The Labor Market Effects of Immigration and Emigration in OECD countries

 
CONTINUE READING
The Labor Market Effects of Immigration and
              Emigration in OECD countries ∗
       Frédéric Docquier (FNRS-IRES, Université Catholique de Louvain)
                          Çağlar Özden (The World Bank)
                    Giovanni Peri (University of California, Davis)
                                       September 1st, 2011

                                             Abstract
           This paper uses an improved database of the stocks of migrants by education level
       and country of origin for the years 1990 and 2000 to simulate the labor market effects
       of net immigration and emigration during the 1990’s in all OECD countries. Due
       to the much higher international mobility of college graduates relative to all other
       individuals, we find that net migration flows are, in general, very college-intensive
       relative to the population of non-migrants. Using a simple aggregate model of labor
       demand and supply in each country we simulate the long-run employment and wage
       effects of immigration and emigration. We use a range of parameter values that spans
       most of the estimates in the literature. In all cases we find that immigration in the
       1990’s had a positive effect on the wage of less educated natives and it also increased
       or left unchanged the average wages in OECD countries. It also had positive or null
       effect on native employment. To the contrary, emigration had a negative effect on the
       wage of native less educated workers and it contributed to increase inequality in all
       OECD countries. These results hold true also when we correct for the estimates of
       undocumented immigrants, for the skill-downgrading of immigrants, when we focus
       on immigration from non-OECD countries and when we consider (still preliminary)
       measures of more recent immigration flows for the period 2000-2007.
           JEL Codes: F22, J61, J31.
       Keywords: Immigration, Emigration, Complementarity, Schooling Externalities, Av-
       erage Wage, Wage inequality.
   ∗
    Frédéric Docquier, frederic.docquier@uclouvain.be; Çağlar Özden, cozden@worldbank.org; Giovanni
Peri, gperi@ucdavis.edu. This article was funded by the project "Brain drain, return migration and South-
South migration: impact on labor markets and human capital" supported by the Austrian, German, Korean,
and Norwegian governments through the Multi-donor Trust Fund on Labor Markets, Job Creation, and Eco-
nomic Growth administered by the World Bank’s Social Protection and Labor unit. The first author also
acknowledges financial support from the Belgian French-speaking Community (convention ARC 09/14-019
on "Geographical Mobility of Factors"). We thank Francesco D’Amuri, Francesc Ortega and participants to
seminars at Bocconi University, the OECD, the World Bank, Universitat Autonoma de Barcelona, Copen-
hagen Business School and University of Helsinki for valuable comments and suggestions. The findings,
conclusions and views expressed are entirely those of the authors and should not be attributed to the World
Bank, its executive directors or the countries they represent.

                                                    1
1         Introduction
Immigration rates in OECD countries are larger than in the rest of the world and they
increased significantly in the last 20 years. As of year 2000 about 7.7% of the adult residents
of OECD countries were born in another country (hence migrants), versus only 2.9% in the
average world country (Freeman, 2006). Since then the number of foreign-born has further
increased and they were estimated to be about 10% of the OECD resident population in
20091 . Worries about immigration feature prominently in the rich countries media and
are voiced by several European government officials. The common representation of recent
migratory flows portrays a multitude of uneducated individuals, coming from countries at
the margin of the developed world, trying to gain access to the labor markets and to the
welfare systems of rich countries. Such phenomenon, the simplistic view continues, is a
main contributor to depressed wages and job losses for the less educated natives, a group of
workers that has under-performed in the labor markets during the last 20 years. The available
data and recent analysis however (e.g. Docquier and Marfouk, 2006; Grogger and Hanson,
2011) are uncovering a different picture of international migrants. First, a large part of the
mobility to OECD countries is from other OECD countries (about 4% of the 7.7% foreign-
born residents of OECD countries in 2000 were from another OECD country). Second, the
share of college educated among immigrants is usually larger than (or not different from) the
share of college educated in the native population of the receiving country. In some OECD
countries the percentage of college educated among immigrants is much larger than among
natives (up to 4-5 times).
    Our paper uses a new database that combines original Census data for 76 receiving
countries in year 2000 and 61 receiving countries in year 1990 to measure (or estimate in
the case of the missing host countries) bilateral net immigration and emigration flows of all
OECD countries in the 1990’s. The data distinguish between college educated migrants and
non college educated ones and we can distinguish net flows for each bilateral relation between
a OECD country and any other country in the world. These data are new, they are described
in detail in the report by Docquier et al. (2010). They constitute a substantial improvement
on Docquier and Marfouk (2006) especially in the construction of net emigration data from
OECD countries because they include more than double the number of receiving countries.
    Using these data and simple models of the national economies and labor markets we sim-
ulate the employment and wage effect of immigration and emigration on nationals of each
OECD country. The model used is a simple application of production-function based models
that have become popular in the labor literature of the national analysis of effects of immi-
gration (Borjas 2003; D’Amuri et al., 2010; Ottaviano and Peri, forthcoming, Manacorda et
al forthcoming). Macroeconomic studies analyzing growth, productivity and skill premium
in the US and other countries have also used similar framework (e.g. Acemoglu and Zilibotti
2001, Caselli and Coleman 2006, Card and Lemieux 2001, Goldin and Katz 2008). To this
framework that enables us to derive a labor demand by skill group we add a simple labor
supply decision that generates an aggregate supply curve (also by skill group).
    The two facts about migration mentioned above have clear implications on the potential
labor market effects of immigration and emigration. First, as OECD countries are important
    1
        These figures are from OECD (2011).

                                              2
sources as well as destinations for many of the recent world migrant it makes sense to
analyze the potential labor market effects of both flows, immigration and emigration, and
see whether OECD countries should be concerned with the domestic labor market effects
of either of them. Second, if migrants have a large share of college graduates, immigration
can actually help wages and employment of less educated (through complementarity) and
possibly average wages (through human capital externalities). To the contrary emigration
may hurt them. Immigrants in Barcelona or Athens are more visible to the European public
eye than the Spanish or Greek engineers in Silicon Valley, but are they more harmful to the
labor market options of Spanish and Greek workers with low education? While there are
scores of studies on the labor market effects of immigration in OECD countries there is only
a handful of studies on the labor market effects of emigration. This asymmetric view may
lead to misconceptions of the economic effects of migration. The goal of this paper is to
assess the impact of global labor movements in the 1990’s on the wages of those who did not
migrate. We consider all OECD countries as well as the remaining non-OECD countries of
Europe, some of which were affected by significant flows in the 1990’s.
    The existing estimates of the labor market effects of immigrants are often seen as differen-
tiated or even as conflicting with each other2 . Most of the disagreement, however, is relative
to the US labor markets and it is limited to moderate differences about the wage impact of
immigrants on less educated workers. We take a different approach here. We capture the
range of disagreement across economists with different estimates of the fundamental para-
meters of our labor market model. In particular, different choices of the elasticity of relative
demand between more and less educated and between native and immigrants, of the elastic-
ity of supply of more and less educated and of the strength of human capital externalities can
be varied to produce different scenarios. Those can be associated with the most pessimistic,
an intermediate and a most optimistic view of the labor market effects of immigrants. This
is what we will do, without taking any stand on the current debate but showing what range
of effects one obtains by allowing the whole reasonable spectrum of parameter estimates.
    Some general results emerge from these simulations. First, in general, over the period
1990-2000 immigration had zero to small positive long-run effect on the average wages of
non-migrant natives in all the OECD countries. These effects were, usually, positively cor-
related with the immigration rate of the country (the size of immigrant flow relative to the
population). They ranged from 0 to +4%. Canada, Australia and New Zealand, which
adopted immigration policies explicitly selecting in favor of highly educated had significant
positive wage gains of natives from immigration. However also countries as Luxembourg,
Malta, Cyprus, the United Kingdom and Switzerland (which did not explicitly select their
immigrants based on education) experienced positive average wage effects in the order of
1 to 3%. Second, immigration had even more beneficial effects on wages of less educated
(non-college) workers in OECD countries. These effects ranged between 0 and +6%. For
some countries such as Ireland, Canada, Australia, United Kingdom and Switzerland the
effects are likely in the 2-4% range. Only Austria, Denmark, Italy, Japan and Greece show
estimated effects on the wages of less educated (in the most pessimistic scenario) that are
close to 0. A corollary of this result is that immigration reduced the wage differential be-
  2
   The estimates in Borjas (2003) and Card (2001, 2009) are considered as spanning the range between the
more pessimistic and more optimistic view of the labor market effects of immigrants.

                                                   3
tween more and less educated natives. Third, emigration, to the contrary, had a negative and
significant effect on wages of less educated natives ranging between 0 and -7%. In countries
as Cyprus, Ireland and New Zealand, less educated workers suffered wage decrease between
3 and 6% due to emigration of the highly skilled. Even in Portugal, United Kingdom, South
Korea, Latvia and Slovenia less educated suffered losses between -1 and -2% because of
emigration.
    All three results logically proceed from the nature of measured migrant flows from 1990
to 2000. OECD countries have experienced both immigration and emigration that were
usually more "college-intensive" than their domestic labor forces. Under these conditions,
in the long run, immigration is associated with average wage gains of less educated workers
and emigration with average wage losses for non-migrant less educated workers.
    As the skill composition of migrants is crucial in determining our relative and average
wage results, we attempt to correct for the "effective" skill content of immigrants in a series
of checks. First, we use estimates of the extent of illegal immigration (from the recent
"Clandestino" study, performed in several European countries) to correct for the inflows of
undocumented migrants. Second, we account for the potential "downgrading" of immigrants’
skills in the host countries’ labor market, by using their occupational choice as of 2000. Third,
we focus on immigration from non-OECD countries which is often portrayed as particularly
low skilled. All corrections reduce the percentage of "effective" highly educated immigrants in
OECD countries. However none of them eliminates or reverses the general picture described
above: when immigration changed the educational composition of residents, it changed it by
increasing the share of college educated (highly skilled).
    Finally we consider two further extensions of our data and simulations. First, we re-
do the exercises for a subset of countries for which we have provisional net immigration
data for the 2000’s (2000-2007). We choose some European countries that received large
immigration flows (including Luxembourg, Spain and Greece which were very large receivers
of immigrants) and the US. For these countries data from the EU Labor Force Survey or from
the American Community Survey are available. They are based on smaller samples relative
to the censuses and hence subject to larger measurement error. Even in this case, however,
we find that the long-run effects of the more recent immigration flows are between zero and
positive for all countries. For Luxembourg, the biggest recipient of immigrants in this period,
they can be as large as +6% for less educated. For Spain, usually considered as the country
most affected by immigrants in the 2000’s the wage effect on less educated natives range
between 0 and +2%. The second extension is to account for sluggish capital adjustment in
the short-run (rather than assume perfectly elastic capital supply), using estimates of the
speed of adjustment from the literature. In this case, Spain and Cyprus exhibit a negative
short-run impact on wage of less educated, when accounting for downgrading, undocumented
and slow capital adjustment. The effects are between -1 and -2%. For all other countries
experiencing net immigration, the short-run effect on wages of less educated are very small
(between -0.5 and +0.5%) and for Luxembourg they are still positive at +2.2%.
    The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section 2 presents the simple aggregate
production and labor supply framework from which we derive wages and employment ef-
fect of exogenous immigration and emigration shocks. Section 3 describes the data, their
construction the main sources and it shows some simple summary statistics about the edu-
cational structure of labor force data and migrant data. Section 4 presents the basic results

                                               4
of the simulated wage effects of immigrants using our model and the range of parameters
available from the literature. Section 5 considers the wage effect when accounting for un-
documented workers, for downgrading of skills, looking at non-OECD immigrants and using
the preliminary data on net immigration in the 2000’s. Section 6 concludes the paper.

2       Model
We present here a simple aggregate model of each country for which we derive the labor
demand and labor supply for different types of workers: native and foreign-born. This al-
lows us to examine the long-run wage and employment effects of exogenous net immigration
and emigration flows, which constitute change in the supply of workers of certain skill types.
The analysis builds on the literature that aims at identifying the impact of immigration on
national labor markets. Immigration has the main effect of changing the marginal produc-
tivity (demand) of native workers. Emigration changes the exogenous supply of potential
workers. The long-run consequence of these changes on employment and wages of natives
depend crucially on the elasticity of substitution across workers and on the elasticity of la-
bor supply. The size and the educational composition of immigrants and emigrants relative
to the non-migrants are the crucial factors in determining the long-run domestic wage and
employment effects of international migrations.

2.1     Aggregate production function
The prevalent model adopted in this literature (Borjas 2003, Card 2001, Ottaviano and Peri
forthcoming) is based on a production function where the labor aggregate is represented as a
nested constant elasticity of substitution (CES) aggregation of different types of workers. In
the production function (we omit country subscripts for simplicity), we assume that output
in year  ( ) is produced according to a constant-returns-to-scale Cobb-Douglas production
function with two factors, physical capital ( ), and a composite labor input ( ):
                                                e 1− 
                                            =                                                    (1)
The term  e represents the total factor productivity (TFP), and  is the income share of
labor.
    Assuming that physical capital is internationally mobile in the long-run and that each
single country is too small to affect the global capital markets, the returns to physical capital
are equalized across countries. If ∗ denotes the international net rate of return to capital,
the following arbitrage condition implicitly defines the equilibrium capital-to-labor ratio in
the economy:
                                    ∗ = (1 − ) e −                                 (2)
   The above condition holds in the short and in the long run in a small open economy.
In a closed economy as in Ramsey (1926) or Solow (1951) condition (2) holds in the long-
run balanced growth path, with ∗ being a function of the inter-temporal discount rate of
individuals (or of the savings rate)3 . Hence in the long-run we can substitute this arbitrage
    3
    As long as immigration does not change the saving rate of an economy the pre- and post- migration ∗
are identical.

                                                   5
condition into (1) to obtain an expression of aggregate output as linear function of the
aggregate labor  :
                                        =                                      (3)
where  ≡   e1
                  [(1 − )∗ ](1−) is an increasing function of TFP and is referred to as
modified TFP. Production function 3 can be considered as an aggregate production function
in which inputs (workers) can be adjusted immediately and the long-run and short run effects
of a change in workers are the same as there is no slowly "accumulated" factor. Alternatively
it can be considered as the long-run reduced version of a function with capital accumulation.
In long-run (balanced growth path) analysis the two interpretations are equivalent.
    Following the labor (Katz and Murphy 1992, Card and Lemieux 2001, Acemoglu and
Zilibotti 2001) and growth (Caselli and Coleman 2006) literature, we assume that labor
in efficiency unit () is a nested CES function of highly educated ( ) and less educated
workers ( ):
                                   "      −1             
                                                              #  −1
                                                           −1     
                                                           
                            =    + (1 −  )                                      (4)

where  and 1 −  are the productivity levels of highly educated workers (college educated)
and less educated workers (non college educated). The parameter   , is the elasticity of
substitution between the two groups of workers.
    We also distinguish between natives and immigrants within each labor aggregate  and
 . If native and immigrant workers of education level  were perfectly substitutable, the
aggregate  would simply be equal to the sum of natives’ and immigrants’ labor supplies.
However native and immigrant workers of similar education may differ in several respects.
First, immigrants have skills, motivations and tastes that may set them apart from natives.
Second, in manual and intellectual work, they may have culture-specific skills and limita-
tions (e.g., limited knowledge of the language or culture of the host country), which create
comparative advantages in some tasks and disadvantages in others. Third, even in the ab-
sence of comparative advantage, immigrants tend to concentrate in occupations different
from those mostly chosen by natives because of migration networks, information constraints
and historical accidents. In particular, new immigrants tend to cluster disproportionately in
those sectors or occupations where previous migrant cohorts are already over-represented.
Several studies (such as Card, 2009; D’Amuri et al 2010; Ottaviano and Peri, forthcoming;
Manacorda et al., forthcoming) find imperfect degrees of substitution between natives and
immigrants. Hence, we assume that the quantities of high-educated ( ) and low-educated
labor ( ) are both nested CES functions of native and immigrant labor stocks with the
respective education levels. This is represented as:
                      ∙      −1             −1 ¸  −1
                                                      
                                                      
                                             
                   =   + (1 −  )                  where  =            (5)

where  is the number of type- native workers and  is the number of type- foreign-
born workers who are present in the country.   is the elasticity of substitution between
natives and foreign-born in group .

                                               6
2.2     Schooling externalities
We also consider the possibility of a positive externality from highly educated workers, in the
spirit of the recent literature (Acemoglu and Angrist 2000, Ciccone and Peri 2006, Moretti
2004a, 2004b and Iranzo and Peri 2009). There is a large body of growth literature (beginning
with Lucas 1988, and extending to Azariadis and Drazen 1990, Benhabib and Spiegel 2005,
Cohen and Soto 2007 and Vandennbussche et al 2009) that emphasizes the role of human
capital (schooling) on technological progress, innovation and growth of GDP per capita.
More recently, however, the empirical literature has pointed out that while it is sometimes
hard to find an effect of human capital on growth of income per capita (Benhabib and Spiegel
2005), there seems to be evidence that human capital contributes to the level of income per
person beyond its private returns. This implies that TFP is an increasing function of the
schooling intensity in the labor force. Such formulation is particularly appropriate to be
included in our model and, based on the expressions used in Moretti (2004a, 2004b), the
TFP can be expressed as follows ,
                                µ    µ                               ¶¶
                                                + 
                         = 0 exp                                                          (6)
                                        +  +  + 
where 0 captures the part of TFP independent of the human capital externality, and  is the
semi-elasticity of the modified TFP to the fraction of highly educated individuals in the labor
force (in parenthesis) that we call  .  is the total number of individual of education  and
nativity-status  in working age4 . The upper bar distinguishes total population in working
age from the actual employed individuals of the same group denoted as   Acemoglu and
Angrist (2000) and Iranzo and Peri (2009) also use a similar formulation to express schooling
externalities and we use their estimates of the parameter .

2.3     Labor Demand
We consider each country as a single labor market. Then we derive the marginal productivity
for native workers of both education levels ( and  ) by substituting (4) and (5)
into (3) and taking the derivative with respect to the quantity of labor  and 
respectively. This yields the following expression which defines the labor demand for each
type of national workers:
                                           µ     ¶1 µ       ¶1
                                                      
                        =                                                     (7)
                                                     
                                                 µ ¶ 1 µ        ¶1
                                                            
                        = (1 −  )                                             (8)
                                                          
    By taking the logarithm of the demand functions above and calculating the total differ-
entials of each one of them with respect to infinitesimal variations (∆) of the employment of
   4
     We assume that the schooling externality depends on the college intensity of the population in working
age. In practice this is very similar to the college intensity of workers and simplify the analysis much. Non-
institutionalized individuals in working age represent the total pool of potential workers in the long-run. It
is, therefore, reasonable to consider them as the relevant group in generating productive externalities.

                                                      7
each type of workers, we obtain the percentage change in marginal productivity in response
to employment changes. In particular, the percentage change of marginal productivity for
native workers of schooling level  (=  ) in response to a percentage change in em-
ployment of foreign-born (∆  and ∆  ) and native (∆  and
∆  ) workers can be written as follows5 :

                   µ                                                     ¶
∆          1        ∆         ∆         ∆         ∆
             =              +        +          +          +     (9)
                                                
               µ         ¶µ                         ¶
                  1   1      ∆    ∆      1 ∆
                    −                  +              −          + ∆ for  =  
                                        

    In expression 9 the terms  represent the share of wage bill going to workers of schooling
level  (=  ) and place of origin (=   ) The first term in the summation captures the
effect of changes in the employment of each group on the marginal productivity of natives
of type  through the term  in the wage equation. The second term in the summation,
which depends only on the change in supply of workers of the same schooling type (natives
or immigrants), is the impact on marginal productivity of natives of type  through the terms
                                                ∆                                                      − 1
 in the wage equation. The term − 1 
                                           
                                               captures the impact through the term  .
Finally the terms ∆ is the effect of a potential change in college intensity, measured as
a change in the share of the college educated in the working-age population, through , the
Total factor Productivity.

2.4     Labor Supply
We assume that a native household of type (=  ) chooses how to split one unit of
labor endowment between work  and leisure 1 −  to maximize the following instant utility
function6 which depends positively on consumption  and negatively on the amount of labor
supplied  :
                                                                 
                                             =    −                                          (10)
    The constant parameters    ,  and  (=   ) can be specific to the schooling group.
Considering production without capital as in expression 3, in each period individuals consume
all their labor income and hence the budget constraint implies  =   for each period7 .
The term  is the wage rate of native worker of schooling level . Substituting the
   5
      The details of the derivation are in the Appendix B .
   6
      The more common form of the utility function when analyzing the labor-leisure choice in a macro model
           1−
is:  =  exp(−)−1
                1−       This function would generate an individual labor supply that is independent from
the wage paid. Hence it would produce a special case of expression 11, with perfectly rigid (vertical) supply
curve.
    7
      The model with savings and capital accumulation could be solved with the alternative utility function
       1−
 =  exp(−)−1
            1−       as an intertemporal optimization model. In that case, which is illustrated at page 422-25
of Barro and Sala i Martin (2004) the labor supply in balanced growth path does not depend on wages.
Consumption would be a constant fraction of income and, in balanced growth path wages would be growing
at the rate of e Hence it would be a special case with perfectly inelastic individual labor supply.

                                                      8
constraint into the utility function and maximizing with respect to  we obtain the labor
supply for the individual household.
                                                                 
                                                         =  
                 ³           ´  −
                                  

   where  =         
                      
                                      
                                           is a constant and   =        
                                                                         − 
                                                                                  = 0 is a positive parameter, that
captures the elasticity of household labor supply. As there are  individuals in working
age among households of type  then the aggregate labor supply of that type is given by:
                                                             
                                              =    for  =                                      (11)
    As described above  is the wage paid to a native worker of schooling ,  (as defined
in section 2.2) is the working-age population in group ,   > 0 is the elasticity of labor supply
and  is an unimportant constant.
    For immigrants we make a further simplification assuming that all immigrants in working
age supply a constant amount of labor (call it  ) so that total employment of immigrants
is:  =   for  =   This is equivalent to the assumption that immigration
employment is rigid to changes in wages. It is also equivalent to considering immigration as
an exogenous shock and tracking its labor market impact on natives which is customarily
done in the labor literature on the impact of immigrants (e.g. in Borjas 2003, Borjas and
Katz 2007, Ottaviano and Peri, forthcoming).

2.5      Equilibrium effect of exogenous immigration and emigration
An exogenous change in the foreign-born population in working age (∆ and ∆ )
and in the native population in working age (∆ and ∆ ) are what we call net
immigration and net emigration. They generate changes in the marginal productivity of
native workers as well as changes in the supply of native workers. In the new equilibrium each
of the two labor markets for more and less educated native workers will respond these flows
reaching a new wage and employment combination. In particular considering an immigration
"shock" represented by ∆  and ∆  and an emigration "shock" represented
by ∆  and ∆  the following two conditions (for each market) represent
the percentage change in demand and supply of native labor:

                µ                                                     ¶
 ∆       1        ∆         ∆         ∆         ∆
          =              +        +          +          +     (12)
                                              
            µ         ¶µ                         ¶
               1   1      ∆    ∆      1 ∆
                 −                  +              −          + ∆ for  =  
                                     
                                                  µ                      ¶
                               ∆   1              ∆   ∆
                                     =                      −                 for  =                       (13)
                                                    
   The new equilibrium is obtained by equating the percentage wage changes in the demand
                                                          ∆     ∆
and supply of native labor in each market and solving for   and    For compactness

                                                             9
b = ∆ the percentage change of any variable . We also denote the change
we define as 
of marginal productivity of native workers of schooling  due to exogenous immigration as:

              ∙                                         µ            ¶µ               ¶            ¸
 \             1 ³     [ +  [ +
                                        ´                    1   1         d
   =                                         −                      + ∆        for  =  
                                                                     
                                                                                     (14)
   Solving the system of (12) and (13) and simplifying we obtain the following two linear
equations in two unknown that summarize the equilibrium in each labor market:
                                                   µ         ¶
                  \     [        1 [          1         [
                 +          +      −        +     = 0             (15)
                                                 
                                                    µ        ¶
                  \      [        1 [          1       [
                 +           +  −           +     = 0             (16)
                                                  

    In expression (15) the first two terms   \ 
                                                      +  [
                                                                represent the shift (in per-
                                                        
centage terms) of the intercept of the logarithmic demand function for native workers of
schooling  while 1  [ is the (negative of) the change in the intercept of the logarithmic
                        
                                                                       ³         ´
supply of native workers of schooling  8 The coefficient  = 1 + 1 − 1   
                                                                                         − 
                                                                                              

is the (absolute value) of the slope of the logarithmic demand function for native workers of
type  while 1 is the slope of the logarithmic supply for those workers9 .
                
    The interactions between the two markets ( and ) is due to the fact that a change in
employment of workers with schooling  affects the marginal productivity of, and hence the
demand for, workers of schooling level  through the term    [
                                                                    In turn, employment in
                                                               

the  market affects productivity (and demand) for workers of type  (through         [ ).      
                                             [
Solving the system (15)-(16) with respect to         [
                                               and  we obtain the following equilib-
rium changes in employment and wages of natives in response to immigration and emigration
that we denote with a star:

                      ³            ´³                 ´        ³             ´
                           1          \     1 [           \  1 [
                  ∗       
                               +   +   +   +  
          [
           =                      ³        ´ ³     ´                 
                                                                                                            (17)
                                         1
                                        
                                           +  1 +  − 
                                                                 
                                                                  
                                                    
                      ³            ´³                 ´        ³             ´
                           1          \     1 [           \  1 [
               ∗          
                               +   +   +   +  
         [
          =                       ³        ´³
                                                        ´                
                                                                                                            (18)
                                        
                                         1
                                           +  1 +  − 
                                                                 
                                                                  
                                                        

   8
     Correspondingly, in equation (16) the term  \  +  
                                                          
                                                                  \  is the shift in labor demand for
                                    1 \
native workers of schooling  and   is the negative of the change in labor supply for those workers.
                               ³        ´
   9
     Correspondingly  = 1 + 1 − 1     
                                            −   is the (absolute value of) the slope of the logarithmic
                                            

                                                  1
demand for native workers of schooling  while      is the slope of their logarithmic supply.

                                                      10
and

                               ∗       1 ³d∗ d´
                               =       −  for  =                                     (19)
                                       

2.6      Special cases
Two extreme cases are of interest to define the boundaries of potential wage and employment
effects. If wages are perfectly flexible and supply of workers perfectly inelastic ( = 
and  =  ) the whole effect of exogenous immigration and emigration shocks accrues
to wages. This is a reasonable scenario, especially in the long-run, and it is the one considered
by most national studies (such as Borjas 2003). In such a case there is no endogenous
response of native employment to the exogenous immigration and emigration shocks and the
change in equilibrium wages is:

           ∗       1 ³     [ +       [          [            [
                                                                    ´
      d
         =                 +   +   +              (20)
                  
                  µ        ¶µ                      ¶
                    1    1      d  d           1 d
                      −              +      −      + ∆ for  =  
                                             

    At the opposite extreme of the spectrum the wage would be completely rigid so that any
change in exogenous immigration is absorbed by changes in employment. In this case there
is no wage impact of immigration and the employment response of natives to the exogenous
inflow of immigrants is given by:
                                       ³        ´         ³         ´
                                         \ 
                                 ( )          
                                                  +   \ 
                             ∗
                       [
                         =                                                        (21)
                                            − 
                                                     
                                                        
                                                         
                                       ³        ´         ³         ´
                                (  )   \
                                         
                                                  +      \
                                                             
                            ∗                            
                      [ =                                                         (22)
                                                   
                                            −  
    Such case is well outside the reasonable range of long-run effects, as assuming full wage
rigidity in the long-run is unreasonable. Most of the estimates of the labor supply imply
that it is very rigid (the elasticity of labor supply to wages is estimated much closer to 0
than to infinity) and hence this perfectly elastic case is simply a theoretical case.

2.7      Imperfect physical capital adjustment and the short-run ef-
         fects
With full capital adjustment to its balanced growth path equilibrium the effects of migration
on wages are as described above. However, immigration in the short run may affect the
capital labor ratio10  =   pushing the economy outside its balanced growth path.
  10
     We use the slightly modified expression for the capital-labor ratio that includes the labor composite
(rather than employment) at the denominator.

                                                   11
Due to slow adjustment of capital there will be an extra effect of immigrants on marginal
productivity of each type of worker, through  . We can re-write the expressions of marginal
productivity in (??) and (??) noting explicitly their dependence on the capital-labor ratio:

                                                      µ   ¶1 µ         ¶1
                                        e ( )1−      
                           =                                                                (23)
                                                              
                                                          µ      ¶ 1 µ      ¶1
                                  e       1−                         
                           =  ( )    (1 −  )                                             (24)
                                                                    

In balanced growth path (or in an open economy) the capital-labor ratio is given by the
                          ¡    ¢ 1 1
following expression ∗ = 1−     e and it does not depend on the inflows and outflows of
                                   
                            ∗
migrants. In that case expressions (23) and (24) reduce to (7) and (8) and the total per-
centage effect of immigrants and emigrants on marginal productivity are as in (15) and (16).
In the short run, however,  may deviate from its long-run equilibrium due to exogenous
migration shocks. In this case the percentage effect on marginal productivity, included in
expressions 17 and 18 of each group, includes an extra term, namely:

                     \
                                   \
                                      =  
                                                + (1 − )b
                                                         short run  =                            (25)
                         short run     

where bshort run is the short-run percentage deviation of the capital-labor ratio from ∗ due to
exogenous immigration or emigration. Considering, immigration11 , with immediate and full
capital adjustment, b  short run equals 0. At the opposite extreme, with fixed total capital,  =
 then bshort run is approximately equal to the negative percentage change of labor supply
                                                                ∆   +∆
due to exogenous immigration and emigration which is: −    , where the numerator
is the net change in workers due to the total net immigration and  is, approximately, the
employment at the beginning of the period. While for short periods or for sudden shocks
the short run effect may be evaluated considering capital as fixed in the case of ten years of
immigration, which is a slow and sustained phenomenon, we need to account explicitly for
the dynamics of the capital-labor ratio to recover a short-run effect.
    A popular way to analyze the deviation of ln( ) from its balanced growth path trend,
used in the growth and business cycle literature, is to represent its time-dynamics in the
following way:

                                                                  ∆ + ∆
                ln( ) =  0 +  1 ln(−1 ) +  2 () +                  +                   (26)
                                                                       

where
    ³ the term
            ´  2 () captures the balanced growth path trajectory of ln( ) equal to
1
  ln 1− e  and the term  1 ln(−1 ) captures the sluggishness of yearly capital adjust-
         
     ∗
ment. The parameter (1 −  1 ) is commonly called the “speed of adjustment ” since it is the
  11
    The short run effect of exogenous emigration could be accounted similarly. The difference is that in that
case we should consider actual, rather than exogenous, employment changes. However in our case due to
the small values of net emigrants (relative to the total lab or force) we neglect the endogenous employment
response on  in the short-run and we consider only the effect of exogenous emigration on it.

                                                    12
share of the deviation from the balanced growth path (trend) eliminated each year. Finally,
∆ +∆
      
                 represents the yearly net exogenous immigration flows as share of the labor
force and  are other zero-mean uncorrelated shocks. Once we know  1 ,  and the sequence
                                   ∆ +∆
of yearly net immigration flows,         
                                                 we can use (26) to obtain an impulse response
of ln( ) as of 2000 in deviation from its trend (short run).
    In order to obtain the short-run effect on native employment and wages of immigration
we need to evaluate the yearly short-run deviation of ln( ) from its trend due to the net
                          ∆ +∆
inflows of immigrants          
                                       and correct the marginal productivity effects in by (1 −
)bshort run  When analyzing the short-run effects of immigration it is reasonable to consider
the labor supply as rigid, to be consistent with the optimizing model (which has a rigid labor
supply) and to isolate only this channel.

3       Description of the New Data-Set
3.1       Net migration data: sources and definitions
The relevant migration flows to be used in our analysis are net immigration and emigration
flows, namely gross flows of immigrants and emigrants net of returnees. The figures for
immigrants are calculated using the stock of foreign-born (or foreign nationals) individuals
in each countries in two different years and taking the difference between the two. The
figures for emigrants are calculated for each country of origin by aggregating the stock of
people living in other countries in two different years and taking the difference between the
two.
    There are several sources documenting yearly migration flows by receiving country (e.g.
OECD International Migration Database, UN migration statistics) but those only include
gross inflow of people in a country and they do not correct for migrants who leave or go back
to their country of origin. Moreover they never record undocumented migrants and they
often record immigrants when they achieve their resident status rather than when they first
enter the country. Most importantly for our purposes, those data do not have information on
the education level of migrants. The flows of immigrants to a country can only be recovered
by measuring the stock of foreign born people in a destination country (from a certain origin
country) at different points in time and then taking the difference. The other advantage of
using data on stocks of migrants is that they are from national censuses which tend to be
more representative, more accurate and more complete than other data sources. Censuses
(i) often account for undocumented immigrants at least in some countries like the US, (ii)
they categorize immigrants by place of birth, rather than nationality which can change over
time and across countries due to naturalization laws and (iii) report their education levels.
    Our database was constructed by two of the authors and is described in greater detail in
Docquier et al. (2010)12 . It consists of measures of bilateral immigrant and emigrant stocks
for 195 countries in 1990 and 2000. The starting point for the new data is the database
assembled by Docquier and Marfouk (2006) which collected the stock of foreign-born in all
OECD destination countries in 1990 and 2000, by country of origin and level of schooling
 12
      Further detsails of the construction and specific references are also in the Appendix A.

                                                      13
(primary, secondary and tertiary), using Censuses as primary data sources. These data were
supplemented with original data from the censuses of a large number of non-OECD countries.
Finally, for many destination countries with no data, bilateral migrant stocks were predicted
using a gravity framework as described in greater detail in Docquier et al. (2010). Table
A1 in the appendix shows the estimated total stock of migrants in OECD countries, in non-
OECD countries with observed data and in non-OECD countries with imputed data. As we
can see about 70-77% of world migrants are in countries with census data and only 23-30%
of them are in countries with imputed data. Measuring emigration from OECD countries
requires data from all the possible destination countries, at least the most relevant ones.
Emigrant stocks from a certain country of origin can only be measured by aggregating all
migrants recorded in the censuses of all destination countries. As some important destination
countries (such as Russia, South Africa, Brazil, Argentina, and Singapore) are outside the
OECD, this new database, ensures much better coverage of emigrants from OECD countries
relative to Docquier and Marfouk (2006). Table A2 in the appendix show that the majority
of emigrants from the countries considered in this study are in destination countries for which
we have actual census data.13 Less than 13% of emigrants from most countries of origin are
in countries with imputed (rather than actual) migration data. The only countries relying
on imputed data for a larger fraction of their emigrants (up to 40%) are Israel, the Baltic
States and France14 .
    We distinguish two schooling types indexed by .  =  denotes college graduates (also
referred to as highly educated) and  =  denotes individuals with secondary completed or
lower education (referred to as less educated). The database covers the years 1990 and 2000
and the differences in stocks by country of origin and destination provides the measures of
the bilateral net flows in the 1990’s. The data are relative to individuals aged 25 and over as
a proxy of the working-age population. This choice maximizes comparability between data
on migration and on labor force per educational attainment. Furthermore, it excludes a
large number of students who emigrate temporarily to complete their education or children
who migrate with their families and are not active in the labor market.15

3.2     Labor force data per education level
It is relatively easier to identify the number and average education level of adult individuals
resident of each country of the world. Several data sources can be used to assess the size
and skill structure of the labor force of each country. The size of the adult population (i.e.
population aged 25 and over) is provided by the United Nations. Data is missing for a few
countries but can be estimated using the CIA world factbook.16
    Adult population data is then split across skill groups using international indicators of
educational attainment. We follow Docquier and Marfouk (2006) and Docquier, Lowell
  13
     This pattern is also confirmed in Ozden et.al. (2010) which presents global bilateral migration stocks
but does not disaggregate by education levels.
  14
     Also for this reason we will consider Israel and the Baltic States as outliers in most of our simulations.
  15
     The dataset contains 195 source countries: 190 UN member states (after excluding North Korea), the
Holy See, Taiwan, Hong Kong, Macao, and the Palestinian Territories. We consider the same set of countries
in 1990 and 2000, although some of them had no legal existence in 1990.
  16
     See http://www.cia.gov/cia/publications/factbook.

                                                      14
and Marfouk (2009) in combining different data sets documenting the proportion of post-
secondary educated workers in the population aged 25 and over. Those studies use De La
Fuente and Domenech (2006) for OECD countries and Barro and Lee (2010) for non-OECD
countries. For countries where Barro and Lee’s measures are missing, they estimate the
proportion of educated using Cohen and Soto’s measures (see Cohen and Soto, 2007). In
the remaining countries where both Barro—Lee and Cohen—Soto data are missing (about 70
countries in 2000), they apply the educational proportion of the neighboring country having
the closest enrollment rate in secondary/tertiary education, or the closest GDP per capita.

3.3     Description and General Trends
Table 1 shows the immigration rates during the period 1990-2000 for all the countries consid-
ered in this studies, namely all OECD countries plus all the remaining countries of Europe.
The first column of Table 1 shows total immigration rates calculated as net inflow of im-
migrants (age 25 and older) over the period 1990-2000 (∆ + ∆ in the notation of
the model in section 2) divided by the initial population in working age as of 1990, 1990 
For instance the figure of 14.35% relative to Israel means that the net inflow of foreign-born
during the decade 1990-2000 was equal to 14.35% of its population in 1990. This is a huge
number and it is the consequence of the very well known migration of Russian Jews between
1990 and 1994 when migration restriction were lifted in a very unstable Soviet Union17 .
Less well known is that also Luxembourg, Austria and Ireland received during this period
very large inflow of immigrants relative to their population with total rates between 7.6 and
12.5%. Three countries at the bottom of the table are also worth mentioning. The three
Baltic Republic (Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania), born after the collapse of the Soviet Union,
experienced a massive negative net immigration. This means that the stock of foreign-born
individuals decreased massively during this period. This is due to the return migration of
many people of Russian ethnicity back to Russia, after their immigration into Latvia and
Estonia (and to a less extent into Lithuania) during the Soviet period. Hence the negative
immigration rates are really emigration of foreign nationals. Several other eastern European
countries (e.g. Romania, Slovenia, Hungary and Poland) also experienced during this period
net emigration of foreign nationals.
    The second column of Table 1 shows the net immigration rages for College educated,
refereed to as "highly educated" in this study. They are calculated as the net change (be-
tween 1990 and 2000) in the stock of college educated foreign-born (∆ ) relative to the
resident population aged 25 and older with a college degree in 1990 1990 We notice two
interesting things. First, in all countries with positive net immigration rates, except for one
(Austria), the immigration rate of college educated was larger than the rate for the total
population. In some cases (such as Israel, Ireland, Iceland, Canada, Malta, Australia and
the United Kingdom) the immigration rate for college educated was more than double the
overall immigration rate. Immigration, therefore, contributed to increase the share of col-
lege educated in the resident population in all but one of the countries considered. Second
Latvia and Estonia, had negative immigration rates, implying large returns of immigrants
  17
    There are several studies analyzing the economic impact of this episode on the Israel economy. Friedberg
(2001), Cohen-Goldberg and Pasermann (forthcoming) and are among those.

                                                    15
and even larger return rates for college educated. Third the immigration rate for college
educated was remarkably high in many countries. Even omitting the whopping 60% expe-
rienced by Israel, ten more countries had immigration rates for highly educated larger than
10%. Among the countries with immigration rates most skewed in favor of highly educated
were Ireland, Malta, United Kingdom and Switzerland. None of those is among the countries
with immigration policies explicitly favouring highly educated immigrants.
    The third and fourth column of Table 1 show the total and college-educated immigration
rates considering only foreign-born from non-OECD countries. In calculating those figures,
while we left as denominator the stock of population or college educated resident in the
country we only included in the numerator (net immigrants) those born outside the OECD
countries. For some European countries (e.g. Luxembourg, Austria, Ireland and Iceland)
the immigration-rates from non-OECD countries are less than half the total rates indicat-
ing that large part of the immigration is probably within-European mobility. However, in
many cases, including several important receiving countries, the immigration rates from
non-OECD countries were significantly more than half of the total. This was the case, for
instance, in the US, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and Sweden. Moreover even focussing
on non-OECD immigrants the immigration rates for college educated were larger than the
average immigration rates for all but three countries (Luxembourg, Austria and Italy). Even
non-OECD immigrants contributed to increase the college share of most OECD receiving
countries.
    Table 2 shows the emigration rates for the countries in our sample. Column 1 displays the
total emigration rate, calculated as the net outflow of natives (25 year and older) during the
period 1990-2000 (∆ + ∆ ) relative to the total resident population (25+) in 1990
1990  Column 2 contains the net emigration rate of native college-educated. A negative
emigration rate of natives implies that during the period 1990-2000 the flow of returnees
(native resident abroad) was larger than the flow of emigrants. Countries are ranked in the
table in decreasing order of their college emigration rates. Few comments are in order. First,
as in the case of immigration, emigration rates are also larger for college educated than on
average for all but one country (Israel). For some small countries (Cyprus, Malta and Ireland)
a very large emigration rate of college educated, which we may call "brain drain" is associated
with negative overall emigration rates, implying large rate of return for non-college educated
natives from abroad. Some of those small countries had, however, large immigration rates
among college educated that compensated in part for the brain drain. Second there are
some countries with large immigration and emigration rates. Typical is New Zealand with
large immigration from Asian and Pacific countries and large emigration to Australia. Third
several Eastern European countries (such as Poland, Romania, Slovenia, Slovakia) and some
western European countries (Portugal, Greece) had significant emigration rates, but mainly
very large rate of college emigration not compensated by similar immigration flows. For
those countries emigration was a significant source of change in the supply of highly educated
labor. Other European countries such as United Kingdom, Luxembourg, Switzerland and
the Netherlands had significant rates of college-educated emigration but they made up with
significant immigration rates in that group. Finally the United States, Canada and Australia
were, as expected, mainly countries of immigration as the immigration rates (total and for
highly educated) were much larger than the corresponding emigration rates. In summary,
considering OECD countries during the 1990’s immigration and emigration were very college-

                                              16
intensive, that many countries experienced emigration rates as large as immigration rates
and that even immigrant from non-OECD countries were over-represented among college
educated relative to the total.

4     Simulated Labor-Market effects
4.1     Parameterization and Measurement
Our model allows us to calculate the percentage wage and employment effects of migration
on natives. As one can see from the formulas in 17-19, in order to evaluate these effects
we need to know three sets of variables, for each country. The first is the share of wage
income to each of four groups (native and foreign-born, more and less educated) as of 1990
denoted as ( )1990 ( =   and  =   ). The second is the percentage change in
employment in each of those four groups due to immigrants and emigrants in the decade
1990-2000, d
               1990−2000 ( =   and  =   ). The last is the change in college intensity
due to immigration and emigration ∆  Then we also need to know the value of four
fundamental parameters:   , the elasticity of substitution between more and less educated;
  the elasticity of substitution between native and immigrants with same schooling, 
the intensity of college-externalities and      the labor supply elasticity of more and less
educated natives. I describe briefly in this section how we measure these country-specific
variables and how we choose the range of the parameters.
    The share of wage income to more and less educated and native-immigrants depend
on their employment and their wages. We use their number in the population in working
age as measure of employment (from the Docquier et al. 2010, Database). As there is no
international database on wages of college educated and less educated we proceed as follows.
From the Hendricks (2004) database we take the estimated returns to one year of schooling
in each of the considered countries estimated in a year as close as possible to 199018 . From
the Barro and Lee (2010) database we calculate the average years of schooling in each of the
two schooling groups (college graduates and those with no college degree) for each country.
We multiply the yearly return by the year of schooling difference between the two groups
to identify the college wage premium in the country. Then from several estimates, most of
which reviewed in Kerr and Kerr (2009) we use the country-specific estimate of the native-
foreign wage premium to correct the wages of immigrants at each level of wage. Even in this
case we use the estimate for the closest country with most similar income per person if the
data is not available for a specific country. Multiplying the group-specific employment by
the group-specific wage (standardized for the wage of less educated natives) we obtain the
wage-bill for the group, which divided by the total wage bill provides the share. The shares
of wage income for each of the four groups in each country, calculated using this method,
are reported in Table A3 of the appendix. The percentage change in the employment of
each group during the period 1990-2000 due to immigration and emigration, as well as the
change in share of college-educated, are calculated from the dataset on stocks of migrants in
1990-2000.
  18
     If the estimate was not available for a country we choose the estimate for country sharing a border with
the closest level of income per capite.

                                                     17
Table 3 summarizes the values of the parameters chosen in each of three scenarios con-
sidered in the numerical simulations. The estimates span the range found in the literature.
For the parameter   the elasticity of substitution between more and less educated, there are
several estimates in the literature. A group of influential papers propose specific estimated
values for low, intermediate and high levels of substitution. For instance Johnson (1970) and
Murphy et al. (1998) estimate values for   around 1.30 (respectively 1.34 and 1.36); Angrist
(1995); Katz and Murphy (1992), Ciccone and Peri (2005) and Krusell et al. (2000) estimate
values around 1.5-1.75 (respectively 1.47, 1.50, 1.66) and Ottaviano and Peri (forthcoming)
estimate a value close to 2. Hence we use the values 1.5, 1.75 and 2 for the three scenarios.
    The parameter   capturing the elasticity of substitution between natives and immigrants
has been the subject of several recent papers and has generated a certain level of debate.
This parameter is particularly relevant to determine the effect of immigrants on wages of
natives and, as we will see, the choice of this parameter affects the significantly the estimated
wage-effects of migration in some countries. Borjas et al. (2008), Peri (2010) and Ottaviano
and Peri (forthcoming) use US data and Manacorda et al. (forthcoming) use UK data in
their estimation of . The first study finds a value of infinity, the second and third estimate
an elasticity between 10 and 20 and the paper on UK data finds a value of 6. We use infinity,
20 and 6 as the three parameters spanning the range.
    The parameter , capturing the externality of college educated, whose magnitude has
been estimated using data from US cities (Moretti 2004a, 2004b) or US states (Acemoglu
and Angrist 2000 and Iranzo and Peri 2009) is also subject to a certain level of disagreement.
Some studies find substantial schooling externalities ( =0.75 in Moretti 2004b) while others
do not ( = 0 in Acemoglu and Angrist 2000).
    Finally, the estimates of the elasticity of labor supply  as summarized in the review by
Evers et al (2008), which covers several European countries and the US, range from 0 (with
actually a few small negative estimates) to 0.17 (in a study relative to the US of Flood and
MaCurdy 1992 and in one relative to the Netherlands by van Soest et al 1990). Hence we
choose 0, 0.10 and 0.20 as representative values in this range.

4.2    Simulation: Wage Effects of Immigration
The effects of immigration on native wages, in percentage points are shown in Figures 1 and 2.
Each figure reports the values obtained using the formulas 19 and the three configurations
of the parameters shown in Table 3 (pessimistic, intermediate and optimistic), for each
of the considered countries. The thick solid line connects the estimates in the optimistic
scenario, the thin solid line connects estimates in the intermediate scenario and the dashed
line connects the pessimistic estimates. The numeric values corresponding to the figures are
reported in Table A4 of the Appendix. We show the long-run percentage effect of immigration
on the wage of less educated native workers in Figure 1 and the percentage average wage
effects on natives in Figure 2. We focus our attention on less educated workers, first, as
they are those usually considered as suffering the most disruptive labor market effects from
immigration (e.g. Borjas 2003). The average wage effect, on the other hand, provides us with
an idea of the overall effect of immigrants in the long-run on income accruing to national
factors. While in Table A4 we report the effect on natives for all the 39 countries considered
(all OECD plus the remaining European Countries) in the Figures we omit Israel and the

                                              18
You can also read