Access rights for outdoor recreation in New Zealand: some lessons for open country in England and Wales - UPSI ...

Page created by Hugh Hammond
 
CONTINUE READING
Journal of Environmental Management (2002) 64, 423–435
doi:10.1006/jema.2001.0525, available online at http://www.idealibrary.com on

Access rights for outdoor recreation in New
Zealand: some lessons for open country in
England and Wales
Nigel Curry
Countryside and Community Research Unit, University of Gloucestershine, Francis Close Hall,
Swindon Road, Cheltenham, GL4 8HR, UK
Received 11 May 2001; accepted 22 October 2001

Access opportunities for outdoor recreation in New Zealand and England and Wales are classified according to their
conformity with collective, citizenship or exclusion rights and their degrees of permanence. Alternative criteria for the
apportionment of access rights are considered in the context of this classification. Different criteria for rights apportionment
are found to be appropriate according to different circumstances in the context of pluralist provision. Policy developments
in New Zealand are compared with those in England. After 150 years of a dominance of collective rights in New Zealand
current policy is shifting provision towards exclusionary rights. In England, there is a policy shift in the other direction,
towards collective rights. Lessons for the development of collective rights in England are drawn from the New Zealand
experience in relation to styles of governance, public preferences, public cost, insurance liability and the potential of
markets.
 2002 Published by Elsevier Science Ltd

Keywords: outdoor recreation, collective rights, citizenship rights, exclusionary rights, New Zealand,
England and Wales.

Land as a bundle of rights                                       main not by the occupier nor by the public per se,
                                                                 but by the state, through the medium of the local
                                                                 planning authority.
In theories of land rights and processes of land                    To a large degree, this structure of rights has its
reform, land is commonly characterised as a bundle               origins in a range of both rights theories (Bromly,
of rights, rather than more simply a producer or                 1991) and proposals for land reform (Adams, 2000).
consumer good. Grove-Hills et al. (1990), in the                 Whilst these are disparate in their perspectives,
context of a Neo-classical economic interpretation               those that have had currency in the West, from
of property rights, offer a number of such rights                the Judeo–Christian tradition, through Marxist
that pertain to land. These are the right to use                 thinking to Neo-classical economics, have tended
land, the right to transfer or transact land, the                to take as their starting point, the productive
right of enforcement of legal arrangements over the              use of the land. Land rights have been inex-
land and the right to exclude people from the land.              tricably linked with the potential of the human
Commonly, these rights run with the land and are                 exploitation of nature. Rights to land, viewed as
held by the owner or occupier. To these, they add a              environmental and cultural capital, have been less
collective right that is held not by the occupier, but           fully considered. In respect of land as environ-
the public at large in respect of a range of interests           mental and cultural capital, conceptualisations of
in the land. Development rights too, in both New                 rights have been more fully grounded in social
Zealand and England and Wales are held in the                    processes, often being characterised as rights of
                                                                 citizenship (Salamon, 1993; Voyce, 1994; Munton,
Email: ncurry@glos.ac.uk                                         1995).

0301–4797/02/$ – see front matter                                                            2002 Published by Elsevier Science Ltd
424    N. Curry

   In respect of rights of access to land for outdoor    mechanisms. Exclusionary rights can be created
recreation, there has been a traditional tension         through state economic mechanisms or private
between the rights of exclusion on the part of the       markets. All three kinds of access right can be
occupier and collective rights on the part of the pub-   apportioned for different time periods. Within these
lic (Shoard, 1999; Curry, 2001). More recently, how-     characteristics, a taxonomy of access rights for out-
ever, rights of citizenship have been asserted over      door recreation is offered in Table 1. It is beyond
land in the context of access for outdoor recreation     the scope of this paper to discuss each of these
originating, perhaps, in the global development of       individual access rights in any detail. Those for
environmental groups (Samuel, 1994). Acting as a         New Zealand are considered fully in Curry (2001).
self-proclaimed ‘citizenry’ they have laid increas-      For England and Wales, a critique is offered in
ing claim on ‘localities’ (be they local, national or    Shoard (1999) and the development of privileges in
global) as forms of cultural capital in need of pro-     England and Wales, by Curry, (1998).
tection as assets. Active citizens have thus asserted
a societal ‘stakeholder’ claim to certain land rights,
in part displacing the more traditional role of the      The nature of rights apportionment
state (Hutton, 1999) through asserting community
ownership of, and responsibility for, such rights        Collective rights apportionment
(Jones and Little, 2000).
   As Parker (1999) notes, such citizenship claims       The core of the debate over access rights con-
to land rights modify conceptions of both rights         cerns which of those outlined in Table 1 is most
of exclusion and collective rights in respect of         appropriate for the provision of outdoor recreation.
access to land. Citizenship itself is variably con-      In this context, the weight of the literature over
structed in the literature. Liberal constructions        the past 20 years has tended to favour the provi-
tend to be based on individualism and the trad-          sion of collective rights for one or more of three
ing of rights through the market, with inequalities      reasons: welfarism, non-excludability and merit
being corrected by philanthropy and altruism. Such       goods. Whilst some simply extol the virtues of
a conception tends to favour rights of exclusion         leisure provision generally as being at ‘the apex
to land that can then be differentially reappor-         of the pyramid of welfare rights’ (Henry, 1994,
tioned through market mechanisms. Communitar-            page 52, cited in Coalter, 1998), traditional wel-
ian notions of citizenship on the other hand, are        farist views for the collective provision of outdoor
based on community rather than individual activ-         recreation are predicated largely on the observed
ity. These tend to favour a form of collective rights    inequalities in recreation consumption. The bet-
of access to land. But importantly, even these com-      ter off are the dominant consumers and there
munitarian notions contain strong elements that          is a need to redress this inequality by targeting
favour exclusion. A ‘community’ is only a small          policies at the recreation disadvantaged (Coalter,
sub-set of the public and there are many of them.        1998). A range of social policies specifically for
Any rights accorded to a community are thus likely       outdoor recreation was developed in the 1970s
to exclude other communities and thus:                   and 1980s in England and Wales within this
  ‘Citizenship can act as much to exclude people         welfarist framework (considered fully in Curry,
  from certain rights as to include them’ (Parker,       1994).
  1999, page 1207).                                         Collective rights arising from non-excludability
                                                         are based on the notion that in parts of the
                                                         countryside (such as national parks and open
A taxonomy of access rights for                          country) it is physically difficult to exclude peo-
                                                         ple from entering the area. Effectively, exclu-
England and New Zealand                                  sion rights cannot be enforced. This means
                                                         that the apportionment of rights cannot be con-
Access rights in both New Zealand and England            trolled through ‘rationing’ mechanisms (there is
and Wales are pluralistic: provision acknowledges        no point of entry) and so collective rights are
collective, exclusionary and citizenship rights. In      appropriate.
both countries too, outdoor recreation takes place          The merit good argument is more contentious,
outside the rights structure altogether, through         however, since it bases the argument for collective
what Mason (1991) terms ‘privileges’. Collec-            provision on what the state considers is ‘good for
tive rights can be statutorily imposed, volun-           people’ and what they ought to have, rather than
tarily offered, or traded through state economic         necessarily what they want. In New Zealand, the
Access rights in New Zealand and England        425

Table 1.     A taxonomy of access rights for outdoor recreation in New Zealand and England and Wales

New Zealand                                                                       England and Wales

Statutory collective rights in perpetuity
Crown lands                                                      The rights of way system
Parks and reserves                                               Open country
Crown forest licenses                                            Common land
State land purchase                                              State land purchase for recreation
Walkways over public lands                                       Rights of navigation
The queen’s chain: marginal strips; esplanade
  reserves and strips; public roads
Voluntary collective rights in perpetuity
The ‘gifting’ of land                                            Dedications under the CROW Act, 2000
Easements without compensation                                   Planning agreements
Covenants                                                        Public path orders
State economic collective rights for a fixed time period
Walkway leases to the state                                      Leases to the state
Walkway easements with compensation                              Agri-environment agreements
                                                                 Other written agreements
Citizenship rights in perpetuity
Community ownership of backcountry facilities                    Millennium greens
                                                                 Town and village greens
                                                                 Community forests
State economic exclusionary rights for a fixed time period
Licenses and permits from the state                              Licenses and permits from the state
User charges to state facilities                                 User charges to state facilities
Concessions
Leases from the State
Crown pastoral leases (the sale of the right of
  exclusion)
Private market exclusionary rights
Market provision (pay at the gate)                               Market provision (pay at the gate)
De facto access with voluntary payments                          De facto access with voluntary payments
Access through weekly or annual memberships                      Access through weekly or annual memberships
Privileges
De facto Access with the permission of the landholder            De facto access with the permission of the landholder
Access by tradition                                              Access by tradition

merit good argument in particular for outdoor                outdoor recreation were not participating because
recreation, has been championed by the Hillary               they did not have the means. In fact, the vast
Commission (1991). In England and Wales, the                 majority of non- participation in outdoor recre-
relationship between walking in the countryside              ation arises because of a lack of interest, a lack
and ‘the health and happiness of individuals and             of time, or the use of leisure time in other ways
the nation’ (Countryside Commission, 1999, page              than consuming the outdoors (Social and Com-
1) is a central plank in the development of national         munity Planning Research (1999) for England,
policy.                                                      Devlin (1993) for New Zealand). Rather than sim-
  The limits of welfarism in collective provision            ply the lack of material opportunity to partici-
for outdoor recreation, however, also have been              pate.
articulated in the literature. The failure of social           In this context, the subsidization of collective
policies to address inequalities in participation            rights for outdoor recreation for social policy
came about as a result of one overriding reason              reasons has been characterised as both inefficient
in both countries. In state policy, non-participation        and ineffective (Gratton and Taylor, 1985). Such
was assumed to arise entirely as a result of some            subsidies have been overwhelmingly consumed by
form of material deprivation. Non-consumers of               the more affluent who are themselves most able
426    N. Curry

to take responsibility for their own consumption.       self-organisation amongst the wider population,
The Audit Commission for England and Wales              through citizenship action, to do what they wanted
(quoted in Coalter, 1998, page 28) summarized           rather than what was considered good for them.
the situation for leisure provision in general thus:    Interestingly, these two arguments for state provi-
                                                        sion have spawned criticism from both the political
  ‘across the board subsidies have a perverse
  effect from a redistributional perspective. Many      right, who have argued the ineffectiveness of wel-
  poorer people are, through their rates, paying to     fare motivations, and the political left who have
  subsidise the pastimes of the rich’.                  argued the elitism and social control of merit good
                                                        motivations.
Recognition of such unequal benefit distribution
amongst the recipients of outdoor recreation also
has been noted in relation to the consumption of
backcountry recreation in New Zealand (Curry,           Apportionment through state economic
2001).                                                  mechanisms
   The limitations of the non-excludability argu-
ment hinge on being able to define the areas on         A number of critiques of access rights apportion-
which exclusion rights effectively can be exercised     ment discuss the relative merits and deficien-
and those on which they cannot. This relates not        cies of state collective apportionment relative to
only to the ability physically to exclude, but also     exclusionary market apportionment (Clarke, 1992;
to notions of perceptual exclusion. Open country        Clarke et al., 1994). Rather fewer give considera-
in England and Wales (mountain, moor, heathland         tion to apportionment by the state through the use
and downland) and registered common land might          of economic mechanisms. These are of increasing
be considered the most likely land type to exhibit      visibility in both New Zealand (covenants, ease-
non-excludability characteristics and yet statutory     ments, leases) and England and Wales (through
collective rights have only just been conferred on      the use of direct payments, management agree-
these areas through the Countryside and Rights          ments, producer subsidies and so on). Where
of Way Act, 2000 (CROW Act, 2000). There has            these kinds of mechanism are considered, they
been a presumption of at least some ability to          are usually characterised as the commodification
exclude from this land, prior to this time (Shoard,     of rights and therefore conflated and indeed con-
1999).                                                  fused, with market provision (Bishop and Phillips,
   Coalter (1998) suggests that the merit good argu-    1993).
ment has its origins in 19th Century Britain where         This is clearly not the case, since the use
both the local and the national state used collective   of such economic mechanisms describes a rela-
rights for outdoor recreation provision generally       tionship not between producer and consumer (a
as a means of ‘pacifying’ an urban population           market), but between producer and the state.
living in poor environmental conditions. Such pro-      They are means of ‘rationing’ access rights, which
vision was deemed socially desirable, but this was      can equally be achieved through non-economic
more to do with social engineering than social          means such as regulation and non-priced per-
welfare. Even today, the merit good argument is         mits.
seen by some as a means of state control over              In contrast to these kinds of mechanism, the
leisure behaviour through the provision of ‘good’       state also does become involved in markets where
leisure. There remains confusion in state policy        it charges the user for outdoor recreation provi-
in both New Zealand and England and Wales as            sion. Here, the state is acting as the producer
to whether people should participate in outdoor         in the expression of a producer–consumer rela-
recreation (the merit good argument) or should          tionship. Such arrangements have a considerable
have the opportunity to participate (the welfare        and well established history (the use of back-
argument).                                              country huts in New Zealand, charging for car
   In this context, it has been suggested that          parking at country parks in England and Wales)
whilst the provision of collective rights may have      and provide a number of advantages in rights
a genuine concern for improving the lot of the          apportionment, not least controlling the volume of
working population, the welfarist and merit good        visitors in environmentally fragile areas (Curry,
approaches at least, have been predicated on value      1994). Again here, however, there is a confu-
systems of an elite. Specifically in the context        sion in the literature that state provision is ‘free’
of outdoor sport, Houlihan (1991) has suggested         and market provision is solely a private sector
that this has prevented an important role for           function.
Access rights in New Zealand and England     427

Citizenship and the apportionment of                       Postmodernists, too, argue for difference, plural-
access rights                                            ism and the ‘incommensurability of cultures and
                                                         values’ (Turner, 1990, page 12). For some, the
More recent arguments in respect of the apportion-       notion of inclusive social citizenship is a paradox.
ment of rights through citizenship, share reserva-       Holmwood (1997), maintains (quoted in Coalter,
tions about the appropriateness of state collective      2000, page 173):
provision. A central tenet of citizenship is that          ‘any values of common citizenship would involve
there should be no rights without concomitant              the imposition of the values of one group on
responsibilities (Hutton, 1999). Critiques of state        another’.
collective provision of outdoor recreation in this
context, suggest that such provision confers rights      In this context, he recommends exclusionary mar-
with no responsibilities and that perhaps citizen        kets as a framework that allows different values to
responsibility in this area might be to provide as       flourish.
much of his or her own recreation as possible.
   Certainly, citizenship cannot equate to welfarism
since its essence is that it is displacing the
                                                         Exclusionary market rights
state. Objections to welfarism from a citizenship
standpoint also claim that it is concerned to develop
                                                         Much of the welfarist writing on the collective
a ‘civilizing culture’ that always has the potential
                                                         provision of access rights exhibits a concomitant
to sustain a status quo of inequity. Welfarism
                                                         condemnation of exclusionary rights through mar-
considers a responsible citizen to be a participatory
                                                         ket provision. This invariably is triggered by spe-
citizen and non-participation is seen as a threat
                                                         cific policy strands that exhibit a shift from state
to social stability. Modern notions of citizenship
                                                         provision towards ‘privatization’ or ‘commodifica-
uphold the right to choose (Coalter, 1990).
                                                         tion’. Thatcherism in Britain and the laissez faire
   As a result, citizenship does acknowledge a role
for markets in outdoor recreation. Policies for          economy in New Zealand, with their emphasis on
collective rights largely have failed to respond to      markets, were the principal triggers for this and
consumer demands, choosing instead to extol the          spawned an opposition to exclusionary markets
virtues of merit goods. Public resources have been       per se (Coalter, 1998). Commodified leisure creates
wasted as a result because it is always unlikely         false needs and passive consumers. It is exploita-
that all sectors of society will want to use the same    tive and produces inequalities and has become
amount of public provision. In this context, non-        characterised as a political validation of capital-
consumption certainly does not equate to exclusion       ism (Clarke and Critcher, 1995). The freedom of
(Coalter, 1998). Further, the ‘privatization’ of         choice offered to consumers is illusory because
state leisure facilities (for example through the        exclusionary markets create false needs and there-
sale of public facilities in New Zealand and             fore provide a form of social control (Coalter, 2000).
Compulsory Competitive Tendering in England)                This rhetoric is expressed as a range of con-
can ensure demand-led services and acknowledges          trasts between ‘good’ collective state provision and
market responses. This allows consumer rather            ‘bad’ exclusionary market provision. Thus, welfare
than producer led-provision on the assumption that       rights have been displaced by consumer rights and
consumers know best what they want.                      the politics of choice has been replaced by the
   But what of notions of exclusion rights within        politics of means (Ravenscroft, 1993). Commodifi-
citizenship? One of the central planks in the            cation has undermined a welfare role, relegating
development of modern western governance is that         the active public to passive consumers (Aitchison,
welfarist principles of common public support are        1992) and commercial leisure is exclusive whilst
giving way to more communitarian principles of           public recreation is inclusive (Irvine and Taylor,
citizenship. Hall and Held (1989), for example,          1998). Collective leisure, suggests Parker (1997)
suggest that notions of citizenship must take into       is participant-led, active and spontaneous whilst
account the differentiated ways in which people          exclusive market consumption is provider led, pas-
now wish to participate in social life. Citizenship in   sive and packaged.
the context of modern governance is all about local         Specifically in relation to countryside recreation,
communities and the differentiation of citizens          market-based provision deprives people of a more
by their local spatial and social context. In this       naturalistic communion with nature and is there-
light, notions of equality and universality are the      fore shallow. Coalter (2000, page 167) cites Tom-
antithesis of citizenship.                               linson (1991):
428    N. Curry

  ‘there are many alternative paths towards an            rights for outdoor recreation, provision is likely
  enriching and enjoyable leisure than the one on         to remain pluralistic. The critical question is there-
  offer in the consumer culture model’.                   fore, what is an appropriate balance in such rights
But as Coalter (2000) also notes, all of these per-       apportionment within pluralistic provision? Any
spectives are borne largely of critiques of ideologies    answer to this also is likely to remain indetermi-
of exclusionary consumerism (how the world ought          nate (Warde, 1992). Some observations are made,
to be rather than how it is (Craib, 1994)). There is      however, from the case of New Zealand (with an
little work at all on the sociological analysis of acts   experience of area collective access rights dating
of exclusive consumption and the benefits that they       back to the 1840s) in the context of the recent
might bring to the consumer. They are undertaken          English and Welsh experience of a significant shift
without any attempt to explore empirically the dif-       in apportionment towards collective rights in per-
fering effects of market relationships and they all       petuity through the statutory provision of access to
confuse the mode of production with the experience        open country and common land in the Countryside
of consumption. The effectiveness of exclusionary         and Rights of Way (CROW) Act, 2000.
markets in outdoor recreation in providing signifi-          From the time of European settlement in New
cant consumer satisfaction, is ignored.                   Zealand in the mid-19th Century, a large pro-
   Many of the arguments that find a legitimate role      portion of the land surface (around 40%) was
for markets in the apportionment of exclusionary          designated as public or Crown Lands (Department
access rights build upon the notion that the case         of Conservation, 1996). In large part, the motiva-
against markets is not proven. Outdoor recreation         tion for this was founded on egalitarian principles.
is not an essential welfare area of concern since it is   Public Access New Zealand (1992, page 1) notes
not about satisfying primary needs (Abercrombie,          that the incoming population:
1994). In these circumstances, the consumer should          ‘were determined to get away from the class-
be allowed to have a voice. Exclusionary outdoor            based privileges and restrictions in English
recreation provision does not have to be exploitative       society’.
or experienced passively. As Coalter (1998, page 34)
states:                                                   They were to do this by ensuring the widespread
                                                          availability of collective access rights so severely
  ‘to concentrate on the potentially exclusionary         denuded in England through the enclosures. Queen
  nature of markets for some is also to ignore their      Victoria’s Royal Charter of 1840 placed a duty on
  liberatory potential for others’.                       the Governor that such lands be available for public
Indeed, current trends in outdoor recreation have         access and should remain immune from private
been characterized as a clear movement towards            interests in perpetuity (Anderson, 1990). Just as
exclusionary market-based consumption as a mat-           there has been a shift towards collective access
ter of choice (Clarke et al., 1994). Certain groups in    rights in England and Wales, however, there has
society actively seek to use exclusionary rights and      been a significant move away from such rights in
markets to create social or community structures.         New Zealand, towards exclusionary rights. Several
Consumption, rather than having use or exchange           reasons have been articulated for this.
values, adopts a dominant ‘identity value’ (Warde,
1992). As Keat et al. (1994) note, the supposedly
exploitative nature of exclusionary recreation does       The laissez fare economy
not necessarily mean that it cannot provide satis-
fying forms of social membership. And Williamson          The development of the laissez faire economy
(1985) suggests that buying and consuming pro-            in New Zealand from the early 1980s (at the
vide a sense of control that is unavailable through       same time as the development of Thatcherism
collective public provision.                              in England and Wales) has led to a range of
                                                          policies of trade liberalisation and the removal
                                                          of trade barriers in line with the aspirations
Some observations from New                                of the World Trade Organisation (Kelsey, 1999).
Zealand for England in shifts in                          In common with many other OECD counties, a
                                                          widespread sale of state assets also has taken place.
access rights apportionment                               Significant shifts in governmental ethos have led
                                                          to a reconsideration of the potential of markets for
Within the context of an indeterminate view about         the apportionment of many hitherto state provided
the most appropriate apportionment of access              goods and services. This is all, contend McIntyre
Access rights in New Zealand and England     429

et al. (2001), consistent with an international         (Department of Conservation, 1996, page 8) or
push for ‘smaller’ governments within a globalising     Departmental objectives for effective use (pages
economy. It responds to the characteristics of          35–36). In the context of known recreation trends,
the ‘post-industrial’ society, giving recognition to    the Department concludes, it is in possession of a
notions of ‘Third Way’ politics (Giddens, 1998)         considerable over-supply of backcountry facilities
and the empowerment of citizens. The state is           (Department of Conservation, 1994) and during
adopting more of an enabling than an executive          the 1990s many have been removed or allowed to
role shifting the locus of power to smaller more        deteriorate through a more ‘systematic’ approach
local communities.                                      to asset management (Booth and Simmons, 2000).
  McIntyre et al. (2001) suggest that in respect        The collective public resource on Crown lands is
of access for outdoor recreation in New Zealand         therefore being diminished, largely in response to
this is causing notions of collective provision to      the nature and extent of use.
be questioned and the potential of both market             The New Zealand experience has possible impli-
exclusionary provision and citizenship rights for       cations for the nationalisation of the right of exclu-
a differentiated public to be explored more fully.      sion through access to open country and common
To the extent that England and Wales, along             land in England and Wales. No systematic explo-
with most western economies, shares a number            ration has been undertaken of public preference for
of these governance characteristics with New            access to open country. In the lead up to the CROW
Zealand (Curry, 2000) the introduction of statutory     Act, 2000 a Gallup (1998) poll suggested that the
collective rights through access to open country and    public were generally uncertain about what open
common land under the CROW Act, 2000, would             country was, certainly relative to a clearer under-
appear to run contrary to contemporary political        standing of the nature and location of the Rights of
thinking in respect of an enabling rather than an       Way system. Given that aggregate outdoor recre-
interventionist or welfarist government.                ation consumption has remained static in England
                                                        and Wales for the past 20 years (Curry and Raven-
                                                        scroft, 2001) it is unlikely that the new access
Public use and preference                               opportunities afforded by open country will lead
                                                        to considerable increases in overall consumption.
In the context of a more overtly laissez faire          Such use as takes place in open country is more
economy, the agency responsible for statutory           likely to result from shifts in the use of other
collective rights in New Zealand (the Crown lands),     outdoor recreation resources.
the Department of Conservation, is developing
access policy through a more overt consideration of
consumer demands. The primacy of access rights is       Public cost and accountability
being questioned relative to the legitimacy of using
consumer preferences as criteria in the allocation of   The levels of use associated with statutory collec-
access resources. In this context, the vast majority    tive rights also have a bearing on the financial
of outdoor recreation in New Zealand takes place        accountability of the Department of Conservation
close to centres of population (Booth and Peebles,      in New Zealand. The Department has experienced
1995) where the Department of Conservation has          a reduction in funding from government in real
more limited jurisdiction. The Crown lands are in       terms of 20% between 1987 and 1999 (Booth and
the remoter parts of the country and are much less      Simmons, 2000). This has required the Depart-
intensively used.                                       ment to be selective about the way in which such
  Even within the Crown lands the dominant              resources are used. Two rigidities are built into the
recreational use is through linear backcountry          resource requirements of the Department. Firstly,
tracks (Curry, 2001). Much of the other land area       it has a principal responsibility for conservation
is not used, but even the tracks, which have            (considered below) which inevitably means that it
developed through customary use within Crown            is in the area of its secondary responsibilities for
lands, are not clearly delineated. It is in these       outdoor recreation that the main resources savings
more remote access areas too, that the Department       are sought.
of Conservation claims that there is considerable          The second rigidity is that the Department has a
inappropriate provision because of the facilities       continuing expenditure commitment to the main-
inherited from previous agencies for purposes that      tenance of its existing recreation infrastructure
are no longer pertinent (for example, wild animal       (tracks, campsites, huts and so on). It is outside
control). These no longer meet visitor preferences      of these commitments that the principal resource
430    N. Curry

savings are sought. Further, there is a general gov-     in New Zealand through Walkways, an economic
ernment exhortation to focus outdoor recreation          collective right mechanism, have met with limited
provision close to centres of population, where the      success (Department of Conservation, 1995). Any
majority of it takes place (Corbett, 1995). Here,        impoverishment of the Rights of Way system at the
the opportunity cost of state expenditure in less        expense of open country, therefore, is likely to be
used areas becomes important. Consequently, it is        an ineffective use of resources.
more remote recreation (collective rights on Crown
lands) that falls outside of these commitments or
rigidities, that has become the primary consid-          Safety and insurance liability
eration for resource savings (Booth and Peebles,
1995).                                                   The collective access rights on Crown lands are
  Such resource issues will be important in Eng-         bearing the brunt of resource rationalisation on
land and Wales in respect of open country. Public        the part of the Department of Conservation, but
expenditure will be more visible than in New             significant issues of health and safety have exac-
Zealand because in the latter country, the access        erbated this. The Department is responsible for
lands are managed primarily for conservation pur-        the welfare of users of its facilities and compensa-
poses and recreation expenditure can be absorbed,        tion can be claimed against it for negligence. This
or hidden, within a conservation budget. Visitor         was brought into sharp focus by an incident on 28
management is only a small marginal cost within          April 1995 when 13 Tai Poutini Polytechnic stu-
a much larger conservation budget anyway. Open           dents and a Department of Conservation manager
country budgets in England and Wales will not be         lost their lives when a viewing platform collapsed
able to be absorbed in a similar way.                    at Cave Creek on the West Coast, due to its poor
  Apart from initial start-up costs (for mapping         construction (Department of Conservation, 1996).
and definition), the resourcing of open country in          There have been two principal consequences
England and Wales is to come from local authority        of this in relation to the reduction of collective
budgets. By the beginning of 2001 no net additional      rights. Firstly, in 1996 the Department undertook
funding had been specifically identified by govern-      a detailed engineering survey of the facilities and
ment, on a recurring basis, for local authorities        structures for which it was responsible. Some
in respect of on going open country management.          were found to be dangerous and in need of repair
The Countryside Agency, however, is committed to         leading to their closure, either on a temporary
identifying such additional costs and assessing the      or permanent basis. Even temporary closures
feasibility of gaining new types of funding support.     would be reopened only as and when resources
The Department of the Environment, Transport             became available. The Department of Conservation
and the Regions too, is to make sure that resources      (1996, page 17) was able to claim that ‘many’
are made available to local authorities (Country-        of its facilities were reaching the end of their
side Agency, 2001). It has been estimated that such      working life.
net additional costs of access to open country may          Secondly, priority for expenditure has been
well be in the region of £6–£6Ð5 million a year          given to health and safety, not only in respect
at 1997 prices. Concerns have been expressed by          of safe and robust structures, but also through
local authorities themselves (Curry and Hickey,          the provision of more user information (termed
1998) that if this magnitude of funding is required      ‘recreation orientation’). This is a further consumer
with insufficient dedicated resources, it is likely to   of Departmental resources. In addition, funding
threaten the resource base currently being used for      allocations are prioritised in accordance with the
the Rights of Way system.                                deemed quality of the site or area. Those perceived
  The Rights of Way system is highly regarded            of highest quality are dealt with first, which
in New Zealand as an effective means of securing         means that ‘unremarkable’ backcountry collective
collective access rights because of its linearity and    resources are the most vulnerable to closure for
the fact that linear routes are much easier to define    the longest periods of time if not permanently
and understand for the public at large. The Rights       (Department of Conservation, 2000). All of these
of Way system, too, covers the whole country (to         priorities for maintenance and repair themselves
varying degrees) rather than only remote portions.       take precedence over new programmes. Even at
As a result, many policymakers in New Zealand            Department’s (Department of Conservation, 2000)
consider it superior to the existing regime of Crown     own admission, there is a constant management
lands in New Zealand (Curry, 2001). Certainly,           shortfall on public lands and this ‘rundown or
attempts to develop a comprehensive linear system        removal of some visitor services in the 1990s has
Access rights in New Zealand and England    431

been criticised by a wide range of New Zealanders’        of the access resource would lead to the abandon-
(Department of Conservation, 1996, page 7).               ment of collective backcountry rights altogether.
   The New Zealand collective access resource             This was a prevailing view, for example, in con-
appears therefore to be bearing the brunt of              sultations over the Department of Conservation’s
real reductions in Department of Conservation             (1996, page 21) Visitor Strategy.
expenditure for a variety of reasons. An hierarchy           On the positive side, these moves towards mar-
in relation to the development of their facilities        ket principles respond more squarely to consumer
in these areas is apparent. Popular facilities have       demands (a current aspiration of the Countryside
become exclusionary and command sophisticated             Agency in England (Countryside Agency, 2000a).
differential pricing, marginal facilities are ‘offered’   Both the Department of Conservation and a num-
to user groups (as citizenship rights) free of            ber of New Zealand pressure groups acknowledge
charge to see if the value of them equates to a           that the public does not differentiate between
perceived cost of maintenance. Collective facilities      unpriced state-provided resources and priced mar-
with little perceived use potential, or perceive          ket ones to any significant degree. Indeed a number
inappropriateness are closed and abandoned (a loss        of authors have noted in the New Zealand context
of rights altogether).                                    that market provision often is preferred for the cer-
   Certainly, the introduction of open country in         tainty of access relative to people being somewhat
England and Wales will not have a base of facilities      unsure of their rights on public land (Shultis, 1991;
to the extent that they have developed in New             Reiling et al., 1988).
Zealand. Further, the CROW Act 2000 removes                  Whatever the advantages and disadvantages
occupier liability in respect of all users of access in   of this approach, the development of pricing
relation to incidents occurring as a result of any        mechanisms for state economic exclusionary rights
‘natural feature of the land’. The user has a ‘duty of    has been sophisticated both for concessions and
care’ for his/her own welfare (Countryside Agency,        for user charges. The latter currently are being
2001). Whilst this would appear to minimise health        considered for entry into national parks (Booth and
and safety liabilities in England and Wales for both      Simmons, 2000), undermining the inevitability,
the landowner and the state it will be important to       perhaps, of the non-excludability presumption in
monitor any costs of personal injury as the result        respect of such areas.
of access to open country (in respect of health              These developments in New Zealand appear to
services, mountain rescue and so on) as part of           shift the burden of the management of public
an assessment of its overall effectiveness.               lands onto partnerships, the private sector and
                                                          individuals. In the longer term, the extent to which
                                                          open country will be managed fully by the state in
The move towards markets                                  England and Wales, will depend on its (particularly
                                                          recurring) cost. The experience in New Zealand
All of these factors have led to a clear diminution       might suggest that such a cost is not sustainable
in the collective access resource in New Zealand.         in perpetuity.
In the context of a laissez faire economy, there also
has been a concomitant move towards both state
economic exclusionary rights for a fixed time period      Agency structure and conservation
and private market exclusionary rights (Memon,            priorities
1993). Whilst the latter of these requires only the
exhortation of the state, the former requires it to       New Zealand’s statutory collective access rights
be active in the market itself, acting as a market        are managed by the Department of Conservation
agent whilst still holding social development and         where:
environmental custodianship roles (Perkins, 1993).
  Whilst the New Zealand Department of Conser-              ‘human values are fairly low down the pecking
vation construes such developments as being about           order for the Department because it is first and
                                                            foremost a resource agency’ (Curry, 2001, page
resource rationalization others see them as more
                                                            80).
overt commercialization. Environmental groups
are antagonistic to such developments particularly        Successive legislation has reinforced the conser-
as they have taken place, by and large, without           vation priority of the Department (Corbett, 1995)
public consultation (Department of Conservation,          and recreation is allowed on Crown lands only as
1996). There even has been apprehension on the            far as it serves the conservation purpose (Devlin
part of the public too, that such ‘commodification’       and O’Conner, 1989). On the ground, restrictions,
432    N. Curry

exceptions and prohibitions of access in defer-             Whilst the legal arrangements relating to this
ence to the conservation priority serve to render         process are complex and subtle (Ngai Tahu Negoti-
the availability of collective access confusing and       ating Group, 1998), some loss of collective rights is
uncertain. Even the terminology used in respect of        broadly agreed (Public Access New Zealand, 2000).
access in policy documentation is ambiguous. Both         Further, on the repossession of this land, commer-
the Conservation Act 1987 and the National Parks          cial recreation development by Moari often has
Act 1980, for example, fail to define the terms           ensued, an inevitable consequence of 150 years of
‘recreation’ and ‘tourism’ and terms such as ‘fos-        delayed economic development (Matunga, 2000).
tering’ and ‘allowing’ recreation in the Acts are not     A loss of collective rights has taken place in
clarified.                                                tandem with a development of private market
   This has promulgated the development of per-           exclusionary rights, in contrast with England and
sonal views amongst policy makers (invariably             Wales.
resource managers) about the importance of recre-
ation, ranging from a promotional stance to ignor-
ing the visitor altogether (Booth, 1993). The lack
of an understanding of values and needs of vis-
                                                          The influence of international tourism
itors too, to the extent that such knowledge can
                                                          The growth of international tourism in New
guide management, has exacerbated this. Where it
                                                          Zealand also has brought into question the issue
becomes important to embrace the values of visitors
                                                          of to whom collective rights should pertain. With
in management decision-making, managers often
                                                          a resident population of 3Ð6 million (Ministry
use their own value systems rather than those of
                                                          for the Environment, 1998) and an envisaged
the recreationist (Corbett, 1995).
                                                          international tourist throughput of 3 million a
   Such a conservation priority therefore residu-
                                                          year (New Zealand Tourist Board, 1999) it is
alises the positive development of collective access
                                                          possible that the dominant users of New Zealand
rights. This in turn has led to a growth in access
                                                          collective access rights, may well be from overseas
provision through more exclusionary means where
                                                          (Department of Conservation, 1996). Policy is
collective provision has been found wanting. Again,
                                                          unclear about to whom collective rights should
this development of exclusionary provision in New
                                                          pertain in this context. The Walkways Acts of 1975
Zealand is at variance with the recent policy devel-
                                                          and 1990 suggest that such rights should be for ‘all
opments in England and Wales.
                                                          visitors’ but the Department of Conservation (1996
                                                          and 2000) have interpreted this as being for ‘all
                                                          New Zealanders’. It is widely considered, too, that
Maori land negotiations                                   international tourists have had a more significant
                                                          impact on the environment of wilderness areas
Maori land negotiations also have served to reduce        than the local population. This is partly because
collective access rights in New Zealand in contrast       of their lack of understanding of the nature of
to the way in which they have been expanded in            backcountry but also because of the growth in
England and Wales. The history of land loss from          commercial facilities such as helicopter and aircraft
the indigenous population as a result of European         flights.
settlement in New Zealand is a complicated one               In this context, there is a sense in public
and largely beyond the scope of this paper. The           policy, that provision for the international tourist
creation of collective access rights for the European     is probably better served through exclusionary
population in the 1840s, however, was achieved            rights, again in contrast with England and Wales.
only though significant Maori land dispossession          State economic and private market provision both
(Matunga et al., 1994). The more recent reassertion       provide the opportunity to control visitor impacts,
of Maori land rights through the land reform              through licenses, permits and other limitations on
process of the Treaty of Waitangi has acknowledged        visitor use. Importantly, too, with tourism being
historical claims to land to a greater degree than        the largest foreign exchange earner in New Zealand
in any of the other New World countries (Devlin,          (Kelsey, 1999), such exclusionary rights provide
1993). But the effect of this land repatriation           the opportunity of income generation in remoter
effectively has been to privatise the collective rights   areas with an otherwise fragile economic base.
of access to it (Mason, 1991). The land is ceded          Such income generating opportunities from the
to individuals or groups, allowing the right of           international tourist will not be available in the
exclusion to be reasserted.                               same way in England and Wales.
Access rights in New Zealand and England          433

Conclusions                                               be assessed in respect of the relative preferences of
                                                          the public for the consumption of collective access
                                                          rights compared with the desire to consume, and
Area-based collective rights in New Zealand have          effectiveness in providing, exclusionary rights.
been the dominant means of access rights appor-
tionment for more than 150 years. More recently,
however, there has been a significant shift in            Acknowledgements
such apportionment towards more exclusionary
mechanisms. This has happened at a time when
significant new collective apportionment has been         The research on which this paper is based was conducted
                                                          under a Leverhulme Trust Study Abroad Fellowship
introduced in England and Wales. At least some of         whilst the author was resident in the Human Sciences
the reasons for the shift away from collective rights     Division of the University of Lincoln, New Zealand.
in New Zealand may therefore prove instructive            Thanks are due to both the Trust and the University
for the English and Welsh case in the implemen-           for their support in the conduct of this work.
tation of access to open country under the CROW
Act, 2000.
   Certainly some of the reasons for this shift           References
in New Zealand are unique to that country.
Land reform in respect of the Maori population            Abercrombie, N. (1994). Authority and consumer society.
and the weight of international tourism, provide            In The Authority of the Consumer (R. Keat, N. Whitely
particular circumstances for the more towards               and N. Abercrombie, eds), pp. 43–57. London: Rout-
exclusionary rights. Whilst conservation priorities         ledge.
                                                          Adams, M. (2000). Breaking Ground: Development Aid
have dominated those of recreation in England and
                                                            for Land Reform. London: Overseas Development
Wales in the past (Curry, 1994), the introduction           Institute.
of the Countryside Agency in England at least,            Aitchison, C. (1992). Women and the implications of
in April 2000, has provided clear responsibilities          compulsory competitive tendering in united kingdom
for both access to the countryside and the economic         local authority leisure services. In Perspectives on
                                                            Provision (D. Leslie, ed.), pp. 37–47. LSA Publication
worth of countryside recreation and tourism within
                                                            Number 52. Eastbourne: Leisure Studies Association.
a single agency that has the social, rather than just     Bishop, K. D. and Phillips, A. A. C. (1993). Seven steps to
the environmental, welfare of the countryside at its        market–the development of the market-led approach
core (Countryside Agency, 2000b).                           to countryside conservation and recreation. Journal of
   Experiences in New Zealand in respect of the             Rural Studies 9(4), 315–338.
                                                          Booth, K. L. (1993). Recreation on public lands in New
preferences of the public, the state cost of collective     Zealand–past, present and future. Geojournal 29(3),
access and safety and insurance issues, however,            299–305.
are all pertinent to open country in England and          Booth, K. L. and Peebles, C. (1995). Patterns of use. In
Wales. Policies that acknowledge consumption, too,          Outdoor Recreation in New Zealand: A Review and
in the context of a laissez faire economy, also are         Synthesis of the Research Literature (P. J. Devlin,
                                                            R. A. Corbett and C. J. Peebles, eds), pp. 31–62.
instructive in respect of the potential of state and        Christchurch, New Zealand: Department of Conser-
private markets, if not for open country per se,            vation and Lincoln University.
then for the way in which facilities might develop        Booth, K. L. and Simmons, D. G. (2000). Tourism and
in support of such access. Thus, in the introduction        the establishment of national parks in New Zealand. In
of access to open country in England and Wales              Tourism and National Parks: Issues and Implications
                                                            (R. W. Butler and S. W. Boyd, eds), pp. 39–49.
it will be pertinent to measure levels of use and           Chichester: John Wiley.
consumer satisfactions to identify user preferences       Bromly, D. (1991). Environment and Economy: Property
closely and to ensure the most effective use of public      Rights and Public Policy, Oxford: Blackwell.
expenditure.                                              Clarke, A. (1992). Citizens and consumers. In Leisure in
   Certainly, the ongoing management and admin-             the 1990s: Rolling Back the Welfare State (J. Sugden
                                                            and C. Knox, eds), pp. 109–120. Leisure Studies
istrative costs of open country should be monitored         Association Publication No. 46. Eastbourne: Leisure
not only in respect of absolute costs relative to use       Studies Association.
but also in respect of the opportunity cost of such       Clark, G., Darrell, J., Grove-White, R., Macnaghten, P.
expenditure, particularly in respect of any adverse         and Urry, J. (1994). Leisure Landscapes. London:
impacts that they might have on the Rights of Way           Council for the Protection of Rural England.
                                                          Clarke, J. and Critcher, C. (1985). The Devil Makes Work,
system. Health and safety costs, too, need to be clar-      London: Macmillan.
ified and monitored over time. In the longer term,        Coalter, F. (1990). The politics of professionalism:
the sustainability of such expenditure will need to         consumers or citizens? Leisure Studies 9(2), 107–119.
434     N. Curry

Coalter, F. (1998). Leisure studies, leisure policy and         Devlin, P. J. (1993). Outdoor recreation and environ-
  social citizenship: the failure of welfare or the limits of     ment: towards an understanding of the use of the
  welfare? Leisure Studies 17(1), 21–36.                          outdoors in New Zealand. In Leisure, Recreation
Coalter, F. (2000). Public and commercial leisure provi-          and Tourism (H. C. Perkins and G. Cushman, eds),
  sion: active citizens and passive consumers? Leisure            pp. 37–49. Auckland, New Zealand: Longman Paul.
  Studies 19(3), 163–181.                                       Devlin, P. J. and O’Conner, K. F. (1989). Exploring
Corbbett, R. (1995). Managing outdoor recreation. In              the relationships of recreation users, impacts and
  Outdoor Recreation in New Zealand: A Review and                 management. In Proceedings of a Symposium on
  Synthesis of the Research Literature (P. J. Devlin,             Environmental Monitoring in New Zealand with
  R. A. Corbett and C. J. Peebles, eds), pp. 191–214.             Emphasis on Protected Natural Areas (B. Craig, ed.),
  Christchurch, New Zealand: Department of Conserva-              pp. 96–104. Dunedin, May 1988. Wellington, New
  tion and Lincoln University.                                    Zealand: Department of Conservation.
Countryside Commission (1999). Countryside Recre-               Gallup. (1998). Countryside Survey, 22–28 January.
  ation: Enjoying the Living Countryside. CCP544. Chel-           London: Gallup.
  tenham: the Commission.                                       Giddens, A. (1998). The Third Way: the Renewal of Social
Countryside Agency (2000a). Six of the Best as                    Democracy. Cambridge: Polity Press.
  Access Projects are Given go Ahead, Countryside               Gratton, C. and Taylor, P. (1985). Sport and Recreation:
  Focus. August/September. Cheltenham: the Country-               an Economic Analysis. London: E and FN Spon.
  side Agency.                                                  Grove-Hills, J., Munton, R. and Murdoch, J. (1990).
Countryside Agency (2000b). Tomorrow’s Country-                   The Rural Land Development Process: Evolving a
  side–2020 Vision. The Future of the Countryside and             Methodology, Working Paper 8, Countryside Change
  the Countryside Agency’s Role in Shaping it. CA,                Initiative, the University of Newcastle Upon Tyne.
  No. 22. Cheltenham: the Countryside Agency.                   Hall, S. and Held, D. (1989). Citizens and citizenship. In
Countryside Agency (2001). web site: http://www.coun-             New Times (S. Hall and M. Jaques, eds), pp. 173–188.
  tryside.gov.uk/access. Cheltenham: the Countryside              London: Lawrence and Wishart.
  Agency.                                                       Henry, I. (1994). The Politics of Leisure Policy. Bas-
Craib, I. (1984). Modern Social Theory. Brighton: Har-            ingstoke: MacMillan.
  vester.                                                       Hillary Commission. (1991). Life in New Zealand Survey.
Curry, N. R. (1994). Countryside Recreation, Access and           Executive Overview. Wellington, New Zealand: Hillary
  Land Use Planning. London: E. and F. N. Spon.
                                                                  Commission for Recreation and Sport.
Curry, N. R. (1998). Permitted access in england and
                                                                Holmwood, J. (1997). Citizenship and inequality in post-
  wales. In Access to the Countryside. A response to the
                                                                  modern social theory. In Constructing a New Consumer
  Government’s consultation paper on Access to Open
                                                                  Society (P. Sulkunen, J. Holmwood, H. Radner and
  Country. Volume 2, chapter 2, no pagination. London:
                                                                  G. Schulze, eds), pp. 58–78. London: Macmillan.
  Country Landowners’ Association.
                                                                Houlihan, B. (1991). The Government and Politics of
Curry, N. R. (2000). Community participation in outdoor
  recreation and the development of millennium greens             Sport. London: Routledge.
  in England. Leisure Studies 19(1), 1–19.                      Hutton, W. (1999). The Stakeholding Society: Writings
Curry, N. R. (2001). Access Rights for Outdoor Recreation         on Politics and Economics. Cambridge: Polity Press.
  in New Zealand. A Report to the Leverhulme Trust.             Irvine, D. and Taylor, P. (1998). The value and structure
  Cheltenham: Countryside and Community Research                  of commercial leisure. In Leisure Management: Issues
  Unit.                                                           and Applications (M. Collins and I. Cooper, eds),
Curry, N. R. and Hickey, R. (1998). Analysis of the               pp. 157–179. Wallingformd: CAB International.
  Potential Costs to Local Authorities of Administer-           Jones, O. and Little, J. (2000). Rural challenge(s):
  ing a Statutory Right of ‘Open Access’ over ‘Mountain           partnership and the new rural governance. Journal
  Moor, Heath, Down and Common Land. In Access                    of Rural Studies 16(4), 171–183.
  to the Countryside. A response to the Government’s            Keat, R., Whiteley, N. and Abercrombie, N. (1994). The
  consultation paper on Access to Open Country. Vol-              Authority of the Consumer, London: Routledge.
  ume 2, chapter 2, no pagination. London: Country              Kelsey, J. (1999). Reclaiming the Future: New Zealand
  Landowners’ Association.                                        and the Global Economy. Wellington, New Zealand:
Curry, N. R. and Ravenscroft, N. (2001). Countryside              Bridges Williams Books Ltd.
  recreation provision in England: exploring a demand-          McIntyre, N., Jenkins, J. and Booth, K. (2001). Global
  led approach. Land Use Policy 18(3), 281–291.                   influences on access: the changing face of recreational
Department of Conservation (1994). Specialist Manual:             access to public conservation lands in New Zealand.
  Management Techniques to Reduce Visitor Impact.                 Journal of Sustainable Tourism 9(5), 400–416.
  Wellington, New Zealand: Department of Conserva-              Mason, B. (1991). Public Roads: A Guide to Rights of
  tion.                                                           Access to the Countryside. July. Dunedin: Public Lands
Department of Conservation (1995). New Zealand Walk-              Coalition.
  ways Policy. Wellington, New Zealand: Department of           Matunga, H. (2000). Decolonising planning: the treaty
  Conservation.                                                   of waitangi, the environment and a dual planning
Department of Conservation (1996). Visitor Strategy.              tradition. In Environmental Planning in New Zealand
  Wellington, New Zealand: Department of Conserva-                (P. A. Memon and H. C. Perkins, eds), pp. 36–47.
  tion.                                                           Palmerston North, New Zealand: Dunmore Press.
Department of Conservation (2000). http://www.doc.gov.          Matunga, H., Wakefield, B. and Hulme, L. (1994).
  nz. Wellington, New Zealand: Department of Conser-              Maori Perspectives on the Recreational Use of the
  vation.                                                         Conservation Estate, Report to the Department of
Access rights in New Zealand and England         435

  Conservation. Wellington, New Zealand: Department          Reiling, S. D., Criner, G. K. and Oltmans, S. E.
  of Conservation.                                             (1988). The influence of information on users’ attitudes
Memon, P. A. (1993). Keeping New Zealand Green.                towards campground user fees. Journal of Leisure
  Dunedin: University of Otago Press.                          Research 20, 208–217.
Ministry for the Environment. (1998). The State of           Salamon, S. (1993). Culture and agricultural land tenure.
  New Zealand’s Environment 1997. Wellington, New              Rural Sociology 58, 580–598.
  Zealand: Ministry of the Environment.                      Samuel, R. (1994). Theatres of Memory, Volume 1: Past
Munton, R. (1995). Regulating rural change: prop-              and Present in Contemporary Culture. London: Verso.
  erty rights, economy and environment – a case study        Shoard, M. (1999). A Right To Roam: Should We Open
  from Cumbria, UK. Journal of Rural Studies 11(3),            Up Britain’s Countryside? Oxford: Oxford University
  269–284.                                                     Press.
New Zealand Tourist Board. (1999). Visitor spending          Shultis, J. D. (1991). Natural Environments, Wilderness
  doubles in four years. In New Zealand Tourism News,          and Protected Areas: an Analysis of Historical and
  April, page 4. Wellington, New Zealand: New Zealand          Western Attitudes and Utilisation and their Expression
  Tourist Board.                                               in Contemporary New Zealand. Unpublished Geog-
Ngai Tahu Negotiating Group. (1998). Crown Set-                raphy Thesis. Dunedin, New Zealand: University of
  tlement Offer, Consultation Document, Second Edi-            Otago.
  tion, November. Christchurch: Ngai Tahu Negotiating        Social and Community Planning Research. (1999).
  Group.                                                       United Kingdom Leisure Day Visits Survey 1998.
Parker, G. (1999). Rights, symbolic violence and the           Unpublished data printouts. London: Social and Com-
  micropolitics of the rural: the case of the Parish paths     munity Planning Research.
  partnership scheme. Environment and Planning A 31,         Tomlinson, A. (1991). Leisure as consumer culture. In
  1207–1222.                                                   Ideology, Leisure Policy and Practice (D. Botteril and
Parker, S. (1997). Leisure and Culture: Consumers              A. Tomlinson, eds), pp. 1–2. LSA Publication No. 45.
  or Participants? Paper presented at the Leisure              Eastbourne: Leisure Studies Association.
  Studies Conference, Leisure, Culture and Commerce,         Turner, B. S. (1990). Periodisation and politics in the
  Roehampton, Surrey. September.                               postmodern. In Theories of Modernity and Postmoder-
Perkins, H. C. (1993). Recreation and tourism. In              nity (B. S. Turner, ed.), pp. 5–14. London: Sage.
  Environmental Planning in New Zealand (P. Memon            Voyce, M. (1994). Testamentry freedom, patriarchy and
  and H. C. Perkins, eds), pp. 57–74. Palmerston North,        inheritance of the family farm in Australia. Sociologa
  New Zealand: Dunmore Press.                                  Ruralis 34, 71–83.
Public Access New Zealand. (1992). Public Access             Warde, A. (1992). Notes on the relationship between
  Newsletter, Number 1, September. Omakau, New                 production and consumption. In Consumption and
  Zealand: Public Access New Zealand.                          Class: Division and Change (R. Burrows and C. Marsh,
Public Access New Zealand. (2000). News Release, Set-          eds), pp. 15–31. London: Macmillan.
  tlement Helps Protect Public Access to Mt Hikurangi,       Williamson, J. (1995). Consuming Passions: The Dynam-
  October 6. Omakau, New Zealand: Public Access New            ics of Popular Culture. London: Marlon Boyars.
  Zealand.
Ravenscroft, N. (1993). Public leisure provision and the
  good citizen. Leisure Studies 12(10), 33–44.
You can also read