an open global trade or-         additional costs of imposed tariffs to con-
     der (Ojo, 2016; Oliver and Williams, 2016).     sumers by raising the price of items that
     A weakened rules-based world trade              directly affect consumers’ welfare such as
     system would be damaging for Britain. A         food, prescription drugs and foreign holi-
     change to a more protectionist world order      days. However, contrary to some expec-
     would be challenging for the UK, inde-          tations, the imposed tariffs may not bring
     pendent of the EU (Pabst, 2016). Currently      manufacturing jobs back.
     Britain is party to preferential trading ar-       Many companies will move their pro-
     rangements with the EU and 50 other part-       duction overseas to circumnavigate tariffs
     ners. The UK is more specialised in terms       because they may not want to absorb ex-
     of services, but trade negotiations have        tra costs for exports. The trade war could
     become increasingly complicated, partic-        even extend into bureaucratic hurdles for
     ularly when it comes to services, focusing      companies operating abroad, and inter-
     on harmonising standards and regulations        fere with licensing. The trade war could
     rather than merely reducing tariffs. It may     make investors more nervous, which may
     be difficult for a medium-sized country like    worsen as the trade war continues, and
     the UK to negotiate favourable trade deals      could turn into a currency war, reinforcing
     in a fragmented world trade order beyond        the effects of the tariffs.
     the EU and with other countries.                   Developed economies could be partic-
                                                     ularly affected by the trade war (e.g., the
     3.7. Developing countries                       UK). It may be difficult for a country like the
        According to an old African proverb,
                                                     UK to negotiate favourable trade deals in
     “When elephants fight, it is the grass that
                                                     a fragmented world trade order. Develop-
      suffers.” The same is true for the US-Chi-
                                                     ing countries will also be hard hit as tariffs
      na trade war: developing countries will
                                                     applied to their exports would rise steeply,
      be among the hardest hit as, on average,
                                                     thus undermining growth and develop-
      tariffs applied to their exports would rise
                                                     ment around the globe. Moreover, they are
      steeply. A trade war would be a severe
                                                     likely to face higher tariff barriers which
      blow to the world’s poorest countries, as it
                                                     may spell doom for their export-oriented
      would compromise the fragile global eco-
                                                     growth.
      nomic recovery, thus undermining growth
The effects of the US-China trade war and Trumponomics                                             53

   However, it must be noted that restric-        consumers, firms, stocks, cryptocurrency,
tions on global trade might be an opportu-        in both developed and developing coun-
nity for developing countries to fall back on     tries, in various settings and using different
domestic sectors and develop high-tech            methodologies. Such detailed empirical
industries. This may provide protection for       investigation would be highly interesting
domestic entrepreneurs and investors and          and promising.
thus the impetus to expand production,
learning by doing, giving domestic firms
                                                  References
the chance to grow and become globally            Abboushi, S. (2010), Trade protectionism:
competitive. As firms grow, they may invest         Reasons and outcomes, Competitive-
in physical and human capital and develop           ness Review: An International Business
new capabilities and skills. Once these ca-         Journal, 20(5): 384-394. DOI: 10.1108/10
pabilities are developed, domestic firms            595421011080760.
can compete globally.                             Alden, E. (2018), Trump: Reckless free
   The current waves of tariffs and coun-           trader or genuine protectionist?, Inter-
ter-tariffs by US, China and major trading          economics, 53(4): 239-240.
countries represent a reversal of efforts         Biswas, A.K., Sengupta, S. (2015), Cor-
                                                    rupt importers, domestic producers &
(multilateral cooperation, and eight rounds
                                                    welfare: Role of trade policy, Economics
of global trade negotiations, first under the
                                                    & Politics, 27(3): 459-487. DOI: 10.1111/
GATT and then under the World Trade Or-             ecpo.12065.
ganisation) since the end of World War II to      Blinder, A.S. (2016), Financial entropy and
remove trade barriers and promote unin-             the optimality of over-regulation. In: D.D.
terrupted global commerce. In the current           Evanoff, A.G. Haldane, G.G. Kaufman
trade war, everyone is likely to lose. Com-         (Eds.), The new international financial
panies will lose profits; workers will lose         system: Analyzing the cumulative impact
jobs. Governments will lose revenue; con-           of regulatory reform (pp. 3-35), Singa-
sumers will have fewer products to choose           pore: World Scientific.
from. Households, firms, and governments          Chen, B., Ma, H. (2012), Trade restrictive-
                                                    ness and deadweight loss in China’s im-
would incur higher costs. A global trade
                                                    ports. Frontiers of Economics in China,
war would threaten the multilateral trading
                                                    7(3): 478-494. DOI: 10.3868/s060-001-
system itself.                                      012-0021-3.
   However, the effects of the trade war are      Chow, D.C.K. (2017), Can the United States
likely to hit some industries and regions           impose trade sanctions on china for cur-
harder than others. It would cause disrup-          rency manipulation? Washington Univer-
tion in global supply chains which are likely       sity Global Studies Law Review, 16(2):
to cause the largest drag on global growth          295-328.
from the strain over trade (Hughes, 2005;         Costinot, A. (2009), Jobs, jobs, jobs:
Korniyenko, Pinat and Dew, 2017; Man-               A “new” perspective on protectionism.
ners-Bell, 2017). Summarily, a trade war is         Journal of the European Economic As-
                                                    sociation, 7(5): 1011-1041. https://doi.
debilitating not just for the US and China,
                                                    org/10.1162/JEEA.2009.7.5.1011.
but for the entire global economy.
                                                  Coughlin, C.C. (2010), Measuring inter-
   This study has its limitations. A major lim-     national trade policy: a primer on trade
itation of this study pertains to the lack of       restrictiveness indices. Federal Reserve
empirical evidence; further research could          Bank of St. Louis Review, 92(5): 381-394.
therefore focus on empirical verification of      Coughlin, C.C., Chrystal, K.A., Wood, G.
the effects of the US-China trade war on            E. (2000), Protectionist trade policies:
54                                    Forum Scientiae Oeconomia • Volume 7 (2019) • No. 1

       A survey of theory, evidence, and ration-        iffs, American Economic Journal: Eco-
       ale, in: J.A.Frieden (Ed.), International        nomic Policy, 2(3): 111-33. DOI: 10.1257/
       political economy: perspectives on               pol.2.3.111.
       global power and wealth (pp. 308-317),        Irwin, D.A. (2017), Peddling protectionism:
       London: Routledge.                               Smoot-Hawley and the great depression,
     Dixon, P.B., Rimmer, M.T. (2010), Optimal          Princeton: Princeton University Press.
       tariffs: should Australia cut automotive      Jakupec, V. (2017), Trumponomics: From
       tariffs unilaterally?, Economic Record,          foreign trade to foreign aid, Leibniz On-
       86(273): 143-161. https://doi.org/10.1111/       line, 25: 1-12.
       j.1475-4932.2009.00599.x                      Jakupec, V. (2018), Development aid
     Draper, T. (2017), American business and          – populism and the end of the neoliberal
       public policy: The politics of foreign           agenda,. Berlin: Springer.
       trade, London: Routledge.                     Krugman, P. (2016), And the trade war
     Feldstein, M. (1999), Tax avoidance and            came, New York Times, 26 December
       the deadweight loss of the income tax.           2016.
       Review of Economics and Statistics,           Lee, C.E., Schwartz, F. (2016), US com-
       81(4): 674-680. https://doi.org/10.1162/0        petes with China for influence in Cuba,
       03465399558391.                                 The Wall Street Journal, 18 March 2016.
     Findlay, R.M. (2017), Britain under protec-     Locke, R.R. (2017), Trumponomics, firm
       tion: An examination of the government’s         governance and US prosperity, Real-
       protectionist policy, London: Routledge.         world Economics Review, 79: 120-135.
     Fletcher, I. (2011), Why the theory of com-     Korniyenko, M.Y., Pinat, M., Dew, B. (2017),
       parative advantage is wrong, Internation-        Assessing the fragility of global trade:
       al Journal of Pluralism and Economics           The impact of localized supply shocks
       Education, 2(4): 421-429.                        using network analysis, Washington: In-
     Fong, G.R. (2017), Export dependence ver-          ternational Monetary Fund.
       sus the new protectionism: constraints        Magee, C.S. (2011), Why are trade barriers
       on trade policy in the industrial world,         so low?, Economic Affairs, 31(3): 12-17.
       London: Routledge.                            Ojo, M. (2016), Free trade and trade pro-
     George, H. (2017), Protection or free trade:       tectionism: US-China relations and Post
       an examination of the tariff question, with      Brexit impact on UK-China relations, The
       especial regard to the interests of labour,      Institute for Business and Finance Re-
       London: Routledge.                               search, LLC.
     Ghosh, J. (2017), Trumponomics and the          Oliver, T., Williams, M.J. (2016), Special re-
       developing world. New agenda, South              lationships in flux: Brexit and the future
       African Journal of Social and Economic           of the US–EU and US–UK relationships,
       Policy, 2017(67): 42-46.                         International Affairs, 92(3): 547-567. ht-
     Harberger, A.C., Just, R. (2012), A conver-        tps://doi.org/10.1111/1468-2346.12606.
       sation with Arnold Harberger, Annual          Manners-Bell, J. (2017), Supply chain risk
       Review of Resource Economics, 4(1):              management: Understanding emerging
       1-26. https://doi.org/10.1146/annurev-re-        threats to global supply chains, London:
       source-043012-101557.                            Kogan Page Publishers.
     Hsiang, A.C. (2016), Power transition: The      Pabst, A. (2016), Brexit, post-liberalism, and
       US vs. China in Latin America, Journal           the politics of paradox. Telos, 176(2016): 189-
       of China and International Relations. ht-        201. https://doi.org/10.3817/0916176189.
       tps://doi.org/10.5278/ojs.jcir.v4i2.1589.     Perelman, M. (2011), Retrospectives: X-
     Hughes, N. C. (2005), A trade war with Chi-        efficiency, Journal of Economic Per-
       na? Foreign Affairs, 84(4): 94-106.              spectives, 25(4): 211-22. DOI: 10.1257/
     Irwin, D.A. (2010), Trade restrictiveness          jep.25.4.211.
       and deadweight losses from US tar-
The effects of the US-China trade war and Trumponomics                                        55

Porcher, S. (2014), Efficiency and equity in     2017.08.007.
  two-part tariffs: The case of residential Zoellick, R. (2017). If Trump really knows
  water rates, Applied Economics, 46(5):         the art of the deal, he’ll embrace free
  539-555. https://doi.org/10.1080/00036         trade, The Washington Post, 5 January
  846.2013.857001                                2017.
Rösl, G., Tödter, K.H. (2017), The financial
  repression policy of the European cen-
  tral bank: interest income and welfare Olaniyi Evans is a faculty member at Pan
  losses for German savers, IFO DICE Re- Atlantic University, Lagos, Nigeria. His re-
  port, 15(1): 5-8.                           search interests encompass financial inclu-
Ruccio, D.F. (2017), Class and Trumpo- sion, digital economy and dynamic stochas-
  nomics, Real-World Economics Review, tic general equilibrium (DSGE) modelling
  78: 62-85.                                  from an African economic perspective. With
Rugman, A. (2016), Multinational enterpris- snowballing citations, his scholarly publi-
  es from emerging markets, in: Securing cations proliferate in high-impact journals
  the Global Economy (pp. 81-100), Lon- hosted by high-rank publishers such as
  don: Routledge.                             Elsevier, Emerald, Sage, Springer, Taylor &
Rugman, A.M., Li, J. (2007), Will Chi- Francis, and Wiley. Some of his bestselling
  na’s multinationals succeed globally books are How to Get a First-class Degree,
  or regionally?, European Management The Firstclass You, Art of Research, iMathe-
  Journal, 25(5): 333-343. https://doi.org/ matics and iStatistics. Additionally, he is the
  10.1016/j.emj.2007.07.005.                  founding editor of Business and Economic
Sřrensen, P.B. (2011), Measuring the dead- Quarterly.
  weight loss from taxation in a small open
  economy. A general method with an ap-
  plication to Sweden (No. 2011-03), EPRU
  Working Paper Series.
Spulber, D.F. (2015), Public prizes versus
  market prices: Should contents replace
  patents, Journal of the Patent and Trade-
  mark Office Society, 97(4): 690-735.
Tobin, J. (1977), How dead is Keynes?,
  Economic Inquiry, 15(4): 459–68.
Vashneya, U., Gupta, S. (2017), Economic
  reforms concept and strategy, Journal
  of Management Science, Operations
  & Strategies,1(1): 1-4.
Wang, Q., Chen, X. (2012), China’s electric-
  ity market-oriented reform: from an abso-
  lute to a relative monopoly, Energy Poli-
  cy, 51: 143-148. https://doi.org/10.1016/
  j.enpol.2012.08.039.
Weingast, B.R. (2018). War, trade, and mer-
  cantilism: Reconciling Adam Smith’s three
  theories of the British Empire, Department
  of Political Science, Stanford University.
Zissimos, B. (2017), A theory of trade policy
  under dictatorship and democratization,
  Journal of International Economics, 109:
  85-101. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jinteco.
You can also read